Skip to main content
Log in

Dynamical analysis of the R&D-based growth model with a regime switch

  • Published:
Journal of Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several empirical studies suggest that advanced economies experience a growth regime switch from factor accumulation to knowledge accumulation. To investigate the mechanism of such a regime switch, this study develops a concise and flexible dynamic model based on Romer (J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102, 1990) by introducing two types of endogenously supplied R&D input capital. The model replicates the growth patterns of developed and underdeveloped nations, clarifies the important role that capital plays in the difference between them, and presents several implications for interest-rate subsidies and official development assistance. Further, it shows that if a country enjoying long-run growth has little initial capital, its initial economic development will be based on capital accumulation. When the capital stock becomes sufficient for supporting R&D, the economy will achieve long-run growth through R&D.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Dynamical analysis and proof of stability were given by Arnold (2000).

  2. Matsuyama (1999) focuses on the fluctuations between the two economic regimes—capital-based and R&D-based growth—and Kuwahara (2007) concentrates on the multiple steady states derived by expectations.

  3. As early R&D-based growth models, see Romer (1990), Grossman and Helpman (1991), and Aghion and Howitt (1992), who assume that exogenously endowed human resources and exogenously given R&D resources uniquely determine the long-run growth (or no growth). Furthermore, in these frameworks, if the R&D input factor grows, it yields a drastic rise in the economic growth rate, as Jones (1995a, b) critiques. In addition, some studies along this line conclude that introducing capital would not alter the essential outcome (Grossman and Helpman (1991) Ch. 5; Aghion and Howitt (1998) Ch. 3).

  4. It is noteworthy that this growth rate closely resembles that of Eq. (13) in Romer (1990). One difference between the two is as follows. We have set the R&D input as capital, which is endogenously accumulated. Therefore, (as derived below) we can endogenously derive the total endowment of capital, which is the input factor for R&D and for intermediate goods.

  5. See Appendix A1, which demonstrates that the case of \(\tilde{h}(0)>0\) has asymptotically same properties.

  6. It should be noted that the \(\dot{\tilde{k}}=0\) lines of both the Romer and Solow regimes intersect at \(\tilde{k}=\tilde{k}_Y=\tilde{k}_Y^*\).

  7. See Appendix A2 for detailed derivations.

References

  • Abramovitz M, David PA (1973) Reinterpreting economic growth: parables and realities. Am Econ Rev 63:428–439

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahituv A (2001) Be fruitful or multiply: on the interplay between fertility and economic development. J Popul Econ 14:51–71

    Google Scholar 

  • Arnold LG (2000) Stability of the market equilibrium in Romer’s model of endogenous technological change: a complete characterization. J Macroecon 22:69–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone P (1996) Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid. Eur Econ Rev 40:289–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burnside C, Dollar D (2000) Aid, policies, and growth. Am Econ Rev 90:847–868

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandler AD (1990) Scale and scope: the dynamics of industrial capitalism. Belknap Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Chen B-L, Chu AC (2010) On R&D spillovers, multiple equilibria and indeterminacy. J Econ 100(3):247–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Funke M, Strulik H (2000) On endogenous growth with physical capital, human capital and product variety. Eur Econ Rev 44:491–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galor O, Moav O (2004) From physical to human capital accumulation: inequality and the process of development. Rev Econ Stud 71:1001–1026

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman M, Helpman E (1991) Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayami Y, Ogasawara J (1999) Changes in the sources of modern economic growth: Japan compared with the United States. J Jpn Int Econ 13:1–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howitt P, Aghion P (1998) Capital accumulation and innovation as complementary factors in long-run growth. J Econ Growth 3:111–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Irmen A (2005) Extensive and intensive growth in a neoclassical framework. J Econ Dyn Control 29:1427–1448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (1995a) Time series tests of endogenous growth models. Q J Econ 110:495–525

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (1995b) R&D-based models of economic growth. J Polit Econ 103:759–784

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jones CI (2002) Introduction to economic growth, 2nd edn. W.W. Norton& Company, Inc., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelley AC (1988) Economic consequence of population change in the third world. J Econ Lit 26:1685–1728

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelley AC, Schmidt RM (1995) Aggregate population and economic growth correlations: the role of the components of demographic change. Demography 32:543–555

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1994) The myth of Asia’s miracle. Foreign Aff 73:62–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuwahara S (2006) Management ability, long-run growth, and poverty traps. J Econ 89(1):37–58

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuwahara S (2007) The mechanics of economic growth through capital accumulation and technological progress. Jpn Econ Rev 58:504–523

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama K (1999) Growing through cycles. Econometrica 67:335–347

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Matsuyama K (2001) Growing through cycles in an infinitely lived agent economy. J Econ Theory 100:220–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer PM (1990) Endogenous technological change. J Polit Econ 98:S71–S102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Segerstrom PS (1998) Endogenous growth without scale effects. Am Econ Rev 99:1290–1310

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1957) Technical change and the aggregate production function. Rev Econ Stat 39:312–320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young A (1995) The tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical realities of the East Asian growth experience. Q J Econ 110:641–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zilibotti F (1995) A Rostovian model of endogenous growth and underdevelopment traps. Eur Econ Rev 39:1569–1602

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author thanks Kazuo Mino, Koichi Futagami, Akihisa Shibata, Katsuya Takii, Akira Momota, Yasutomo Murasawa, Yoichi Gokan, Katsunori Yamada, and Yui Nakamura for their many useful comments and suggestions. The author also thanks the two anonymous referee of this journal. Last, the financial support from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS Wakate B) is gratefully acknowledged. Any remaining errors are the sole responsibility of the author.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Shiro Kuwahara.

Appendix A

Appendix A

1.1 A1. Positive initial endowment of human capital

In this appendix, we consider the case of \(H(0)=H_0>0\). If the profit rate of human capital is equated with physical capital, it is simply the Romer regime, and as such, in this section, we consider the case wherein the profit rate of human capital is smaller than that of physical capital. In this case, \(\dot{H}=0\) and \(r>r_H\) hold, and therefore, human capital endowment is fixed at the initial endowment \(H_0\), and R&D is executed to hold the no-arbitrage condition on capital profit rate \(r\). Then \(r_H\) is determined at the level that satisfies the zero-profit condition on R&D.

Therefore, the equilibrium condition on this regime is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial K_A}=(1-\gamma )\delta \frac{\xi _A^{-\gamma }}{N(t)}\bar{V}-r=0\nonumber , \quad \frac{\partial \Pi }{\partial H}=\gamma \, \delta \frac{\xi _A^{1-\gamma }}{N(t)}\bar{V}-r_H=0, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\xi _A(t)\equiv \frac{K_A}{H}\). From these two equations, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \tilde{v}=\frac{\xi _A^\gamma }{(1-\gamma )\delta }r,\quad \text{ and}\quad r_H=\frac{\gamma \xi _A}{1-\gamma }r. \end{aligned}$$

Thus, for the steady state, \(\xi _A=(const)\) is also necessary in this case. Because \(H_0\) is constant, \(K_A\) also is constant, and we denote it as \(\bar{K}_A\). However, the growth rate under \(\bar{K}_A\) is given as

$$\begin{aligned} g_A(t)=\frac{\bar{K}_A}{A(t)N(t)}\xi _A^\gamma . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, after the long run, the growth rate converges to \( \lim _{t \rightarrow \infty }g_A(t)=0; \) namely, the system asymptotically deceases the growth rate and converges to the Solow regime.

1.2 A2. Command economy and optimal conditions

To obtain the welfare properties of the decentralized solution, we consider the social planner formulation of this growth model. A benevolent government is assumed to maximize the representative household’s utility function Eq. (8). Therefore, the Hamiltonian of this government can be written as

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal{H}(t)&= \frac{c(t)^{1-\sigma }-1}{1-\sigma }+\lambda (t) (\underbrace{\eta ^{-\alpha }K_Y(t)^\alpha N(t)^{1-\alpha }A(t)^{1-\alpha }}_{Y}-c(t)N(t)-I_H(t))\\&+\mu (t)\delta \frac{(K(t)-K_Y(t))^{1-\gamma } H(t)^{\gamma }}{N(t)}+\lambda _H(t)I_H(t), \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda \), \(\mu \), and \(\lambda _H\) are the shadow prices of per capita capital stock, knowledge, and human capital, respectively. The optimal conditions are obtained as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda (t)N(t)&= c(t)^{-\sigma }, \qquad \end{aligned}$$
(31)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda (t)&= \lambda _H(t), \end{aligned}$$
(32)
$$\begin{aligned} \lambda (t) \alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }K_Y(t)^{\alpha -1}\bigl \{A(t)N(t)\bigr \}^{1-\alpha }&= (1-\gamma )\mu (t) \delta \frac{(K(t)-K_Y(t))^{-\gamma }H(t)^{\gamma }}{N(t)}, \qquad \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(33)
$$\begin{aligned} \rho \lambda (t)-\dot{\lambda }(t)&= (1-\gamma )\mu (t)\delta \frac{(K(t)-K_Y(t))^{-\gamma }H(t)^{\gamma }}{N(t)}, \qquad \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(34)
$$\begin{aligned} \rho \lambda _H(t)-\dot{\lambda }_H(t)&= \gamma \mu (t)\delta \frac{(K(t)-K_Y(t))^{1-\gamma }H(t)^{\gamma -1}}{N(t)}, \qquad \end{aligned}$$
(35)
$$\begin{aligned} \rho \mu (t)-\dot{\mu }(t)&= \lambda (t)(1-\alpha ) \eta ^{-\alpha } K_Y(t)^{\alpha }N(t)^{1-\alpha }A(t)^{-\alpha }. \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(36)

Using Eqs. (31), (34), and (36) and the notation \(\tilde{k}_Y\), we derive the following equations:

$$\begin{aligned} \rho -g_{\lambda }(t)&= \alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y(t)^{\alpha -1}, \end{aligned}$$
(37)
$$\begin{aligned} \rho -g_{\mu }(t)&= \frac{1-\alpha }{\alpha }\delta \Gamma (\gamma )\tilde{k}_Y(t). \end{aligned}$$
(38)

(34) and (35) yield the optimal rate between physical capital \(K_Y\) and human capital \(H\) as \(H=\frac{\gamma }{1-\gamma }K_Y\); namely, we have the rate between physical capital and human capital, \(\xi \), in both the market and command economies in this study. Using \(\xi \), the growth rate can also be written as \(g_A=\delta (\tilde{k}-\tilde{k}_Y)\xi ^\gamma \).

From Eqs. (31) and (37) and the definitions of \(\tilde{c}\) and \(\tilde{k}\), the following Euler equation is obtained:

$$\begin{aligned} g_{\tilde{c}}(t)=\frac{1}{\sigma }\left\{ \alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y(t)^{\alpha -1}-\rho -n-\sigma \delta \bigl (\tilde{k}(t)-\tilde{k}_Y(t)\bigr )\xi ^\gamma \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(39)

From Eqs. (33), (37), and (38), eliminating \(\lambda \) and \(\mu \) yields

$$\begin{aligned} g_{\tilde{k}_Y}(t)=\frac{1}{1-\alpha }\left[\frac{\delta (1-\alpha )\Gamma (\gamma )}{\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y(t)+n-\alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y(t)^{\alpha -1}\right]. \end{aligned}$$
(40)

The system consists of the following dynamic equations: (2), (39), and (40). These equations imply that \(g_{\tilde{k}_Y}=g_{\tilde{k}}\) and \(g_A=g_k=g_c=\delta (\tilde{k}-\tilde{k}_Y)\) must hold in a steady state. Substituting these conditions into Eqs. (2), (39), and (40), we obtain the following equations denoting the steady state of the command economy:

$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \rho +\sigma \delta (\tilde{k}^{*op}-\tilde{k}_Y^{*op})\xi ^\gamma =\alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y^{*op\, \alpha -1}-n,\end{aligned}$$
(41)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y^{*op \, \alpha }-\tilde{c}^{*op}-\bigl \{n+\delta (\tilde{k}^{*op}-\tilde{k}_Y^{*op})\xi ^\gamma \bigr \}\tilde{k}^{*op}=0\end{aligned}$$
(42)
$$\begin{aligned}&\displaystyle \alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y^{*op \alpha -1}-n=\frac{(1-\alpha )\Gamma (\gamma )}{\alpha }\delta \tilde{k}_Y^{*op}. \end{aligned}$$
(43)

By eliminating \(\alpha \eta ^{-\alpha }\tilde{k}_Y^{*op\, \alpha -1}-n\) from (41) and (43), we obtain the result that optimal capital allocation in the steady state in a command economy is the same as that in a market economy given by (12). Furthermore, the growth rate for given R&D-difficulty-adjusted capital stock in a command economy is the same as that in a market economy given by (13).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kuwahara, S. Dynamical analysis of the R&D-based growth model with a regime switch. J Econ 108, 35–57 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-012-0309-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00712-012-0309-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation