Skip to main content
Log in

Precautionary saving under many risks

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies precautionary saving when many small risks are considered. We first introduce two simultaneous risks: labor income and interest rate risks. We show that, in this context, sufficient conditions for precautionary saving are weaker than in similar models. Moreover, we find that, unlike previous literature, precautionary saving can occur in the case of negative covariance between the two risks and in the case of imprudence. We then extend our analysis to a three-risk framework, where a background risk is included. We derive sufficient conditions for precautionary saving which are interpreted in the light of the previous literature.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Menegatti (2001) weakens the sufficient conditions about the positivity of the third derivative of the utility in the case where utility is defined over an unbounded domain.

  2. Generalizations to the case of \(nth\)-order risk changes are studied in Eeckhoudt and Schlesinger (2008) and Chiu et al. (2012).

  3. The implication for risk aversion of a background risk in a two-argument utility framework is studied by Pratt (1988), Finkelshtain et al. (1999) and Courbage (2001).

  4. For a formal definition of the relative prudence index see Eq. (14).

  5. In the same setting, Wang and Gong (2012) obtain a threshold equal to 2 for the partial relative prudence index.

  6. For simplicity, we here denote as \(v_{111}\) the third derivative with regard to the first argument of the bivariate utility function \(v_{111}(y_{1}+( 1+r) s^{\star \star },x_{1})\). A similar notation is adopted in the rest of the paper.

  7. See Li (2011).

  8. Note that, from now on, we drop the arguments of the functions \(RP(X,m)\) and \(PRP(X,m)\) for the sake of simplicity.

  9. Lemma 4 is directly derived from Proposition 3.2 in Li (2012).

  10. On this point see Li (2011).

  11. Li (2012) calls the first effect ‘income effect’ and the second ‘substitution effect’. (Rothschild and Stiglitz (1971), p. 69) refer to these two effects stating that: ‘Intuition suggests that increased the uncertainty in the return on savings will either lower savings because“a bird in the hands is worth two in the bush ” or raise it because a risk averse individual, in order to insure his minimum standard of life, saves more in face of increased uncertainty.’

  12. Obviously the term ‘large’ refers to \(|cov[ \tilde{y},\tilde{r}]|\).

  13. Note that a similar use of the reasoning below Inequality (13) can be made in the case where saving is negative and the agent is borrowing.

  14. The concept of ‘cross prudence’, introduced by Eeckhoudt et al. (2007), is associated with the sign of the third order cross derivatives of the utility function \(v_{122}\). However, to our knowledge, the index in Eq. (26) is studied here for the first time.

  15. An analogous role for the condition \(v_{122}\ge 0\) in a two-risk framework is found by Menegatti (2009b) and, in a different context , by Baiardi and Menegatti (2011) who study optimal environmental policies.

  16. A detailed discussion about the sign of this derivative is provided by Rey and Rochet (2004).

References

  • Ayong Le Kama A, Schubert K (2004) Growth, environment and uncertain future preferences. Environ Res Econ 28:31–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bleichrodt H, Crainich D, Eeckhoudt L (2003) Comorbidities in cost benefit analysis of health care. J Publ Econ 87:2399–2406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baiardi D, Menegatti M (2011) Pigouvian tax, abatement policies and uncertainty on the environment. J Econ 103:221–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu HW, Eeckhoudt L (2010) The effects of stochastic wages and non-labor income on labor supply: update and extensions. J Econ 100:69–83

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiu HW, Eeckhoudt L, Rey B (2012) On relative and partial risk attitudes: theory and implications. Econ Theory 50:151–167

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choi G, Kim I, Snow A (2001) Comparative statics predictions for changes in uncertainty in the portfolio and savings problems. Bull Econ Res 53:61–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courbage C (2001) On bivariate risk premia. Theory Decis 50:29–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Courbage C, Rey B (2007) Precautionary saving in the presence of other risks. Econ Theory 32:417–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denuit M, Eeckhoudt L, Menegatti M (2011) Correlated risks, bivariate utility and optimal choices. Econ Theory 46:39–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Denuit M, Rey B (2013) Benchmark values for higher order coefficients of relative risk aversion. Theory Dec 1–14

  • Drèze J, Modigliani F (1972) Consumption decision under uncertainty. J Econ Theory 5:308–335

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eeckhoudt L, Rey B, Schlesinger H (2007) A good sign for multivariate risk taking. Manag Sci 53:117–124

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eeckhoudt L, Schlesinger H (2006) Putting risk in its proper place. Am Econ Rev 96:280–289

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eeckhoudt L, Schlesinger H (2008) Changes in risk and the demand for savings. J Monet Econ 55:1329–1336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Wagener A (2004a) Relative risk aversion, relative prudence, and comparative statics under uncertainty: the case of (\( \mu \), \(\sigma \))-preferences. Bull Econ Res 56:159–170

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichner T, Wagener A (2004b) Insurance demand, the elasticity of risk aversion, and relative prudence: a further result. OR Spectrum 26:441–446

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finkelshtain I, Kella O, Scarsini M (1999) On risk aversion with two risks. J Math Econ 31:239–250

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gollier C (2010) Discounting, inequalities and economic convergence. CESifo working paper, no 3262

  • Grossman M (1972) On the concept of health capital and demand for health. J Polit Econ 80:223–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kimball MS (1990) Precautionary savings in the small and in the large. Econometrica 58:53–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland H (1968) Saving and uncertainty: the precautionary demand for saving. Q J Econ 82:465–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li J (2011) The demand for a risky asset in the presence of a background risk. J Econ Theory 146:372–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li J (2012) Precautionary saving in the presence of labor income and interest rate risks. J Econ 106:251–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menegatti M (2001) On the conditions for precautionary saving. J Econ Theory 98:189–193

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menegatti M (2007) A new interpretation for the precautionary saving motive: a note. J Econ 92:275–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Menegatti M (2009a) Precautionary saving in the presence of other risks: a comment. J Econ 39:473–476

    Google Scholar 

  • Menegatti M (2009b) Optimal saving in the presence of two risks. J Econ 96:277–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt JW (1964) Risk aversion in the small and in the large. Econometrica 32:122–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pratt JW (1988) Aversion to one risk in the presence of others. J Risk Uncertain 1:395–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rey B, Rochet J (2004) Health and wealth: how do they affect individual preferences? Geneva Pap Risk Insur Theory 29:43–54

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothschild M, Stiglitz J (1971) Increasing risk II: economic consequences. J Econ Theory 3:66–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo A (1970) The effect of uncertainty on saving decisions. Rev Econ Stud 37:353–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang J, Gong P (2012) Labor supply with stochastic wage rate and non-labor income uncertainty. J Econ 109:41–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Xepapadeas A (2005) Economic growth and the environment. In: Handbook of environmental economics, vol 3, Chap 23. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 1219–1271

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mario Menegatti.

Appendix

Appendix

In this Appendix we consider a modification of Problem 6 where background risk is introduced in both first and second periods. The framework is the same as Problem 6 except for the introduction of the stochastic term \(\tilde{x_0}=x_0+\psi \), where \(\psi \) is a random variable such that \(\mathbb E [\psi ] =0\) and \(\mathbb E [ \tilde{x_0}] =x_0\). The consumer decision problem thus becomes:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{s}\mathbb E [u( y_{0}-s,\tilde{x_0})]+\mathbb E [ v(\tilde{y}+s(1+\tilde{r}), \tilde{x})]. \end{aligned}$$
(34)

The optimal level of saving \(\check{ s}\) is thus determined by the first-order condition:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb E [(1+\tilde{r})v_{1}(\tilde{y}+\check{ s}(1+\tilde{r}),\tilde{x})]-\mathbb E [u_{1}(y_{0}-\check{ s},\tilde{x_0})]=0 \end{aligned}$$
(35)

The condition which ensures positive precautionary saving is obtained by comparing Eqs. (7) and (35). It is clear that, since \(u_{11}<0\) and \(v_{11}<0\), \(\check{s}\ge s^{\star }\) holds if and only if

$$\begin{aligned}&\mathbb E [(1+\tilde{r})v_{1}(\tilde{y}+\check{ s}(1+\tilde{r}),\tilde{x})]-(1+r)v_{1}(y+\check{ s}(1+r),x_1)\nonumber \\&\quad +\,u_{1}(y_{0}-\check{ s},x_0)-\mathbb E [u_{1}(y_{0}-\check{ s},\tilde{x_0})]\ge 0 \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Computations similar to those in Sect. 4 yield:

Corollary 12

In the case of small labor income and interest rate risks in the second period (\(\tilde{y}\) and \(\tilde{r}\), respectively) and small background risks in both first and second periods (\(\tilde{x_0}\) and \(\tilde{x}\), respectively) and assuming positive covariances between the random variables \(\tilde{y}\), \(\tilde{r}\) and \(\tilde{x}\), the five Conditions (28), (29), (30) and (31) and

$$\begin{aligned} u_{122}\le 0 \end{aligned}$$
(37)

are sufficient to have positive precautionary saving (\(\check{ s}\ge s^\star \)).

Proof

As in Corollary 11, Conditions (28), (29), (30) and (31) ensure that the difference between the first and the second terms in the left-hand side of Inequality (36) is positive. By Jensen’s inequality, Condition (37) ensures that the difference between the third and the fourth terms in the left-hand side of Inequality (36) is positive too. All the conditions together thus ensure that Inequality (36) holds. \(\square \)

The first four conditions in Corollary 12 are the same as Corollary 11 and their interpretation is analogous to that in Sect. 4. Condition (37), on the other hand, is new and is directly related to the introduction of a background risk in the first period. As Condition (29) indicates cross-prudence in wealth in period 2, Condition (37) indicates cross-imprudence in wealth in period 1. Its interpretation is thus straightforward. In presence of a background risk in the second period, the agent is pushed to increase saving if her disutility due to the background risk is lower when second-period wealth is higher. This is what cross-prudence in wealth in second period guarantees. Similarly, when we also have a background risk in first period, this risk pushes the agent to increase saving (and thus to reduce wealth in the first period) if the disutility due to the background risk is lower when first-period wealth is lower. This is exactly what is ensured by cross-imprudence in first period.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Baiardi, D., Magnani, M. & Menegatti, M. Precautionary saving under many risks. J Econ 113, 211–228 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0366-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0366-0

Keywords

JEL Classification 

Navigation