Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Progressive taxation as an automatic destabilizer under endogenous growth

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

It has been shown that in an otherwise standard one-sector real business cycle model with an indeterminate steady state under laissez faire, sufficiently progressive income taxation may stabilize the economy against aggregate fluctuations caused by agents’ animal spirits. We show that this previous finding can be overturned within an identical model which allows for sustained endogenous growth. Specifically, progressive taxation may operate like an automatic destabilizer that leads to equilibrium indeterminacy and sunspot-driven cyclical fluctuations in an endogenously growing macroeconomy. This instability result is obtained under two tractable progressive tax policy formulations that have been considered in the existing literature.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In a similar vein, Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe (1997) show that equilibrium indeterminacy can arise within standard one-sector RBC models under constant returns-to-scale in production and a balanced-budget rule where fixed government spending is financed by proportional taxation on labor or total income. This fiscal formulation is qualitatively equivalent to regressive income taxation that may destabilize the no-growth macroeconomy.

  2. It is straightforward to show that as in the no-growth counterpart, progressive income taxation may work like an automatic stabilizer in the exogenous-growth version of Banhabib and Farmer’s (1994) model.

  3. There has been an extensive literature that explores the macroeconomic effects of various tax policies in an endogenous growth setting with useful public expenditures that contribute to firms’ productivity and/or households’ utility. See, for example, Barro (1990), Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1992), Futagami et al. (1993), Glomm and Ravikumar (1994, 1997), Cazzavillan (1996), Turnovsky (1997, 1999), Zhang (2000), Baier and Glomm (2001), Yamarik (2001), Palivos et al. (2003), Park and Philippopoulos (2002), Li and Sarte (2004), Chen (2006), Greiner (2006, 2007), Slobodyan (2006), and Hu et al. (2008), among others.

  4. By contrast, Chen et al. (2018) find that progressive taxation may operate like an automatic stabilizer within a two-sector RBC model which exhibits social constant returns in production and utility linearity in consumption.

  5. In order for a balanced-growth equilibrium to exist in our model economy, the household’s taxable income \(y_{t}\) needs to grow at the same rate as the baseline level of output \(y_{t}^{*}\). The constant growth rate \(\theta \) for \(y_{t}^{*}\) will be endogenously determined through the model’s equilibrium conditions (see Eq. 21).

  6. Notice that \(k_{0}\) does not introduce an initial condition to the dynamical system (17)–(18) because the period-0 values of \( h_{0}\) and \(c_{0}\) are both endogenously determined.

  7. It can be shown that along any balanced-growth equilibrium path, \(z^{*}>\rho \) since every term on the right-hand-side of Eq. (19) is positive. Moreover, since \(0<\phi <1\) and \(\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-1-\gamma <0\), the second bracket term in the denominator of (24), i.e. \(\left[ \left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-1-\gamma \right] \), is negative.

  8. Notice that the left-hand-side of (28) is decreasing with respect to \(\hat{\phi }\), whereas the right-hand-side is monotonically increasing. It follows that there will be a unique intersection that determines \(\hat{\phi }\) .

  9. Since \(0<\alpha <1\), the bracket term in the numerator of (29) is greater than \(\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-\left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1+\gamma \right) \), which can be rewritten as \(\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-1-\gamma +\phi \left( 1+\gamma \right) >0\).

  10. Given \(\alpha =\frac{1}{3}\) and \(\gamma =0\), the minimum level of labor externalities in firms’ production that satisfies the condition needed for the possibility of multiple interior BGP’s, \(\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-1-\gamma >0\), is \(\chi _{\min }=0.51\). The (in)stability results reported in this subsection remain qualitatively unchanged over the range of \(\chi \in [0.51\), 0.8], where \(\chi =0.8\) leading to \(\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )=1.2\) is considered by Benhabib and Farmer (1994, p. 38) in their quantitative analysis.

  11. Given the baseline parameterization mentioned above, the two eigenvalues associated with the high-growth BGP are found to be real and negative. This result continues to hold when \(\chi \) takes alternative values from the interval [0.51, 0.8].

  12. In particular, plugging \(\phi =0\) into Eq. (A.5) in Appendix A leads to \(h_{t}=\left[ \frac{Az_{t}}{\eta \left( 1-\alpha \right) }\right] ^{\frac{ 1}{\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-1-\gamma }}\). We then substitute this expression into (A.2) and (A.4) to derive the differential equation (31).

  13. The derivation details for all equations in this section are available upon request.

  14. It can be shown that along the economy’s balanced growth path, \(h^{*}= \left[ \frac{Az^{*}}{\left( 1-\tau \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) } \right] ^{\frac{1}{\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )-1-\gamma }},\)\(x^{*}=\frac{E_{0}}{k_{0}\left( h^{*}\right) ^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )}}\) and \(\theta =\alpha \left( 1-\tau \right) \left( h^{*}\right) ^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) (1+\chi )}-\delta -\rho .\)

  15. It is straightforward to show that the plot of \(\Psi \left( \cdot \right) \) on the right-hand-side of (44) is an upward-sloping and convex curve that begins at the origin. As a result, this locus will intersect the 45-degree line once in the positive quadrant, which in turn determines the unique \(\hat{E}\).

References

  • Baier SL, Glomm G (2001) Long-run growth and welfare effects of public policies with distortionary taxation. J Econ Dyn Control 25:2007–2042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ (1990) Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. J Polit Econ 98:S103–S125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro RJ, Sala-i-Martin X (1992) Public finances in models of economic growth. Rev Econ Stud 59:645–661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib J, Farmer REA (1994) Indeterminacy and increasing returns. J Econ Theory 63:19–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosi S, Seegmuller T (2010) On the role of progressive taxation in a Ramsey model with heterogeneous households. J Math Econ 46:977–996

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cazzavillan G (1996) Public spending, endogenous growth, and endogenous fluctuations. J Econ Theory 71:394–415

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chari VV, Christiano Lawrence J, Kehoe Patrick J (1994) Optimal fiscal policy in a business cycle model. J Polit Econ 102:617–652

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen B-L (2006) Public capital, endogenous growth, and endogenous fluctuations. J Macroecon 28:768–774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen B-L, Hsu M, Hsu Y-S (2018) Progressive taxation and macroeconomic stability in two-sector models with social constant returns. J Econ. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-018-0596-2

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-H, Guo J-T (2013a) Progressive taxation and macroeconomic (in)stability with productive government spending. J Econ Dyn Control 37:951–963

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-H, Guo J-T (2013b) On indeterminacy and growth under progressive taxation and productive government spending. Can J Econ 46:865–880

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-H, Guo J-T (2014) Progressive taxation and macroeconomic (In)stability with utility-generating government spending. J Macroecon 42:174–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-H, Guo J-T (2016a) Progressive taxation, endogenous growth, and macroeconomic (In)stability. Bull Econ Res 68(S1):20–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S-H, Guo J-T (2016b) On indeterminacy and growth under progressive taxation and utility-generating government spending, forthcoming in Pac Econ Rev

  • Dromel NL, Pintus PA (2007) Linearly progressive income taxes and stabilization. Res Econ 61:25–29

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Futagami K, Morita Y, Shibata A (1993) Dynamic analysis of an endogenous growth model with public capital. Scand J Econ 95:607–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm G, Ravikumar B (1994) Public investment in infrastructure in a simple growth model. J Econ Dyn Control 18:1173–1187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm G, Ravikumar B (1997) Productive government expenditures and long-run growth. J Econ Dyn Control 21:183–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner A (2006) Progressive taxation, public capital, and endogenous growth. FinazArchiv 62:353–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner A (2007) An endogenous growth model with public capital and sustainable government debt. Jpn Econ Rev 58:345–361

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo J-T, Harrison SG (2015) Indeterminacy with progressive taxation and sector-specific externalities. Pac Econ Rev 20:268–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo J-T, Lansing KJ (1998) Indeterminacy and stabilization policy. J Econ Theory 82:481–490

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu Y, Ohdoi R, Shimomura K (2008) Indeterminacy in a two-sector endogenous growth model with productive government spending. J Macroecon 30:1104–1123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li W, Sarte P-D (2004) Progressive taxation and long-run growth. Am Econ Rev 94:1705–1716

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palivos T, Yip CY, Zhang J (2003) Transitional dynamics and indeterminacy of equilibria in an endogenous growth model with a public input. Rev Dev Econ 7:86–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park H, Philippopoulos A (2002) Dynamics of taxes, public services, and endogenous growth. Macroecon Dyn 6:187–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohé S, Uribe M (1997) Balanced-budget rules, distortionary taxes and aggregate instability. J Polit Econ 105:976–1000

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slobodyan S (2006) One sector models, indeterminacy and productive public spending, CERGE-EI working paper series no. 293

  • Turnovsky SJ (1997) Fiscal policy in a growing economy with public capital. Macroecon Dyn 1:615–639

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnovsky SJ (1999) Productive government expenditures in a stochastically growing economy. Macroecon Dyn 3:544–570

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamarik S (2001) Nonlinear tax structures and endogenous growth. Manch Sch 69:16–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zhang J (2000) Public services, increasing returns, and equilibrium dynamics. J Econ Dyn Control 24:227–246

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Giacomo Corneo (Editor-in-Chief), two anonymous referees, Gabriele Camera, Juin-Jen Chang, Been-Lon Chen, Hung-Ju Chen, Shin-ichi Fukuda, Jinill Kim, Ching-Chong Lai, Yiting Li, Shian-Yu Liao, David Malueg, Kazuo Mino, Victor Ortego-Marti, Cheng Wang, Yan Zhang, and seminar participants at Shanghai University of Economics and Finance, Fudan University, National Tsing Hua University, National Taiwan University, University of Hong Kong, Academia Sinica, Kobe University, National Sun Yat-Sen University (Taiwan), University of Macau, Soochow University, Chapman University, Korea University, Sun Yat-Sen University (China), Califorina State University Los Angeles, Society for the Advancement of Economic Theory Conference, Asian Meeting of the Econometric Society, Annual Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance, Annual Conference of the Asia-Pacific Economic Association, Taiwan Economics Research Workshop, Annual Meeting of the Taiwan Economic Association, Taipei International Conference on “Growth, Trade and Dynamics”, Biennial Conference of Hong Kong Economic Association, China Meeting of the Econometric Society, Annual Conference of the Western Economic Association, and Singapore Economic Review Conference for helpful comments and suggestions. Part of this research was conducted while Guo was a visiting research fellow of economics at Academia Sinica, Taipei, Taiwan, whose hospitality is greatly appreciated. Of course, all remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jang-Ting Guo.

Appendices

Appendix A

Derivations of the dynamical system (17)–(18) Combining Eqs. (11) and (13) leads to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{c}_{t}}{c_{t}}=\eta (1-\phi )\left( \frac{y_{t}^{*}}{y_{t}} \right) ^{\phi }\alpha h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }-\delta -\rho . \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

In addition, Eqs. (15) and (16) can be rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{g_{t}}{k_{t}}= & {} \left[ 1-\eta \left( \frac{y_{t}^{*}}{y_{t}}\right) ^{\phi }\right] h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }, \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{k}_{t}}{k_{t}}= & {} h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }-z_{t}-\frac{g_{t}}{k_{t}}-\delta ,\text { where }z_{t}\equiv \frac{c_{t}}{k_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

From the above (A.1)–(A.3), we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{z}_{t}}{z_{t}}=\left[ \left( 1-\phi \right) \alpha -1\right] \left[ h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }-\frac{g_{t}}{ k_{t}}\right] -\rho +z_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

Next, using the economy’s aggregate production function (3), Eq. (12) can rewritten as

$$\begin{aligned} Ah_{t}^{1+\gamma }=\frac{\eta (1-\phi )u_{t}^{\phi }\left( 1-\alpha \right) h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }}{z_{t}},\text { where }u_{t}\equiv \frac{y_{t}^{*}}{y_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)

Taking time derivatives on the both sides of (A.5) yields that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{z}_{t}}{z_{t}}=\phi \frac{\dot{u}_{t}}{u_{t}}+[\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) -1-\gamma ]\frac{\dot{h}_{t}}{h_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

From Eqs. (A.4) and (A.6), we find that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{u}_{t}}{u_{t}}= & {} \frac{\left[ \left( 1-\phi \right) \alpha -1\right] \left[ h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }-\frac{g_{t}}{ k_{t}}\right] -\rho +z_{t}}{\phi }\nonumber \\&-\left[ \frac{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) -1-\gamma }{\phi }\right] \frac{\dot{h}_{t}}{h_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

On the other hand, we use Eqs. (3) and (A.3) to obtain

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{u}_{t}}{u_{t}}=\theta -\frac{\dot{y}_{t}}{y_{t}}=\theta -h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }+z_{t}+\frac{g_{t}}{ k_{t}}+\delta -\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) \frac{\dot{h} _{t}}{h_{t}},\text { where }\theta =\frac{\dot{y}_{t}^{*}}{ y_{t}^{*}}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.8)

Equating (A.7) and (A.8) leads to

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\dot{h}_{t}}{h_{t}}=\frac{\left( 1-\phi \right) \left\{ z_{t}+\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left[ \frac{g_{t}}{k_{t}}-h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }\right] \right\} -\rho -\phi \left( \theta +\delta \right) }{\left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) -1-\gamma }. \end{aligned}$$
(A.9)

By utilizing (A.5), we can express Eq. (A.2) as

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{g_{t}}{k_{t}}=h_{t}^{\left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) }- \frac{Az_{t}h_{t}^{1+\gamma }}{\left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(A.10)

Finally, substituting (A.10) into (A.9) leads to Eq. (17); and substituting (A.10) into (A.4) leads to Eq. (18) in the main text.

Appendix B

Derivations of the Jacobian’s determinant (24) and trace (25) The dynamical system (17)–(18) can be approximated by the following linearized equations around a balanced-growth equilibrium characterized by \(\left( h^{*},z^{*}\right) \):

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{c} \dot{h}_{t} \\ \dot{z}_{t} \end{array} \right] =\underbrace{\left[ \begin{array}{c@{\quad }c} \mathbf {J}_{11} &{} \mathbf {J}_{12} \\ \mathbf {J}_{21} &{} \mathbf {J}_{22} \end{array} \right] }_{\mathbf {J}}\left[ \begin{array}{c} h_{t}\quad -h^{*} \\ z_{t}\quad -z^{*} \end{array} \right] ,\, \, \ \end{aligned}$$
(B.1)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {J}_{11}&=\frac{\left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\gamma \right) \left( \rho -z^{*}\right) }{\left[ \left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) -1-\gamma \right] \left[ 1-\left( 1-\phi \right) \alpha \right] }, \end{aligned}$$
(B.2)
$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {J}_{12}&=\frac{\left[ \rho +\phi \left( \theta +\delta \right) \right] h^{*}}{\left[ \left( 1-\phi \right) \left( 1-\alpha \right) \left( 1+\chi \right) -1-\gamma \right] z^{*}}, \end{aligned}$$
(B.3)
$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {J}_{21}&=\frac{\left( 1+\gamma \right) \left( \rho -z^{*}\right) z^{*}}{h^{*}}, \end{aligned}$$
(B.4)
$$\begin{aligned} \mathbf {J}_{22}&=\rho . \end{aligned}$$
(B.5)

It is then straightforward to derive the determinant \(\left( =\mathbf {J}_{11} \mathbf {J}_{22}-\mathbf {J}_{12}\mathbf {J}_{21}\right) \) and trace \(\left( = \mathbf {J}_{11}+\mathbf {J}_{22}\right) \) of the model’s Jacobian matrix \( \mathbf {J}\) given by Eqs. (24)–(25) in the main text.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chen, SH., Guo, JT. Progressive taxation as an automatic destabilizer under endogenous growth. J Econ 127, 47–71 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-018-0623-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-018-0623-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation