Skip to main content
Log in

Radial and directional measures of the rate of technical change

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper we develop radial and directional measures of the rate of technical change for the class of directional distance functions. For both types, we distinguish between primal and dual measures while the former are further divided into oriented (input- and output-based) and non-oriented. We highlight the pivotal role of translation elasticity in examining the interrelationships among the alternative directional measures and that of scale elasticity in the case of radial measures. We also show that the radial and directional measures are related one another through the normalized (with the value of the direction vector) dual functions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Notice that a there is similar relationship between the input- and the output-based measures of technical efficiency; see Färe and Lovell (1978).

  2. Notice that the Shephard-type output (input) distance function can be viewed as a transformation function that is homogenous of degree one in outputs (inputs).

  3. Ohta (1974) initiated this line of research by establishing the relation between the cost function- and the production function-based measures of the rate of technical change by means of scale elasticity. Note that the production function-based is indeed an output-based measure of the rate of technical change.

  4. The notion of translation elasticity, introduced by Färe and Karagiannis (2011), is presented in the next section.

  5. Notice that \(g_x \) is subtracted from the input quantity vector x while \(g_y \) is added to the output quantity vector y.

  6. The last two equalities in (2) are obtained by using the translation property, i.e., \(( {\nabla _x \vec {D}^T(x,y;g_x ,g_y )})^\prime g_x -( {\nabla _y \vec {D}^T(x,y;g_x ,g_y )})^\prime g_y =1\).

  7. Notice that total differential hereon will involve directional derivatives for inputs and outputs and conventional derivatives for the technical change index. For the definition of directional derivatives see (Rockafellar 1970, p. 241).

  8. Notice that in the single-input, single-output case, \(\vec {D}_{g_x }^{TI} \) coincides with the input-based radial measure of technical change as defined in (D9) and \(\vec {D}_{g_y }^{TO} \) coincides with the output-based radial measure as given in (D10).

  9. This result is analogous to that of Boussemart et al. (2003) where the logarithm of the Malmquist index (i.e., the oriented TFP measure) is roughly twice the Luenberger indicator (i.e., the non-oriented TFP measure) under graph translation homotheticity, which is equivalent to constant returns to translation.

  10. An alternative proof is as follows: Chambers (2002) Lemma 2 shows that graph translation homotheticity, which is equivalent to constant returns to translation (Färe and Karagiannis 2011), implies that \(\vec {D}^I=\vec {D}^O\). Then \(\vec {D}_t^I =\vec {D}_t^O \) and using (D5) and (D7) the first equality follows. The second equality follows by combining (D3), (D5), (D7) and Briec and Kerstens (2004) Proposition 2 which shows that \(\vec {D}^I=\vec {D}^O=2\vec {D}^T\) under graph translation homotheticity and thus \(\vec {D}_t^I =\vec {D}_t^O =2\vec {D}_t^T \).

  11. Even though we have focused exclusively on directional functions, the proposed directional measures of the rate of technical change are readily applicable to all non- directional function representations of production technology, such as the Shephard-type distance functions, production and transformation functions.

  12. Notice that the first six rows and columns make a matrix that is symmetric and, as in Table 1, the elements of the lower triangular block are the inverse of those in the upper block.

References

  • Atkinson SE, Cornwell C (1998) Estimating radial measures of productivity growth: frontier vs non-frontier approaches. J Prod Anal 10:35–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balk BM (1998) Industrial price. Quantity and productivity indices, the microeconomic theory and an application, Kluwer Academic Press, USA

  • Bernstein JI (1994) Exports. margins and productivity growth: with an application to the Canadian softwood lumber industry. Rev Econ Stat 76:291–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W (1997) A graph-type extension of Farrell technical efficiency measure. J Prod Anal 8:95–110

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Kerstens K (2004) A Luenberger-Hicks-Moorsteen productivity indicator: its relation to the Hicks-Moorsteen productivity index and the Luenberger productivity indicator. Econ Theory 23:925–939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Peypoch N (2007) Biased technical change and parallel neutrality. J Econ 92:281–292

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Dervaux B, Leleu H (2003) Aggregation of directional distance functions and industrial efficiency. J Econ 79:237–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Briec W, Chambers RG, Färe R, Peypoch N (2006) Parallel Neutrality. J Econ 88:285–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boussemart JP, Briec W, Kerstens K, Poutineau JC (2003) Luenberger and Malmquist productivity indices: theoretical comparison and empirical illustration. Bull Econ Res 55:391–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caves DW, Christensen LW, Swanson JA (1981) Productivity growth, scale economies, and capacity utilization in US railroads, 1955–74. Am Econ Rev 71:994–1002

    Google Scholar 

  • Chambers RG (1998) Input and output indicators. In: Fare R, Grosskopf S, Russell RR (eds) Index numbers: essays in honor of Sten Malmquist, Kluwer Academic Press, USA, pp 241–71

  • Chambers RG (2002) Exact nonradial input, output and productivity measurement. Econ Theory 20:751–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers RG, Chung Y, Färe R (1998) Profit, directional distance functions, and Nerlovian efficiency. J Optim Theory Appl 98:351–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chambers RG, Färe R, Grosskopf S (1996) Productivity growth in APEC countries. Pacific Econ Rev 1:181–190

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2000) On the separability of the profit function. J Optim Theory Appl 105:609–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Färe R, Grosskopf S (2004) New directions: efficiency and productivity, Kluwer Academic Press, USA

  • Färe R, Karagiannis G (2011) Scale and translation elasticities for directional distance functions

  • Färe R, Lovell CAK (1978) Measuring the technical efficiency of production. J Econ Theory 19:150–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fulginiti LE (2010) Estimating Griliches’ k-shifts. Am J Agric Econ 92:86–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hudgins LB, Primont D (2007) Derivative properties of directional technology distance functions. In: Färe R, Grosskopf S (eds) Aggregation, efficiency and measurement, Kluwer Academic Press, USA, pp 31–43

  • Karagiannis G, Mergos GJ (2000) Total factor productivity growth and technical change in a profit function framework. J Prod Anal 14:31–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karagiannis G, Xepapadeas A (2009) Primal and dual measures of the rate of technical change: a synthesis and some new results

  • Luenberger D (1995) Microeconomic Theory. McGraw Hill, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohta M (1974) A note on the duality between production and cost functions: rate of returns to scale and rate of technical change. Econ Stud Quart 25:63–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Rockafellar RT (1970) Convex analysis, Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39:312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank two anonymous referees and Walter Briec for helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Giannis Karagiannis.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Färe, R., Karagiannis, G. Radial and directional measures of the rate of technical change. J Econ 112, 183–199 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0344-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-013-0344-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation