Skip to main content
Log in

Privatization of state holding corporations

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many countries have privatized part of their state holding corporations in recent years. However, the literature on this issue has analyzed mainly the privatization of uniproduct public firms. We consider a state holding corporation with two plants that may produce complement or substitute goods. Assuming that private firms are more efficient than the state holding corporation we find the following: If the marginal cost of the state corporation is low, it is not privatized either if goods are substitutes or if they are complements. However, if the marginal cost of the state corporation is high the two plants of the state holding corporation are sold to a single private investor if goods are complements, and to different investors if goods are substitutes. If goods are close substitutes and the marginal cost of the state corporation takes an intermediate value only one plant is privatized. We extend the model to consider that firms are equally efficient, that they face quadratic cost functions and that there are n uniplant private firms producing each good. We find two differences with the previous result: The government never privatizes just one plant of the state corporation, and when goods are complements the two plants of the state corporation are sold to different investors if n is high.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See, for instance, Parker (1998) and Parker and Saal (2003).

  2. State control is also significant in China, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Singapore, and Thailand.

  3. These papers have been extended to consider, among other factors, partial privatization of public firms (Matsumura 1998), strategic privatization under international trade (Bárcena-Ruiz and Garzón 2005a, b), sequential privatization of public firms (Matsumura and Shimizu 2010), privatization when the public firm is as efficient as private firms (Bárcena-Ruiz 2012), privatization under an interdependence payoff structure (Matsumura and Okamura 2015), price and quantify competition with differentiated products (Haraguchi and Matsumura 2016), collusion between firms (Colombo 2016) and switching cost (Dong and Bárcena-Ruiz 2016).

  4. In Europe governments have created holdings that comprise domestic public firms such as, for example, the Sociedad Estatal de Participaciones Industriales -SEPI- in Spain (see http://www.sepi.es), the Istituto per la Ricostruzione Industriale -IRI- in Italy (see Cafferata 2010), and the Agence des Participations de l’État -APE- in France (http://www.economie.gouv.fr).

  5. This assumption is usually made in mixed oligopoly literature to avoid a trivial solution. If the public firm is at least as efficient as the private firms the public firm produces a quantity such that the market price equals its marginal cost, resulting in a public monopoly (see Pal 1998; Estrin and De Meza 1995). For a survey of empirical studies on privatization see Megginson and Netter (2001). They conclude that research supports the proposition that private firms are more efficient and more profitable than otherwise comparable public firms.

  6. Another example comes from the privatization of airports. Governments in many countries have begun to privatize their public airports. For example, by 2000 Australia had privatized 17 of the 22 public airports at its disposal, and aimed to privatize the rest (see Hooper et al. 2000). Note that different airports were sold to different private firms.

  7. Another example is given by the privatization of the Spanish insurance company Musini (see http://www.sepi.es). This company had two distinct business lines, one covering life insurance and the other non-life insurance. These two lines operate separately in the market. The government decided to sell both lines to the private insurer Mapfre.

  8. As public firms maximize social welfare they take consumer surplus into account when deciding production. Thus, a public firm produces more than a private firm and market competition is stronger in a mixed oligopoly than in a private oligopoly. This implies a greater consumer surplus but a lower producer surplus in the former case. When the number of private firms is low the government does not privatize since it weakens market competition, which decreases the output of industry, the consumer surplus, and social welfare. When the number of private firms is high the government privatizes the public firm since market competition is strong. Although the privatization of the public firm reduces the output of industry and the consumer surplus, the increase in the producer surplus raises social welfare.

  9. If the two plants of the state corporation are independent public firms the result of the model hold since they both maximize social welfare.

  10. The assumption \(c<\overline{\overline{c}} \) ensures that the two plants of the state holding corporation produce a positive output when they are not privatized; \(c<\bar{c}\) ensures that, when one plant of the state corporation is privatized the other plant produces a positive output. Finally, it is easy to see that \(\overline{\overline{c}} >\overline{c} \) if \(b> 0,\overline{c} >\overline{\overline{c}} \) if \(b< 0\) and \(\overline{\overline{c}} >\overline{c} \) if \(b= 0\).

  11. These critical values of parameter c are relegated to the Appendix.

  12. It can be shown that the main result obtained in this proposition holds assuming that n private firms produce each good. The resolution of this case is cumbersome so we have solved the model for specific values of parameter c. It can be shown that when n increases, market competition becomes stronger so, for a given value of parameter c, the zone in which the plants of the state corporation are not privatized in equilibrium becomes smaller. As a result, the zone in which the state corporation is privatized becomes greater. The equilibrium in which just one plant of the public firm is privatized exists for highly substitute goods and a small number of private firms.

  13. It can be shown that \(PS^S=PS^D\) for \(b=b_1 \), where \(b_1=(-3+\sqrt{3} )/2 \approx -0.63\).

  14. Eckel and Neary (2010) point out that multiproduct firms are omnipresent in the modern world economy, especially in technologically advanced countries. Theoretical models of multiproduct firms have analyzed product choice and the determinants of product variety (Anderson and De Palma 2006), market structure (Shaked and Sutton 1990), international trade and productivity (Bernard et al. 2010), the effect of firm heterogeneity on industry profitability and welfare (Symeonidis 2009) and the environmental policy implemented by governments when firms are multiproduct (Bárcena-Ruiz and Garzón 2014), among other issues.

  15. A detailed analysis of the result obtained in this case and its proof are available from the authors on request.

  16. It can be shown that if the cost functions are given by \(C(q_{iA} ) =c\,q_{iA}^2 /2\) and \(C(q_{iBk} ) =c\,q_{iBk}^2 /2\), the main results hold; i.e., the results are robust to changes in parameter c.

  17. These critical values of parameter n are relegated to Appendix 2.

  18. In Sect. 3 an asymmetric equilibrium in which only one plant of the state corporation is privatized arises for certain value of parameters since the state corporation is less efficient than the private firms. This asymmetry permits an asymmetric equilibrium to be obtained.

  19. It can be shown that \(PS^S=PS^D\) for \(n=n_4 ,\) with \(n_4 <n_3 \) and \(n_4 =n_1 \) for \(b= -0.8226\) (see Fig. 2). The issue of the value of \(n_4 \) is relegated to Appendix 2.

  20. With constant marginal cost of production and two uniplant private firms the consumer surplus always dominates the producer surplus.

References

  • Anderson SP, De Palma A (2006) Market performance with multiproduct firms. J Ind Econ 54:95–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC (2012) Privatization when the public firm is as efficient as private firms. Econ Model 29:1019–1023

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2005a) Economic integration and privatisation under diseconomies of scale. Eur J Polit Econ 21:247–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2005b) International trade and strategic privatization. Rev Dev Econ 9:502–513

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bárcena-Ruiz JC, Garzón MB (2014) Multiproduct firms and environmental policy coordination. Environ Resour Econ 59:407–431

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard BA, Redding SJ, Schott PK (2010) Multi-product firms and product switching. Am Econ Rev 100:70–97

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cafferata R (2010) The enduring presence of groups and public enterprises in the Italian economy. J Manage Governance 14:199–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang HJ (2007) State-owned enterprise reform. National development strategies. Policy notes. Department for Economics and Social Affairs, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo S (2016) Mixed oligopolies and collusion. J Econ 118:167–184

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G, Jeanne O (1994) Oligopole mixte dans un marché commun. Annales d’Economie et de Statistique 33:73–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Fraja G, Delbono F (1989) Alternatives strategies of a public enterprise in oligopoly. Oxford Econ Pap 41:302–311

    Google Scholar 

  • De Fraja G, Delbono F (1990) Game theoretic models of mixed oligopoly. J Econ Surv 4:1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Fraja G (2009) Mixed oligopoly: old and new. Working Paper No 09/20, University of Leicester

  • Dong Q, Bárcena-Ruiz JC (2016) Privatization and entry with switching costs. Manch Sch, fortcoming

  • Estrin S, De Meza D (1995) Unnatural monopoly. J Public Econ 97:471–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckel C, Neary JP (2010) Multi-product firms and flexible manufacturing in the global economy. Rev Econ Stud 77:188–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haraguchi J, Matsumura T (2016) Cournot-Bertrand comparison in a mixed oligopoly. J Econ 117:117–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hooper P, Cain R, White S (2000) The privatization of Australia’s airports. Transport Res E-Log 36:181–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar A (1992) The state holding company. Issues and options. World Bank discussion papers N\(^{o}\) WDP 187

  • Matsumura T (1998) Partial privatization in mixed duopoly. J Public Econ 70:473–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Okamura M (2015) Competition and privatization policies revisited: the payoff interdependence approach. J Econ 116:137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsumura T, Shimizu D (2010) Privatization waves. Manch Sch 78:609–625

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Megginson WL, Netter JM (2001) From state to market: A survey of empirical studies on privatization. J Econ Lit 39:321–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pal D (1998) Endogenous timing in a mixed oligopoly. Econ Lett 61:181–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Parker D (1998) Privatisation in the European union: theory and policy perspectives. Routledge, London and New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Parker D, Saal D (eds) (2003) International handbook on privatization. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaked A, Sutton J (1990) Multiproduct firms and market structure. Rand J Econ 21:45–62

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Symeonidis G (2009) Asymmetric multiproduct firms, profitability and welfare. B Econ Res 61:139–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two referees for helpful comments. Financial support from Ministerio de Ciencia y Tecnología (ECO2012-32299, ECO2015-66803-P), Basque Government (IT1124-16) and the University of the Basque Country (EHU14/05) is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Juan Carlos Bárcena-Ruiz.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Proof of Proposition 1.

It can be shown that \(CS^S-CS^D=-b(12+15b+4b^2)/((1+b)(3+b)^2(3+2b)^2)>0\) if and only if \(b<0; PS^D-PS^S=-2b(3+6b+2b^2)/((1+b)(3+b)^2(3+2b)^2)>0\) if and only if \(b_1<b<0\), where \(b_1 =(-3+\sqrt{3} )/2 \approx -0.63\).

Next, we compare the welfare obtained in the different cases. It can be shown that:

$$\begin{aligned} W^{S}-W^{N}= & {} (-1+2( {3+b})^2c-( {3+b})^2( {3+2b})c^2)/((1+b)(3+b)^2),\,\end{aligned}$$
(4)
$$\begin{aligned} W^S-W^D= & {} -3b(2+b)/((1+b)(3+b)^2(3+2b)^2),\end{aligned}$$
(5)
$$\begin{aligned} W^S-W^O= & {} -(9+3b-19b^2+b^3+8b^4-2( {3+b})^2( {9+b-12b^2+4b^4})c\nonumber \\&+\, (1+b)( {3+b})^2(27-28b^2+8b^4)c^2)/(2(1+b)( {3+b})^2( {3-2b^2})^2),\end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned} W^N-W^D= & {} (1-2( {3+2b})^2c+( {3+2b})^3c^2)/((1+b)(3+2b)^2),\end{aligned}$$
(7)
$$\begin{aligned} W^N-W^O= & {} (1-b+2( {1-b})( {4b^2+4b^3-9-8b})c+(27+9b-44b^2-20b^3\nonumber \\&+\, 16b^4+8b^5)c^2)/(2(1+b)(3-2b^2)^2,\end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} W^O-W^D= & {} (9-12b-4b^2+8b^3-2( {3+2b})^2( {9-8b-4b^2+4b^3})c\nonumber \\&+\, ( {3+2b})^2(27-28b^2+8b^4)c^2)/(2( {3+2b})^2( {3-2b^2})^2). \end{aligned}$$
(9)

We consider first that goods are complements \(( {b<0})\). From (A2) we obtain that \(W^S>W^D\) if \(b<0\), so the government does not choose D for \(b<0\). It can be shown from (A1) that \(W^S-W^N\) is strictly concave in c for \(b<0\). This expression equals to zero for two values of c. One of them is \(c=c_1 =(9+6b+b^2-( {3+b})\sqrt{6+4b+b^2} )/(( {3+b})^2(3+2b))\), where \(c_1 <\overline{\overline{c}} \) for \(b<0\). The other one is greater that \(\overline{\overline{c}} \) so we exclude it. We obtain that \(W^S>W^N\) if \(c>c_1 \) and \(W^S<W^N\) if \(c<c_1 \).

It can be shown from (A3) that \(W^S-W^O\) is strictly concave in c for \(b<0\). This expression equals to zero for two values of c. One of them is \(c=c_{SO} <\overline{\overline{c}} \). The other one is greater that \(\overline{\overline{c}} \) so we exclude it. We obtain that \(W^S>W^O\) if \(c>c_{SO} \) and \(W^S<W^O\) if \(c<c_{SO} \), where:

$$\begin{aligned}&c_{SO}\\&=\frac{81+63b-93b^2-71b^3+24b^4+24b^5+4b^6-(9+3b-6b^2-2b^3)\sqrt{2(27+18b-23b^2-13b^3+3b^4+4b^5+2b^6)} }{(3+b)^2(27+27b-28b^2-28b^3+8b^4+8b^5)}. \end{aligned}$$

Moreover, it can be checked that \(c_1 >c_{SO} \), so for \(c>c_1 \) we obtain that \(W^S>W^O\) and \(W^S>W^N\).

It can be shown from (A5) that \(W^N-W^O\) is strictly convex in c for \(b<0\). This expression equals to zero for two values of c. One of them is \(c=c_3 <\overline{\overline{c}} \). The other one is greater that \(\overline{\overline{c}} \) so we exclude it. We obtain that \(W^N>W^O\) if \(c<c_3 \) and \(W^N<W^O\) if \(c>c_3 \), where \(c_3 =(9-b-12b^2+4b^4-\sqrt{2( {1-b^2})( {3-2b^2})^3} )/(27+9b-44b^2-20b^3+16b^4+8b^5)\). Moreover, it can be checked that \(c_1 <c_3 \) for \(b<0\), so when \(c<c_{1} \) we obtain that \(W^N>W^O\) and \(W^N>W^S.\)

Next we consider that goods are substitutes \(( {b>0})\). Let \(c_2 =((3+2b)-\sqrt{2(1+b)(3+2b)} )/( {3+2b})^2\) be the value of c such that \(W^D=W^N\), where \(W^D>W^N\) if \(c>c_2 \). Let \(c_3 \) be the value of c such that \(W^O=W^N\), where \(W^O>W^N\) if \(c>c_3 \). Let \(c_4 =(81+36b-96b^2-44b^3+32b^4+16b^5-(9+6b-6b^2-4b^3)\sqrt{2(27-26b^2+8b^4)} )/((3+2b)^2(27-28b^2+8b^4))\) be the value of c such that \(W^D=W^O\), where \(W^D>W^O\) if \(c>c_4 \).

It can be shown that \(c_2 =c_3 =c_4 \) for \(b=0.9971,c_3>c_2 >c_4 \) for \(b<0.9971,c_4>c_2 >c_3 \) for \(b>0.9971\) and that \(c_i <\bar{c}( {i= 2, 3, 4})\) for \(b>0\). The comparisons between \(c_2 ,c_3 \) and \(c_4 \) are illustrated in Figure 3. Thus, since \(W^D>W^S\) when \(b>0\) from (A2), the definitions of \(c_2 ,c_3 \) and \(c_4 \) imply that \(W^D>max\{W^N,W^S,W^O\}\) if \(c>\max \{c_2 ,c_4 \}\), \(W^N>max\{W^S,W^D,W^O\}\) if \(c<min\{c_2 ,c_3 \}\) and \(W^O>max\{W^S,W^D,W^N\}\) if \(c_{3}<c<c_{4} \).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Comparison of \(c_2 ,c_3 \), and \(c_4 \)

Appendix 2: Quadratic cost functions

When the government does not privatize there is a state corporation and two private uniplant firms. In the second stage of the game, private firm iBk sets the output level \(q_{iBk}\) that maximizes its profit. The state corporation chooses the output levels \(q_{1A}\) and \(q_{2A}\) that maximize social welfare. Solving these problems, we obtain the following result. Denote \(H_1 =4+n+b(2+n)\).

Lemma 5

When the government does not privatize the state corporation, in equilibrium:

$$\begin{aligned}&q_{iA}^N = 2/H_1 , \quad q_{iBk}^N =1/H_1 ,\quad \pi _{iA}^N =2/(H_1 )^2,\quad \pi _{iBk}^N =3/(2(H_1 )^2),\quad CS^N=(1+b)(2+n)^2/(H_1 )^2, \\&PS^N= (4+3n)/(H_1 )^2,\quad W^N=(8+b( {2+n})^2+n( {7+n}))/(H_1 )^2,\quad i =1, 2;\quad k= 1, \ldots ,n. \end{aligned}$$

When the government sells the state corporation to a single private investor there are one multiplant private firm and n private uniplant firms. In the second stage of the game, private multiplant firm A chooses the output levels \(q_{1A} \) and \(q_{2A} \) that maximize the joint profit of its two plants. Private firm iBk sets the output level \(q_{iBk} \) that maximizes its profit. Solving these problems, we obtain the following result. Denote \(H_2 =6+4b+2n+3bn+b^2n\).

Lemma 6

When the government sells the state corporation to a single private investor, in equilibrium:

$$\begin{aligned}&q_{iA}^S =2/H_2 ,\quad q_{iBk}^S =(2+b)/H_2, \pi _{iA}^S =(6+4b)/(H_2 )^2,\quad \pi _{iBk}^S =3( {2+b})^2/(2(H_2 )^2), \\&CS^S=( {1+b})( {2+( {2+b})n})^2/(H_2 )^2,\quad PS^{S} =(12+8b+3( {2+b})^2n)/(H_2 )^2, \\&W^S=(4( {4+3b})+( {2+b})( {10+7b})n+( {1+b})( {2+b})^2n^2)/(H_2 )^2,\quad i =1, 2;\quad k= 1, \ldots ,n. \end{aligned}$$

When each plant of the state corporation is sold to a different private investor, there are n+1 firms producing each good. In the second stage of the game, private firms iA and iBk set the output levels \(q_{iA}\) and \(q_{iBk}\) that maximize their profits, respectively. Solving these problems, we obtain the following result. Denote \(H_{3} =3+b+n+bn\).

Lemma 7

When the government sells each plant of the state corporation to a different private investor, in equilibrium:

$$\begin{aligned}&q_{iA}^D =q_{iBk}^D =1/H_3, \pi _{iA}^D =\pi _{iBk}^D =3/(2(H_3 )^2),\quad CS^D=( {1+b})( {1+n})^2/(H_3 )^2, \\&PS^D=3(1+n)/(H_3 )^2,\quad W^D=(1+n)(4+b+n+bn)/(H_3 )^2,\quad i =1, 2;\quad k= 1, \ldots ,n. \end{aligned}$$

When the government privatizes only one plant of the state corporation we assume, without loss of generality, that the government sells plant 1A. In the second stage of the game, each private firm sets the output level that maximizes its profit. The public firm chooses the output level \(q_{2A}\) that maximizes social welfare. Solving these problems, we obtain the following result. Denote \(H_4 =12+7n+n^2-b^2(2+3n+n^2)\).

Lemma 8

When the government privatizes only one plant of the state corporation, in equilibrium:

$$\begin{aligned} q_{1A}^O= & {} q_{1Bk}^O =(4+n-b( {2+n}))/H_4 ,\,q_{2A}^O =2(3-b+n-bn)/H_4 ,\\&\,q_{2Bk}^O \,(3-b+n-bn)/H_4 ,\, \\ \pi _{1A}^O= & {} \pi _{1Bk}^O =3( {4+n-b( {2+n})})^2/(2(H_4 )^2),\,\pi _{2A}^O =2(3-b+n-bn)^2/(H_4 )^2,\,\pi _{2Bk}^O \\= & {} 3( {3-b+n-bn})^2/(2(H_4 )^2),\,CS^{O} =(26+50n+35n^2+10n^3+n^4\\&+\,b^3( {2+3n+n^2})^2-b( {-4+9n^2+6n^3+n^4})-b^2( {16+38n+31n^2+10n^3+n^4}))/(H_4 )^2,\, \\ PS^O= & {} (84+123n+49n^2+6n^3+b^2( {16+35n+25n^2+6n^3})\\&-\,2b( {36+67n+37n^2+6n^3}))/(2(H_4 )^2), \\ W^O= & {} (136+223n+119n^2+26n^3+2n^4+2b^3(2+3n+n^2)^2\\&-\,2b(32+67n+46n^2+12n^3+n^4) -b^2(16+41n+37n^2+14n^3\\&\quad +2n^4))/(2(H_4 )^2),\quad k= 1, \ldots ,n. \end{aligned}$$

Proof of Proposition 2

It can be shown that \(CS^S-CS^D=-4b(1+b)(b^2n(1+n)+2(3+4n+n^2)+b(3+7n+3n^2))/(H_3 )^2(H_2 )^2>0\) if and only if \(b<0; PS^D-PS^S=-b(3b^3n(1+n)+8n(3+n)+2b^2(4+11n+7n^2)+b(12+43n+19n^2))/(H_3 )^2(H_2 )^2>0\) if and only if \(n>n_4 \) when \(b<0\), where \(n_4 =-(24+43b+22b^2+3b^3-( {1+b})\sqrt{3( {192+176b+35b^2+6b^3+3b^4})} )/(2(1+b)^2(8+3b))\); otherwise \(PS^D<PS^S\).

Let \(n_1 =(-1+2b+b^2+\sqrt{33+44b+18b^2+4b^3+b^4})/(2(1+b))\) be the value of n such that \(W^S=W^N\), where \(W^S>W^N\) if \(n>n_1 \). Let \(n_2 =-(1+b-\sqrt{33+18b+b^2} )/(2+2b)\) be the value of n such that \(W^D=W^N\) , where \(W^D>W^N\), if \(n>n_2 \). Finally, \(W^S-W^D=b(b^3n(1+n)+8(3+n)+2b^2(2+5n+n^2)+b(24+17n+n^2))/(H_3 )^2(H_2 )^2\). It can be shown that \(W^S>W^D\) for \(b>0\). Let \(n_3 =-(8+9b+b^2+\sqrt{64+48b+b^2+2b^3+b^4} )/(2b(1+b))\) be the value of n such that \(W^{S}=W^{D}\) when \(b\le 0\), where \(W^S>W^D\) if \(n>n_3\).

Finally, it can be shown that max\(\{W^D,W^S,W^N\} >W^O\) for all b. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bárcena-Ruiz, J.C., Garzón, M.B. Privatization of state holding corporations. J Econ 120, 171–188 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-016-0498-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-016-0498-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation