Skip to main content
Log in

Stability, strategic substitutes, strategic complements

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The Routh–Hurwitz stability condition is disentangled for choice variables that are strategic substitutes or strategic complements. This yields distinct stability conditions that are not necessarily symmetric. Two examples illustrate this result.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A sufficient condition for (1) to hold is that the absolute value of the slope of the reaction functions is less than one (Martin 2002). With \( n>2\) players stability is more involved. In general, it requires a set of conditions to be met (Dixit 1986).

  2. Note that the situation in panel a corresponds to a value of \(\theta \) that is quite unlikely to be observed. However, the figure only serves to illustrate the workings of the myopic adjustment process underlying (1).

  3. Note that this corresponds to the condition that the absolute value of the slope of the quantity reaction function (9) is less than one.

  4. The literature that d’Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) inspired is vast; see e.g. De Bondt (1997) for an overview.

  5. Strictly speaking, \(x\) is not the ‘level of R&D’ if ‘level’ refers to an investment, although much of the related literature refers to \(x\) in this way. The R&D investment is \(\gamma x^{2}/2\) which yields a reduction in marginal cost of \(x\). The R&D process itself is thus the transformation of \( \gamma x^{2}/2\) into \(x\) (see also Hinloopen 2003).

  6. Qiu (1997) generalizes d’Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) by allowing products to be differentiated, as in (8), whereby \(\theta \in [0,1]\) and \(b=1\). He takes into account the Routh–Hurwitz stability condition, but considers the case of R&D as a strategic complement only (which applies if \( \beta >\theta /2\)). This yields as stability condition: \((2-\theta \beta )(1+\beta )<\gamma (2+\theta )(4-\theta ^{2})/2\). Qiu (1997) neglects the stability condition in case R&D is a strategic substitute: \((2-\theta \beta )(1-\beta )<\gamma (2-\theta )(4-\theta ^{2})/2\). But this condition is more binding when \(\beta <\theta /2\), that is, when R&D is a strategic substitute. In fact, the claim of Qiu (1997) in his Lemma 1 that his condition A1 (\(\gamma >a/A>1\)) ‘is sufficient but not necessary’ to guarantee stability is not true. For \(\theta >0.8\) and sufficiently small \( \beta \), the relevant stability condition (that is, the condition in case R&D is a strategic substitute) requires \(\gamma \) to be distinguishably larger than \(1\), with the maximum approaching \(\frac{4}{3}\) for \(\beta =0\) and \(\theta \uparrow 1\).

References

  • d’Aspremont C, Jacquemin A (1988) Cooperative and noncooperative R&D in duopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 78:1133–1137

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowley AL (1924) The mathematical ground work of economics: an introductory treatise. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulow J, Geanakoplos J, Klemperer P (1985) Multimarket oligopoly: strategic substitutes and complements. J Polit Econ 93:488–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Bondt R (1997) Spillovers and innovative activities. Int J Ind Org 15:1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dixit A (1986) Comparative statics for oligopoly. Int Econ Rev 27:107–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hinloopen J (2003) R&D efficiency gains due to cooperation. J Econ 80:107–125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin S (2002) Advanced industrial economics. Blackwell Publishers, Malden/Oxford

  • Qiu L (1997) On the dynamic efficieny of Bertrand and Cournot equilibria. J Econ Theory 75:213–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seade J (1980) On the effects of entry. Econometrica 48:479–489

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

Thanks are due to Stephen Martin and Jan Vandekerckhove for inspiring yet stable discussions. The comments of an anonymous are greatly acknowledged. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jeroen Hinloopen.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Hinloopen, J. Stability, strategic substitutes, strategic complements. J Econ 116, 129–135 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-014-0422-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-014-0422-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation