Skip to main content
Log in

Bounded rationality and heterogeneous expectations: Euler versus anticipated-utility approach

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

By using Bayesian techniques, our paper investigates behavioral New-Keynesian DSGE models derived under two parsimonious alternatives to introduce heterogeneous expectations: the Euler equation and the anticipated-utility approach. First, we explore the relation between the expectation formation processes and the model determinacy for a broad range of parameterizations by using global sensitivity analysis and Monte Carlo filtering. Second, we perform model comparison to assess how much the two alternatives are consistent with macro and expectation survey data. Our main results are twofold: (1) model determinacy is strongly undermined by the presence of boundedly rational agents; (2) a behavioral model based on Euler equation approach fits the data decisively better than one based on anticipated utility.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We refer to Eusepi and Preston (2018) and Hommes and LeBaron (2018) for details.

  2. This robustness exercise to which we refer as mixed models, is in line with Evans et al. (2019) who, contributing to the learning literature, test through laboratory experiments the consequences, in terms of convergence to the rational expectation equilibrium, of the coexistence of both types of forecasters.

  3. Similar attempts of examining the importance of the forecasting horizon are discussed in Branch et al. (2013), Branch and McGough (2016) and Woodford (2018).

  4. Mankiw et al. (2004) is the main reference. Early studies are Roberts (1997) and Campbell and Mankiw (1989). Similar results are also obtained by Carroll (2003), Branch (2004), Andolfatto et al. (2008), Pfajfar and Santoro (2010), Andrade and Le Bihan (2013), Coibion and Gorodnichenko (2015), Dovern (2015) and Dräger et al. (2016).

  5. See Hommes et al. (2005), Adam (2007), Hommes (2011) and Evans et al. (2019).

  6. It should be noted that both deal with an aggregation issue among agents, which however in larger models (e.g., medium-scale) could be more complex and its solution less robust than the assumptions imposed to solve it.

  7. See Di Bartolomeo et al. (2016), Di Bartolomeo et al. (2019)  and Hommes and LeBaron (2018, Chapter 1, 2.38) for a discussion on assuming constant beliefs.

  8. The assumption does not affect the empirical estimations, but it seems the most reasonable.

  9. A risk sharing mechanism is introduced to insure against the Calvo price adjustment. We refer to Branch and McGough (2009) and Massaro (2013) for details.

  10. Note that we have considered the market clearing condition: \(y_{t}=c_{t}\).

  11. As discussed later, we also test the robustness of our result to alternative specifications of monetary policy.

  12. Branch and McGough (2009) and Massaro (2013) extended these approaches to heterogeneous expectations. The underlying ideas are due to Preston (2005) and Evans and Honkapohja (2006).

  13. A full derivation is provided by Massaro (2013) or Beqiraj et al. (2017).

  14. The rationale for assuming a fixed \(\alpha\) also lies in the general aim of evaluating the consistency to the data of the two mentioned EE and AU approaches, as theoretically derived by Branch and McGough (2009) and Massaro (2013), respectively.

  15. See Hommes and LeBaron (2018, Chapter 1, 2.38) for a general discussion on assuming a constant fraction of rational agents. For time varying estimations, see, e.g., Milani (2006, 2011), who focuses on homogeneous agents with learning.

  16. Some minimal restrictions to the heuristics used by the agents are imposed to aggregate (Branch and McGough 2009).

  17. See Hommes and LeBaron (2018, Chapter 1, 2.38).

  18. The start of our sample is selected to coincide with the Great Moderation while the end is chosen in order to avoid dealing with the zero-lower bound on nominal interest rate.

  19. See Milani (2007) and Del Negro and Eusepi (2011).

  20. The need of adding a measurement error to the inflation arises mainly for two reasons. First, its introduction helps the inversion of the Hessian matrix computed at the posterior mode. Second, it improves the model fit, in particular by looking at the sign of the cross-correlation between inflation and output.

  21. Technical issues deriving from misspecification are widely discussed in Lubik and Schorfheide (2006) and Fernández-Villaverde (2010).

  22. However, to initialize the priors and to facilitate the estimation, we preliminarly explored the parameter space by a Monte Carlo Filtering (MCF) technique. The analysis was performed using the Global Sensitivity Analysis (GSA). Details are reported in the Appendix.

  23. In our estimation \(\alpha\) is fixed. However, we also estimate a version of our models where \(\alpha\) is allowed to be time varying, i.e., by assuming that \(\alpha _{t}\) follows an AR(1) stationary process with non-zero mean. Parameters estimate and likelihood comparison are equal to the ones reported along this next section; modeling \(\alpha\) as a time varying parameter has negligible effects on the model fit. A different empirical strategy in estimating \(\alpha _{t}\) as a time varying parameter is considered in Cornea-Madeira et al. (2017).

  24. We check the correct identification of the subset of estimated parameters implementing the identification condition developed by Iskrev (2010a, b). For a review of identification issues arising in DSGE models, see Canova and Sala (2009).

  25. It is worth noting that identifying the determinacy region of the model is also a fundamental preliminary step in a Bayesian approach. It allows to initialize the estimation within the portion of the acceptable domain of model coefficients, excluding indeterminacy or instability.

  26. This analysis is performed using the Global Sensitivity Analysis (GSA) toolbox for Dynare.

  27. We used Dynare MatLab routines to simulate and estimate the models (see Adjemian et al. 2011).

  28. For an exhaustive analysis of Bayesian estimation methods, see Geweke (1999), An and Schorfheide (2007), Kriwoluzky and Herbst (2017) or Fernández-Villaverde (2010).

  29. For a similar approach, see, e.g., Rabanal and Rubio-Ramirez (2005), Riggi and Tancioni (2010), and Di Bartolomeo and Di Pietro (2017).

  30. Jeffreys (1961) developed a scale to evaluate the Bayes factor indication. Odds ranging from 1:1 to 3:1 give “very slight evidence”, odds from 3:1 to 10:1 are “substantial”, odds from 10:1 to 100:1 give “strong to very strong evidence”, and odds greater than 100:1 are “decisive evidence”.

  31. Estimates of the standard New Keynesian model are available upon request.

  32. Results are available upon request.

  33. It is worth noting that mixed models need further technical clarifications regarding the underlying assumptions on heterogeneous expectations and the structure of higher-order beliefs. See the longer working paper version of this article for details, i.e., Beqiraj et al. (2018).

  34. Other results are available upon request. Indeed, we do not consider (and estimate) the case where firms use EE heuristics and households have long-horizon beliefs since it never fulfills the determinacy region.

  35. Results of the GSA for the mixed model are available upon request.

  36. Previously, we had not considered the smoothing parameters to strictly follow the specifications proposed by Branch and McGough (2009) and Massaro (2013), who inspect the stability properties of the EE and AU models without considering smoothing in the Taylor rule.

  37. Results are available upon request.

  38. Details on estimates are available upon request.

  39. As t increases, the log-marginal likelihood of this model specification becomes similar to that associated with an AU model.

References

  • Adam K (2007) Optimal monetary policy with imperfect common knowledge. J Monet Econ 54(2):267–301

    Google Scholar 

  • Adjemian S, Bastani H, Juillard M, Karamé F, Mihoubi F, Perendia G, Pfeifer J, Ratto M, Villemot S (2011) Dynare: reference manual, version 4. Dynare Working Papers, 1, CEPREMAP

  • An S, Schorfheide F (2007) Bayesian analysis of DSGE models. Econom Rev 26(2–4):113–172

    Google Scholar 

  • Andolfatto D, Hendry S, Moran K (2008) Are inflation expectations rational? J Monet Econ 55(2):406–422

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrade P, Le Bihan H (2013) Inattentive professional forecasters. J Monet Econ 60(8):967–982

    Google Scholar 

  • Beqiraj E, Di Bartolomeo G, Serpieri C (2017) Rational vs. long-run forecasters: optimal monetary policy and the role of inequality. Macroeconomic Dynamics (preprint available on-online) (forthcoming)

  • Beqiraj E, Di Bartolomeo G, Di Pietro M, Serpieri C (2018) Bounded-rationality and heterogeneous agents: long or short forecasters? JRC Working Papers JRC111392, Joint Research Centre

  • Berardi M (2009) Monetary policy with heterogeneous and misspecified expectations. J Money Credit Bank 41(1):79–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Bils M, Klenow PJ (2004) Some evidence on the importance of sticky prices. J Polit Econ 112(5):947–985

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Kahn CM (1980) The solution of linear difference models under rational expectations. Econometrica 48(5):1305–1311

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch WA (2004) The theory of rationally heterogeneous expectations: evidence from survey data on inflation expectations. Econ J 114(497):592–621

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch WA, McGough B (2009) A New Keynesian model with heterogeneous expectations. J Econ Dyn Control 33(5):1036–1051

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch WA, McGough B (2016) Heterogeneous expectations and micro-foundations in macroeconomics. In: Schmedders K, Judd KL (eds) Handbook of computational economics, vol 4. Elsevier Science, North-Holland

    Google Scholar 

  • Branch WA, Evans GW, McGough B (2013) Finite horizon learning. In: Sargent TJ, Vilmunen J (eds) Macroeconomics at the service of public policy. Oxford University Press, Oxford (Chap. 8)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullard J, Mitra K (2002) Learning about monetary policy rules. J Monet Econ 49(6):1105–1129

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo GA (1983) Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. J Monet Econ 12(3):383–398

    Google Scholar 

  • Canova F, Sala L (2009) Back to square one: Identification issues in DSGE models. J Monet Econ 56(4):431–449

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JY, Mankiw NG (1989) Consumption, income, and interest rates: reinterpreting the time series evidence. In: Blanchard OJ, Fischer S (eds) NBER macroeconomics annual 1989, vol 4. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 185–216

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornea-Madeira A, Hommes C, Massaro M (2017) Behavioral heterogeneity in US inflation dynamics. J Bus Econ Stat 2017:1–13

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll C (2003) Macroeconomic expectations of households and professional forecasters. Q J Econ 118(1):269–298

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Galí J, Gertler M (2000) Monetary policy rules and macroeconomic stability: evidence and some theory. Q J Econ 115(1):147–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Coibion O, Gorodnichenko Y (2015) Information rigidity and the expectations formation process: a simple framework and new facts. Am Econ Rev 105(8):2644–2678

    Google Scholar 

  • Del Negro M, Eusepi S (2011) Fitting observed inflation expectations. J Econ Dyn Control 35:2105–2131

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Bartolomeo G, Di Pietro M (2017) Intrinsic persistence of wage inflation in New Keynesian models of the business cycles. J Money Credit Bank 49:1161–1195

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Bartolomeo G, Di Pietro M, Giannini B (2016) Optimal monetary policy in a New Keynesian model with heterogeneous expectations. J Econ Dyn Control 73:373–387

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Bartolomeo G, Beqiraj E, Di Pietro M (2019) Beliefs formation and the puzzle of forward guidance power. J Macroecon 60:20–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Diks C, Van Der Weide R (2005) Herding, a-synchronous updating and heterogeneity in memory in a CBS. J Econ Dyn Control 29(4):741–763

    Google Scholar 

  • Dovern J (2015) A multivariate analysis of forecast disagreement: Confronting models of disagreement with survey data. Eur Econ Rev 80:16–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Dräger L, Laml MJ, Pfajfar D (2016) Are survey expectations theory-consistent? The role of central bank communication and news. Eur Econ Rev 85:84–111

    Google Scholar 

  • Eusepi S, Preston B (2018) The science of monetary policy: an imperfect knowledge perspective. J Econ Lit 56:3–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans GW, Honkapohja S (2006) Monetary policy, expectations and commitment. Scand J Econ 108:15–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans G, Hommes C, McGough B, Salle I (2019) Are long-horizon expectations (De-) stabilizing? Theory and experiments. Bank of Canada Staff Working Paper 2019-27

  • Fernández-Villaverde J (2010) The econometrics of DSGE models. SERIEs Span Econ Assoc 1(1):3–49

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuhrer J (2011) Inflation persistence. In: Friedman BJ, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 3A. Elsevier, North-Holland, pp 423–483

    Google Scholar 

  • Gasteiger E (2014) Heterogeneous expectations, optimal monetary policy, and the merit of policy inertia. J Monet Credit Bank 46(7):1533–1554

    Google Scholar 

  • Gasteiger E (2017) Optimal constrained interest-rate rules under heterogeneous expectations. Mimeo

  • Gasteiger E (2018) Do heterogeneous expectations constitute a challenge for policy interaction? Mimeo. Macroeconomic Dynamics (forthcoming)

  • Geweke J (1999) Using simulation methods for Bayesian econometric models: Inference, development and communication. Econom Rev 18(1):1–73

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes C (2011) The heterogeneous expectations hypothesis: some evidence from the lab. J Econ Dyn Control 35(1):1–24

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes C, LeBaron B (2018) Heterogeneous agent modeling, volume 4 of handbook of computational economics. Elsevier, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Hommes C, Sonnemans J, Tuinstra J, van de Velden H (2005) Coordination of expectations in asset pricing experiments. Rev Financ Stud 18(3):955–980

    Google Scholar 

  • Honkapohja S, Mitra K, Evans GW (2013) Notes on agents’ behavioral rules under adaptive learning and studies of monetary policy. In: Sargent TJ, Vilmunen J (eds) Macroeconomics at the service of public policy. Oxford University Press, Oxford (Chap. 4)

    Google Scholar 

  • Iskrev N (2010a) Local identification in DSGE models. J Monet Econ 57(2):189–202

    Google Scholar 

  • Iskrev N (2010b) Evaluating the strength of identification in DSGE models. An a priori approach. Working papers w201032, Banco de Portugal, 1-70

  • Jeffreys H (1961) Theory of probability. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaplan G, Moll B, Violante GL (2018) Monetary policy according to HANK. Am Econ Rev 108(3):697–743

    Google Scholar 

  • Kass RE, Raftery AE (1995) Bayes factors. J Am Stat Assoc 90(430):773–795

    Google Scholar 

  • Klenow P, Malin BA (2011) Microeconomic evidence on price-setting. In: Friedman BJ, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of monetary economics, vol 3A. Elsevier Science, North-Holland, pp 231–284

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps D (1998) Anticipated utility and dynamic choice. In: Jacobs D, Kalai E, Kamien M (eds) Frontiers of research in economic theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 242–274

    Google Scholar 

  • Kriwoluzky A, Herbst P (2017) Edward and Schorfheide, Frank: Bayesian estimation of DSGE models. J Econ 120(1):91–93

    Google Scholar 

  • Lubik TA, Schorfheide F (2006) A Bayesian look at new open economy macroeconomics. In: Gertler M, Rogoff K (eds) NBER macroeconomics annual 2005, vol 20. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 316–366

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw NG, Reis R, Wolfers J (2004) Disagreement about inflation expectations. In: Gertler M, Rogoff K (eds) NBER macroeconomics annual 2003, vol 18. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 209–270

    Google Scholar 

  • Massaro D (2013) Heterogeneous expectations in monetary DSGE models. J Econ Dyn Control 37(3):680–692

    Google Scholar 

  • Milani F (2006) A Bayesian DSGE model with infinite-horizon learning: do mechanical sources of persistence become superfluous? Int J Central Bank September:87–106

  • Milani F (2007) Expectations, learning and macroeconomic persistence. J Monet Econ 54(7):2065–2082

    Google Scholar 

  • Milani F (2011) Expectation shocks and learning as drivers of the business cycle. Econ J 121(552):379–401

    Google Scholar 

  • Minetti R, Araujo L (2010) Markets and relationships in a learning economy. Rev Econ Dyn 13(3):687–700

    Google Scholar 

  • Minetti R, Herrera AM (2007) Informed finance and technological change: evidence from credit relationships. J Financ Econ 83(1):223–269

    Google Scholar 

  • Ormeño A, Molnár K (2015) Using survey data of inflation expectations in the estimation of learning and rational expectations models. J Money Credit Bank 47(4):673–699

    Google Scholar 

  • Pfajfar D, Santoro E (2010) Heterogeneity, learning and information stickiness in inflation expectations. J Econ Behav Organ 75(3):426–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Preston B (2005) Learning about monetary policy rules when long-horizon expectations matter. Int J Central Bank 1:81–126

    Google Scholar 

  • Preston B (2006) Adaptive learning, forecast-based instrument rules and monetary policy. J Monet Econ 53(3):507–535

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabanal P, Rubio-Ramirez JF (2005) Comparing New Keynesian models of the business cycles: a Bayesian approach. J Monet Econ 52(6):1151–1166

    Google Scholar 

  • Ratto M (2008) Analysing DSGE models with global sensitivity analysis. Comput Econ 31(2):115–139

    Google Scholar 

  • Riggi M, Tancioni M (2010) Nominal vs. real wage rigidities in New Keynesian models with hiring costs: a Bayesian evaluation. J Econ Dyn Control 34(7):1305–1324

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts JM (1997) Is inflation sticky? J Monet Econ 39(2):173–196

    Google Scholar 

  • Slobodyan S, Wouters R (2012a) Learning in a medium-scale DSGE model with expectations based on small forecasting models. Am Econ J Macroecon 4(2):65–101

    Google Scholar 

  • Slobodyan S, Wouters R (2012b) Learning in an estimated medium-scale DSGE model. J Econ Dyn Control 36(1):26–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Smets F, Wouters R (2007) Shock and frictions in US business cycles: a Bayesian DSGE approach. Am Econ Rev 97(3):586–606

    Google Scholar 

  • Weder M (2002) On forecasting heterogeneity, irrational exuberance, and the multiplicity of rational expectations equilibria. J Econ 76(3):201–215

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (2018) Monetary policy analysis when planning horizons are finite. In: NBER macroeconomics annual 2008, p 33

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors are grateful to the Journal Editor, Giacomo Corneo, two anonymous referees, Boragan Aruoba, Pok-sang Lam, Raoul Minetti, Willi Semmler, Patrizio Tirelli, and seminar participants at ECB, JRC, MMF and Rome for useful comments. They also acknowledge financial support by Sapienza University of Rome. The author(s) declared the following potential conflicts of interest with respect to the research, authorship, and/or publication of this article. The authors are solely responsible for the content of the paper. The views expressed are purely those of the authors and may not in any circumstances be regarded as stating an official position of the European Commission or the Italian Ministry of Economy and Finance.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giovanni Di Bartolomeo.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Beqiraj, E., Di Bartolomeo, G., Di Pietro, M. et al. Bounded rationality and heterogeneous expectations: Euler versus anticipated-utility approach. J Econ 130, 249–273 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00697-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-020-00697-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation