Skip to main content
Log in

Reorganizing a partnership efficiently

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Review of Economic Design Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We modify the partnership dissolution model pioneered by Cramton et al. (Econometrica 55:615–632, 1987) to consider the possibility that each partner has an optimal scale and hence values only a fraction of an object, called a block. To achieve efficiency, a partnership should be reorganized so that multiple blocks are allocated one-to-one to the partners who have the highest valuations. The set of initial ownership distributions under which efficient reorganization can be achieved is non-convex. A condition reveals the relationship between the possibility of efficient reorganization for any given partnership and three characteristics that it entails: the number of blocks available (K), the total number of partners (N), and the number of partners who own up to a block (S). Given that K and N are fixed, efficiency can be achieved if and only if S is sufficiently low. In addition, given that N and S are fixed, efficiency can be achieved if and only if K is sufficiently high.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “ BMW, Daimler and Audi Clinch Purchase of Nokia’s Maps Business,”  The Wall Street Journal, August 2015.

  2. “ Verizon to Acquire Stake in AwesomenessTV,”  The Hollywood Reporter, April 2016.

  3. “ Bid & Ask,” Bloomberg Businessweek , 6-12 February 2012.

  4. “ Verizon Unloading LTE Spectrum; AT&T, Open Your Wallet,”  GIGAOM, April 2012.

  5. One rationale, proposed by Edmans and Manso (2011), is that shareholders can discipline managers by selling the stock of the company and lowering its price in the market, and that a multiple-blockholder ownership encourages blockholders to trade competitively and makes this disciplinary device more effective.

References

  • Agastya M, Birulin O (2018) Value of the status quo and efficient partnership dissolution. Int Econ Rev 59:2023–2042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves R, Porter ME (1977) From entry barriers to mobility barriers: conjectural decisions and contrived deterrence to new competition. Quart J Econ 91:241–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cramton P, Gibbons R, Klemperer P (1987) Dissolving a partnership efficiently. Econometrica 55:615–632

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edmans A, Manso G(2011)Governance through trading and intervention: a theory of multiple blockholders, Review of Financial Studies, 24: 2395–2428

  • Gagnepain P, Pereira P (2007) Entry, costs reduction, and competition in the portuguese mobile telephony industry. Int J Ind Organ 25:461–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gresik T, Satterthwaite MA (1989) The rate at which a simple market converges to efficiency as the number of traders increases: an asymptotic result for optimal trading mechanisms. J Econ Theory 48:304–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jehiel P, Pauzner A (2006) Partnership dissolution with interdependent values. Rand J Econ 37:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Y, Pittman R (2013) The proposed merger of AT&T and T-mobile: are there unexhausted scale economies in U.S. mobile telephony? J Compet Law Eco 9:49–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu H, Robert I (2001) Optimal trading mechanisms with Ex Ante unidentified traders. J Econ Theory 97:50–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lu H, Wang Y (2009) Efficient trading with restriction. Rev Econ Des 13:319–334

    Google Scholar 

  • McKenzie D, Small J (1997) Econometric cost structure estimates for cellular telephony in the United States. J Regul Econ 12:147–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P (2004) Putting Auction Theory to Work. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson R, Satterthwaite MA (1983) Efficient mechanism for bilateral trading. J Econ Theory 28:265–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nam C, Kwon Y, Kim S, Lee H (2009) Estimating scale economies of the wireless telecommunications industry using EVA data. Telecommun Policy 33:29–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter ME (1980) Competitive Strategy. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaked A, Sutton J (1983) Natural Oligopolies. Econometrica 51(5):1469–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sheth JN, Sisodia RS (2002) The rule of three: surviving and thriving in competitive markets. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletti T (2003) Is mobile telephony a natural oligopoly? Rev Ind Organ 22:47–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vendruscolo MI, Alves TW (2009) Study of the scale economy in the Brazilian mobile telecommunication sector after privatizations, (in Portuguese). Rev Contab Financ 20:63–78. https://doi.org/10.1590/S1519-70772009000100005

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Cheng-Tai Wu.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of Lemma 1

We first prove that R(q) is the highest revenue that can be generated by any mechanism that implements \( q\left( v\right) \) and satisfies IC and IR. Suppose that (q(v), t(v)) satisfies incentive compatibility. This means that

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})-T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) \ge v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i}^{\prime })-T_{i}\left( v_{i}^{\prime }\right) , \end{aligned}$$

or, equivalently,

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) \ge U_{i}\left( v_{i}^{\prime }\right) +(v_{i}-v_{i}^{\prime })Q_{i}(v_{i}), \end{aligned}$$

which implies that \(U_{i}\) has a supporting hyperplane at \( v_{i}^{\prime }\) with the slope \(Q_{i}(v_{i}^{\prime })\ge 0\) , and hence \(U_{i}(v_{i})\) must be convex and has derivatives \( U_{i}^{\prime }(v_{i})=Q_{i}(v_{i})\) almost everywhere. This also means that \(Q_{i}(v_{i})\) must be increasing in \(v_{i}\) and that

$$\begin{aligned} U\left( v_{i}\right) =U\left( v_{i}^{*}\right) +\int _{v_{i}^{*}}^{v_{i}}Q_{i}(u)du, \end{aligned}$$

where \(v_{i}^{*}\) is the type that gives player i the lowest payoff under (q(v), t(v)), and

$$\begin{aligned} T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =-v_{i}^{*}Q_{i}(v_{i}^{*})+v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})+T_{i}\left( v_{i}^{*}\right) -\int _{v_{i}^{*}}^{v_{i}}Q_{i}(u)du. \end{aligned}$$

Suppose that player \(i \) is a buyer (i.e., \( r_{i}<\alpha \)). In this case, \(v_{i}^{*}=0\), and the highest revenue can be extracted without violating the IR constraint by setting \(U_{i}\left( 0\right) =0.\) This means that \(T_{i}\left( 0\right) =0\) and \(T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})-\int _{0}^{v_{i}}Q_{i}(u)du\). Therefore, the expected revenue from the buyer is

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{0}^{1}T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) f(v_{i})dv_{i}= & {} \int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}-\int _{0}^{1} \int _{0}^{v_{i}}Q_{i}(u)duf(v_{i})dv_{i} \\= & {} \int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}-\int _{0}^{1} \int _{u}^{1}Q_{i}(u)f(v_{i})dv_{i}du \\= & {} \int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}-\int _{0}^{1}Q_{i}(u) \int _{u}^{1}f(v_{i})dv_{i}du \\= & {} \int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}-\int _{0}^{1}Q_{i}(v_{i})\left[ 1-F\left( v_{i}\right) \right] dv_{i} \\= & {} \int _{0}^{1}[v_{i}-\frac{1-F\left( v_{i}\right) }{f\left( v_{i}\right) } ]Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}. \end{aligned}$$

Suppose that player i is a seller (i.e., \(r_{i}\ge \alpha \) ). In this case, \(v_{i}^{*}=1\), and the highest revenue can be extracted without violating the IR constraint by setting \( U_{i}\left( 1\right) =1.\) This means that \(T_{i}\left( 0\right) =0\) and \(T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =-1+v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})-\int _{1}^{v_{i}}Q_{i}(u)du.\) Therefore, the expected revenue from the seller is

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{0}^{1}T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) f(v_{i})dv_{i}= & {} -1+\int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}-\int _{0}^{1} \int _{1}^{v_{i}}Q_{i}(u)duf(v_{i})dv_{i} \\= & {} -1+\int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}+\int _{0}^{1} \int _{0}^{u}Q_{i}(u)f(v_{i})dv_{i}du \\= & {} -1+\int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}+\int _{0}^{1}Q_{i}(u) \int _{0}^{u}f(v_{i})dv_{i}du \\= & {} -1+\int _{0}^{1}v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}+\int _{0}^{1}Q_{i}(v_{i})F \left( v_{i}\right) dv_{i} \\= & {} -1+\int _{0}^{1}[v_{i}+\frac{F\left( v_{i}\right) }{f\left( v_{i}\right) } ]Q_{i}(v_{i})f(v_{i})dv_{i}. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, the expected revenue of a mechanism (q(v), t(v)) that satisfies IC and IR is

$$\begin{aligned} \sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}E(t_{i}(v))= & {} \sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}E(T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) ) \\= & {} \sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}E[v_{i}q_{i}(v)-\int _{v_{i}^{*}}^{v_{i}}q_{i}(u,v_{-i})du]-\sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}U_{i}\left( v_{i}^{*}\right) \\= & {} \sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}E[v_{i}q_{i}(v)-(v_{i}-\phi _{i}(v_{i}))q_{i}(v)]-\sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}U_{i}\left( v_{i}^{*}\right) \\= & {} \sum \limits _{i=1}^{N}E[\phi _{i}(v_{i})q_{i}(v)]-S=R(q), \end{aligned}$$

where the last equality is due to the fact that

$$\begin{aligned} S=\sum \limits _{\left\{ i|r_{i}\ge \alpha \right\} }E[\phi _{i}(v_{i})] \text{, } \end{aligned}$$

which can be seen with integration by parts. This completes the proof of the first point of the Lemma.

The “only if” part of the second point: It follows immediately from the first point that BB is satisfied if \(R(q)\ge 0.\)

The “if” part of the second point: Suppose that q(v) satisfies \(R(q)\ge 0.\) Let

$$\begin{aligned} h_{i}(v_{i})\equiv & {} E_{-i}[v_{i}q_{i}(v_{i},v_{-i})-\int _{v_{i}^{*}}^{v_{i}}q_{i}(u,v_{-i})du]{{\ and}} \nonumber \\ c_{i}\equiv & {} \frac{R(q)}{N}+v_{i}^{*}-\frac{1}{N-1}\sum _{j\ne i}E[\phi _{j}(v_{j}|v_{j}^{*})q_{j}(v)]. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Also let

$$\begin{aligned} t_{i}(v)=h_{i}(v_{i})-\frac{1}{N-1}\sum _{j\ne i}q_{j}(v_{j})-c_{i}, \forall v. \end{aligned}$$

It follows that

$$\begin{aligned} E_{i}[h_{i}(v_{i})]=E[\phi _{i}(v_{i})q_{i}(v)] \end{aligned}$$

and hence

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _{i=1}^{N}c_{i}=0{ {and }}\sum _{i=1}^{N}t_{i}(v)=0, \end{aligned}$$

that is, BB is satisfied. To see that (qt) satisfies IR note that

$$\begin{aligned} T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right)= & {} h_{i}(v_{i})-\frac{1}{N-1}\sum _{j\ne i}E[\phi _{j}(v_{j})q_{j}(v)]-c_{i} \\= & {} h_{i}(v_{i})-\frac{R(q)}{N}-v_{i}^{*}. \end{aligned}$$

Hence, for all \(v_{i},\)

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =E_{-i}[v_{i}q_{i}(v_{i},v_{-i})]-T_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =\int _{v_{i}^{*}}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du+\frac{ R(q)}{N}+v_{i}^{*}, \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(14)

where the second equality is given by (13). Moreover, by the definition of the worst type \(v_{i}^{*},\)

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{0}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du\ge \int _{0}^{v_{i}^{*}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du-v_{i}^{*}=0 \text{ for } \text{ the } \text{ buyer, } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \int _{0}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du-v_{i}\ge \int _{0}^{1}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du-1 \text{ for } \text{ the } \text{ seller }. \end{aligned}$$

It follows from (14) that

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =\int _{0}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du+\frac{ R(q)}{N}\ge 0, \text{ for } \text{ the } \text{ buyer } \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) =\int _{1}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du+\frac{ R(q)}{N}+1\ge 0, \text{ for } \text{ the } \text{ seller, } \end{aligned}$$

that is, IR is satisfied. In addition, to see that \((q\left( v\right) ,t\left( v\right) )\) satisfies IC consider any \(v_{i}\) and \(v_{i}^{^{\prime }}.\) It follows that

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right) -U_{i}\left( v_{i}^{^{\prime }}\right)= & {} \int _{v_{i}^{^{\prime }}}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(u,v_{-i})]du \\\ge & {} \int _{v_{i}^{^{\prime }}}^{v_{i}}E_{-i}[q_{i}(v_{i}^{^{\prime }},v_{-i})]du \\= & {} E_{-i}[v_{i}q_{i}(v_{i}^{^{\prime }},v_{-i})-v_{i}^{^{\prime }}q_{i}(v_{i}^{^{\prime }},v_{-i})]. \end{aligned}$$

This implies that

$$\begin{aligned} U_{i}\left( v_{i}\right)\ge & {} E_{-i}[v_{i}q_{i}(v_{i}^{^{\prime }},v_{-i})]-T_{i}\left( v_{i}^{^{\prime }}\right) \\= & {} v_{i}Q_{i}(v_{i}^{^{\prime }})-T_{i}\left( v_{i}^{^{\prime }}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

which means that IC is satisfied. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chou, E.S., Liang, MY. & Wu, CT. Reorganizing a partnership efficiently. Rev Econ Design 26, 233–246 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10058-021-00266-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10058-021-00266-3

Keywords

Navigation