Skip to main content
Log in

Commodity taxes and rent extraction

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It is difficult for WTO member countries to raise tariffs unilaterally under current WTO regulations. Therefore, given a constant tariff rate, we examine the impacts of two commodity taxes, an ad valorem tax and a specific tax, on the rent-extracting effect regarding the foreign firm and on the protection effect regarding the domestic firm. We obtain two main results. First, the government can extract more profits from the foreign firm by imposing an ad valorem (a specific) tax, when the tariff rate is low (high); and second, when the tariff rate is low, an ad valorem tax is welfare superior to a specific tax while the reverse may occur when the tariff rate is high. This demonstrates that the magnitude of the tariff rate is crucial when the government chooses the commodity tax scheme.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A search using Google Scholar on November 19, 2020 showed that Brander and Spencer (1984) has been cited by 466 papers.

  2. An exception arises under the existence of “bound tariffs”. The tariff rates can be adjusted upwards when tariff rates are below the maximum that the countries agreed on (see the WTO website, https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/tariffs_e/idb_e.htm).

  3. Excise taxes are levied by the forms of the specific and ad valorem taxes. In the real world, we can observe that the governments of the U.S. and Japan impose specific excise taxes on tobacco, alcohol and fuel, and the government of China levies specific excise taxes on alcohol and fuel. Please refer to the following websites: https://taxfoundation.org/state-cigarette-taxes/, https://taxfoundation.org/high-wine-taxes-state/, https://taxfoundation.org/state-gasoline-tax-rates-2017/, and www.nta.go.jp/kohyo/tokei/kokuzeicho/h27/h27.pdf.

  4. Several studies indicate that a specific tax can be welfare superior to an ad valorem tax. They include: Hamilton (1999), Pirttila (2002), Droge and Schroder (2009), Grazzini (2006), and Wang et al. (2018) who employ a partial-equilibrium framework, while Blackorby and Murty (2013) use a general-equilibrium framework. In addition, Azacis and Collie (2018) show that switching from specific to ad valorem taxation under the same collusive price has no effect on the critical discount factor required to sustain collusion, and the tax revenue is always higher under an ad valorem tax than under a specific tax. Liang et al. (2018) analyze the superiority of the specific, demand and cost ad valorem subsidies in industrial and export policies. Both papers measure the ranking of the tax (subsidy) schemes by an identical total output, just as in this paper.

  5. We can allow for \({p}^{{\prime\prime}}\left(Q\right)>0\) in this model. The results derived in this paper remain unchanged if the positive value of \({p}{^{\prime\prime}}\left(Q\right)>0\) is not too large.

  6. We compare the superiority of the two taxes under an identical total output, which is equivalent to analyzing how a change in the tax scheme influences the welfare under the same market price.

  7. In Brander and Spencer (1984), the domestic government can choose an optimal tariff to extract the foreign firm’s profit. In this model, in order to highlight that the domestic government cannot freely raise the tariffs under the regulation of the WTO, we assume that the tariff, T, is a fixed amount.

  8. Please refer to Appendix 1.

  9. From Proposition 3 and (9), we find that \({PS}_{h}^{\tau }\ge {PS}_{h}^{t}\) and \({R}^{\tau }+{TR}^{\tau }\ge \left({R}^{t}+{TR}^{t}\right),\) when \({c}_{h}-{c}_{f}\le T\le {T}_{2}.\)

  10. Under linear demand, we can calculate the equilibrium domestic firm’s output and foreign firm’s output, as well as the equilibrium price as \({q}_{i}^{k}=\frac{(a-2{\tilde{c }}_{i}^{k}+{\tilde{c }}_{j}^{k})}{3},\mathrm{and }\,{p}^{k}=\frac{(a+{\tilde{c }}_{i}^{k}+{\tilde{c }}_{j}^{k})}{3}, i,j=h,f,i\ne j, k=t, \tau ,\mathrm{ respectively}.\)

  11. \(\overline{T }=\left(\left(1-\uptau \right)\mathrm{a}-2{c}_{f}+{c}_{h}\right)/2\) under linear demand. Substituting this into (10), we can obtain that \(4\left(1-\tau \right)\left({c}_{h}-{c}_{f}\right)+{c}_{h}=\tau a\left(1-\tau \right)\) when \({SW}^{\tau }={SW}^{t}\).

  12. A change in the number of foreign firms does not overturn the main results in this paper. In a case where the number of foreign firms changes to n firms and the marginal costs have the following relationship \({c}_{1}<{c}_{2}<\cdots <{c}_{n},\) we show that this change generates the following influences. First, the variable \({c}_{f}\) in the conditions of the inequalities in Propositions 1–3 changes to \(\frac{\sum_{i=1}^{n} {c}_{i}}{n}\). Second, the inequality that causes \({T}_{3}\) to occur in Proposition 4 will be changed. Nevertheless, the result that an ad valorem tax may be worse than a specific tax remains valid in this case. The proofs of the above results are available from the authors upon request.

  13. This is because \(\tau {p}^{\tau }-t>0\) and the total output remains unchanged.

  14. Please find the proof in Appendix 2.

  15. \(\left({q}_{h}^{t}-{q}_{h}^{\tau }\right)<0\) when \({c}_{h}-{c}_{f}<T\le \overline{T }\). Thus, the numerator of \(\frac{d({q}_{f}^{t}-{q}_{f}^{\tau })}{dT}\) is positive as \({p}^{\prime\prime}\left({Q}^{t}\right)\)< 0, or \({p}^{\prime\prime}\left(Q\right)>0\) but the positive value is not too large.

References

  • Anderson SP, de Palma A, Kreider B (2001) The Efficiency of Indirect Taxes under Imperfect Competition. J Public Econ 81:231–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azacis H, Collie DR (2018) Taxation and Sustainability of Collusion: Ad Valorem versus Specific Taxes. J Econ 125:173–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blackorby C, Murty S (2013) Unit versus Ad Valorem Taxes: The Private Ownership of Monopoly in General Equilibrium. Journal of Public Economic Theory 15:547–579

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander J, Spencer BJ (1984) Trade Warfare: Tariffs and Cartels. J Int Econ 16:227–242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Delipalla S, Keen M (1992) The Comparison between Ad valorem and specific taxation under imperfect competition. J Public Econ 49:351–367

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denicolò V, Matteuzzi M (2000) Specific and ad valorem taxation in asymmetric cournot oligopolies. Int Tax Public Financ 7:335–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Droge S, Schroder PJH (2009) The Welfare comparison of corrective AD valorem and unit taxes under monopolistic competition. Int Tax Public Financ 16:164–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grazzini L (2006) A Note on Ad Valorem and Per Unit Taxation in an Oligopoly Model. J Econ 89:59–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton SF (1999) The Comparative Efficiency of Ad Valorem and Specific Taxes under Monopoly and Monopsony. Econ Lett 63:235–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Liang WJ, Wang KCA, Chou PY (2018) The Superiority among Specific, Demand Ad Valorem and Cost Ad Valorem Subsidy Regimes. J Econ 123:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pirttila J (2002) Specific versus Ad Valorem Taxation and Externalities. J Econ 76:177–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skeath SE, Trandel GA (1994) A Pareto Comparison of Ad Valorem and Unit Taxes in Noncompetitive Environments. J Public Econ 53:53–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suits DB, Musgrave RA (1953) Ad Valorem and Unit Taxes Compared. Quart J Econ 67:598–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang KCA, Chou PY, Liang WJ (2018) Specific Versus Ad Valorem Taxes in the Presence of Cost and Quality Differences. Int Tax Public Financ 25(5):1197–1214

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are indebted to the editor and two anonymous referees for inducing us to improve our exposition and for offering several suggestions leading to improvements in the substance of the paper. The first author would like to thank for the financial support from Ministry of Science and Technology, Taiwan (MOST 106-2410-H-182-002-MY2).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Wen-Jung Liang.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix 1

The proof of \({{\varvec{T}}}_{1}\in ({{\varvec{c}}}_{{\varvec{h}}}-{{\varvec{c}}}_{{\varvec{f}}}, \overline{{\varvec{T}} })\)

(1) \({R}^{\tau }-{R}^{t}>0\) when \(T={c}_{h}-{c}_{f},\) and \({R}^{\tau }-{R}^{t}<0\) when \(T=\overline{T }\).

(2) By (4), we can derive the influences of T on the equilibrium \({p}^{\tau }\), \({q}_{f}^{\tau },\) and \({q}_{f}^{t}\) as follows:

$$\frac{{dp^{\tau } }}{{dT}} = \frac{1}{{\left( {1 - \tau } \right)}}\frac{{p'\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)}}{{3p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right) + p''\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)Q^{\tau } }} > 0,$$
(12)
$$\frac{{dq_{f}^{\tau } }}{{dT}} = \frac{1}{{\left( {1 - \tau } \right)}}\frac{{2p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right) + p''\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)q_{h}^{\tau } }}{{\left( {3p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right) + p^{\prime\prime}\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)Q^{\tau } } \right)p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)}} < 0,$$
(13)
$$\frac{{dq_{f}^{t} }}{{dT}} = \frac{1}{{\left( {1 - \tau } \right)}}\frac{{2p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right) + p^{\prime\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right)q_{h}^{t} + \left( {\frac{\tau }{{2\left( {1 - \tau } \right)}}} \right)\left( {p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right) + p^{\prime\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right)\left( {q_{h}^{t} - q_{f}^{t} } \right)} \right)}}{{\left( {3p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right) + p^{\prime\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right)Q^{t} } \right)p^{\prime}\left( {Q^{t} } \right)}} < 0$$
(14)

Differentiating (8) with respect to T gives:

$$\frac{d({R}^{T}-{R}^{t})}{dT}=\frac{d(\tau {p}^{\tau }-t)}{dT}{q}_{f}^{\tau }+(\tau {p}^{\tau }-t)\frac{d{q}_{f}^{\tau }}{dT}-t\frac{d({q}_{f}^{t}-{q}_{f}^{\tau })}{dT}$$
(15)

By using (12, 13 ,14) and \({Q}^{t}={Q}^{\tau },\) we can obtain \(\frac{{d\left( {\tau p^{\tau } - t} \right)}}{{dT}} = \left( {\frac{{ - \tau }}{{1 - \tau }}} \right)\frac{{p^{\prime } \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right) + p^{{\prime \prime }} \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)Q^{\tau } }}{{3p^{\prime } \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right) + p^{{\prime \prime }} \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)Q^{\tau } }}\; < 0,\;\frac{{dq_{f}^{\tau } }}{{dT}}{\text{ }} < 0\;and~\frac{{d\left( {q_{f}^{t} - q_{f}^{\tau } } \right)}}{{dT}} = \frac{1}{{3p^{\prime } \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right) + p^{{\prime \prime }} \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)Q^{\tau } }}\left[ {\frac{{ - 3\tau p^{\prime } \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)}}{{2\left( {1 - \tau } \right)}} + \frac{{p^{{\prime \prime }} \left( {Q^{\tau } } \right)(\left( {2\left( {q_{h}^{t} - q_{h}^{\tau } } \right) - \tau \left( {\left( {q_{h}^{t} + q_{f}^{\tau } } \right)} \right)} \right)}}{{2\left( {1 - \tau } \right)}}} \right] > 0\).Footnote 15 By substituting these inequalities into (15), we obtain that \(\frac{d({R}^{T}-{R}^{t})}{dT}<0.\)

(3) We can find from (1) and (2) that there exists a threshold value \({T}_{1}\in ({c}_{h}-{c}_{f}, \overline{T })\) such that \(T<(\ge ){T}_{1}\) if and only if \({R}^{\tau }-{R}^{t}\)> (\(\le\)) 0.

Appendix 2

The impact of an increase in the specific tax rate t on social welfare

Given a linear demand function, \(p=a-Q\), the equilibrium outputs and price can be obtained as follows:

$${q}_{f}^{\tau }=\frac{a-t-2\left({c}_{f}+T\right)+{c}_{h}}{3}, {q}_{h}^{\tau }=\frac{a-t-2{c}_{h}+\left({c}_{f}+T\right)}{3}, {Q}^{t}=\frac{2\left(a-t\right)-\left({c}_{f}+T\right)-{c}_{h}}{3}, {p}^{t}=\frac{a+2t+\left({c}_{f}+T\right)+{c}_{h}}{3}.$$
(16)

The social welfare under a specific tax can be described as \({SW}^{t}={TR}^{t}+{R}^{t}+{PS}_{h}^{t}+{CS}^{t}\), where \({CS}^{t}\) is the consumer surplus under a specific tax. From (16), we can obtain:

$$\frac{{dSW^{t} }}{{dt}} = \frac{{\left( { - 2\left( {t + T} \right) - c_{f} + c_{h} } \right)}}{3} < 0,\,~for\,~T \ge c_{h} - c_{f} ,$$
(17)

Given the social welfare under an ad valorem tax and by (17), we can find that the value of \({T}_{3}\) in Proposition 4 rises.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wang, KC.A., Chou, PY. & Liang, WJ. Commodity taxes and rent extraction. J Econ 135, 285–297 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00758-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-021-00758-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation