Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Fiscal policy and corruption

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops a simple model of corruption between a tax inspector and a taxpayer in which inspectors’ heterogeneity helps explain why it may be optimal for a revenue-maximizing government to tolerate corruption. In our model, tax inspectors could accept a bribe from a taxpayer for under-reporting his income or to avoid harassment in the form of red tape. The government’s problem is to design a tax policy and the associated monitoring probability to enforce it. Raising tax rates increases enforcement costs as it increases bribery incentives, so it is optimal not to set tax rates at a too high level. The optimal tax policy includes an optimal supervision level required to reduce corruption, which in turns depends on tax collectors’ capacity to impose red tape on taxpayers. When bureaucrats are heterogeneous in terms of their capacity to impose red tape costs, an intermediate detection probability might be appropriate efficiency-wise even if it means tolerating some level of corruption. Bureaucrats’ heterogeneity as the likely source of observation of corruption in equilibrium is generic to various environments in which agents’ delegated power is misused for private gains and various examples are discussed in the paper. We also show how a government could face lose–lose as well as win–win situations in the conduct of its revenue collection policies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See Bardhan (1997), Tanzi (2002), Svensson (2005), Mishra (2006), Banerjee et al. (2012) and Olken and Pande (2012) for reviews of the literature on corruption.

  2. Tanzi (2002) argues that officials from different administration, not just fiscal agencies, take advantage of regulation opacity to further their private interests. Svensson (2003) corroborates Banerjee (1997)’s theoretical findings and shows that bureaucrats’ discretionary power allows them to set prices of public services proportional to firms’ capacity to pay.

  3. In Cameroon for instance, 34 % of manufacturing firms reported fearing being closed by tax officials, (Gauthier and Gersovitz 1997).

  4. For a discussion and examples of bureaucrats’ discretionary power over the private sector, see for instance Tanzi and Davoodi (2002) and Rose-Ackerman (1997, 2004).

  5. Laffont and Tirole (1992) examine the effect of incentives schemes and monitoring to prevent collusion in the context of procurement and regulation. They discuss different cases where a supervisor might engage in side-payments with different types of firms and suggest a set of corresponding incentives schemes to avoid collusion in equilibrium in the context of a representative supervisor. In presence of heterogeneous supervisors, as in our model, it would be optimal for a rent maximizing regulator to tolerate some collusion given the cost of monitoring and incentive schemes. However, this reduces regulator’s rent.

  6. Mookherjee and Png (1995) model a situation of evasion of civic responsibilities in the context of environmental regulation.

  7. Olken and Barron (2007) analyzed bribe payments made by truck drivers in response to extortion by policemen, soldiers and weigh station employees in Indonesia. Bribes represent in aggregate 13 % of the marginal cost of a trip.

  8. The model could be easily amended to account for various situations, e.g., profits or revenues can serve as a proxy for instance for the level of polluting emissions by a firm or value of imports.

  9. Variable T should be interpreted as the aggregate amount of liabilities paid by a taxpayer whether these liabilities stem from direct taxation, custom, tariffs, fees for permits and licenses, fines for pollution, or other payments requested by an inspector or public servant (e.g. a member of the police or the army), etc.

  10. In a situation where the firm can be audited by another public employee after the bribe and tax payment negotiation, we can include a fine, A, in constraint (1b) without changing our main findings. In such a case, the fine would reduce the amount of the bribe, b, paid so that \(A + b \le T + c\) could simply be \(B \le T + c\). We could also consider the case where a firm has to pay a fine plus its tax obligations when caught and thus weighs the benefits of being corrupt against those of being honest. In such a case, the firm’s constraint becomes: \((T+A)(p) + B(1-p) \le T + c\). However, we focus on the simplest case where only the bureaucrat is penalized when evasion is discovered. We also note from firm constraint (1a) that firms will endure some red tape before choosing to pay a bribe.

  11. The model could easily be amended so that the outside option of a bureaucrat is different than zero. For example, we could assume that bureaucrats have to pay a fine F when caught with probability p in Eq. (2a). This only affects the level and not the qualitative nature of the results. For the sake of expositional clarity, we assume that F \(= 0\).

  12. This constraint is very similar to constraint (1a, 1b) in Acemoglu and Verdier (1998). However, the wage considered here is defined as the net wage, that is, gross wage minus taxes paid by the public employee.

  13. We have also examined the effect of a convex cost function. However, the added complexity does not affect the qualitative results below.

  14. Tax rates and wages could be endogenized. Hindriks et al. (1999) examine different tax schemes; Besley and Mclaren (1993), different wage schedules. We focus on the probability of detection.

  15. Note that at equilibrium, bureaucrats are still imposing red tape costs. These represent losses from the governmental point of view or can be seen as efficiency losses from the part of firms. We have in mind the situation of developing countries with inefficient legal systems, where bureaucrats do not fear being caught and try to extract bribes whenever their opportunity cost is low enough.

  16. Area \(\hbox {0A}p_{1}\) includes red tape cost. For simplicity, we assume that this cost is constant and that tax revenues and bribe amounts differ only by this constant.

  17. The same would be true if we were to analyze the situation with incentive wages where, for example, we increased w to \(w_{2}\) which would make bureaucrats’ constraint B \(=\) pw/(1 \(-\) p) go from the origin, through point B and onwards (dotted line on Fig. 2). Transfers would then be in the form of taxes and would correspond to area \(\hbox {0B}p_{1}\). Both corrections are equivalent and yield the same revenues.

  18. For example, custom agents are in a position to impose delays and other costly impediments on a firm’s imports or exports (Sequeira and Djankov 2008). Also, bureaucrats delivering permits and licenses may create red tape to discriminate among clients in a queue with a higher valuation of time in order to extract a bribe in exchange for faster procedures (Lui 1985).

  19. $$\begin{aligned} \begin{array}{lll} \tau _{1} < \tau _{2} &{} \quad \hbox {if}, &{} \quad {\frac{p}{1 - p}} {\frac{w}{V}} - {\frac{c_{1}}{V}} < {\frac{p}{1-p}} {\frac{w}{V}} - {\frac{c_{2}}{V}} \\ &{}&{} \Leftrightarrow -c_{1} < -c_{2} \\ &{}&{}\Leftrightarrow c_{1} > c_{2} \end{array} \end{aligned}$$
  20. Fiscal obligations and costs paid to type 1 bureaucrats under the regime with tax rate \(\tau _{2}\), equivalent to \(T_{2} + c_{1}\), are obviously greater than obligations paid to type 2 bureaucrats, which are equivalent to \(T_{2} + c_{2}\) since \(c_1 > c_2\).

  21. This is very similar to the maximization problem considered in the basic model, the only difference being that \(\eta = 0\) and firms could not reduce their bribe amounts through negotiations.

  22. Note that the bargaining model is a generalization of the model without bargaining power. Indeed, setting \(\eta =0\) and allowing for homogeneity in bureaucrats type leads back to Eq. (1b).

  23. Note that B\(_{\mathrm{min}}\) also corresponds to \(p_{2} w/(1-p_{2})\) in Fig. 3.

  24. Also, \(B_{\mathrm{max}}\) corresponds to \(T_{2}+c_{1}\) in Fig. 3.

  25. See Besley and Mclaren (1993) for a complete discussion on wage incentives in administration in developing countries.

  26. These are net of tax transfers to the government and to corrupt bureaucrats.

  27. A normative analysis of social costs is also available upon request.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Verdier T (1998) Property rights, corruption and the allocation of talent: a general equilibrium approach. Econ J 108:1381–1403

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Verdier T (2000) The choice between market failures and corruption. Am Econ Rev 90:194–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allingham M, Sandmo A (1972) Income tax evasion: a theoretical analysis. J Publ Econ 1:323–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A (1997) A theory of misgovernance. Q J Econ 112:1289–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Hanna R, Mullainathan S (2012) Corruption. In: Robert G, John R (eds) The Handbook of Organizational Economics, Princeton University Press, pp 1109–1147

  • Bardhan P (1997) Corruption and development: a review of issues. J Econ Lit 35:1320–1346

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu K, Bhattacharya S, Mishra A (1992) Notes on bribery and the control of corruption. J Publ Econ 48:349–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1968) Crime and punishment: an economic approach. J Polit Econ 76:169–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS, Stigler GJ (1974) Law enforcement, malfeasance, and compensation of enforcers. J Leg Stud 3(1):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bertrand M, Djankov S, Hanna R, Mullainathan S (2007) Obtaining a driving license in india: an experimental approach to studying corruption. Q J Econ 122(4):1639–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Mclaren J (1993) Taxes and bribery: the role of the wage incentives. Econ J 103:119–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Di Tella R, Schargrodsky E (2003) The role of wages and auditing during a crackdown on corruption in the city of Buenos Aires. J Law Econ 46(1):269–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, La Porta R, Lopez-De-Silanes F, Schleifer A (2002) The regulation of entry. Q J Econ 117(1):1–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman R, Svensson J (2007) Are corruption and taxation really harmful to growth? Firm level evidence. J Dev Econ 83(1):63–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisman R, Wei S (2004) Tax rates and tax evasion: evidence from missing imports in China. J Polit Econ 112(2):471–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman E, Johnson S, Kaufman D, Zoido-Lobaton P (2000) Dodging the grabbing hand: the determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. J Publ Econ 76(3):459–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gang I, Goswani O, Sanyal A (1991) Taxes, fines, and bribes: a model of indian public finance. In: Roermer M, Jones C (eds) Markets in developing countries: parallel, fragmented and black, pp 201–213

  • Gauthier B, Gersovitz M (1997) Revenue erosion through exemption and evasion in Cameroon 1993. J Publ Econ 64:407–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gauthier B, Reinikka R (2006) Shifting tax burdens through exemptions and evasion: an empirical investigation of Uganda. J Afr Econ 15(3):373–98

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon R, Li W (2009) Tax structures in developing countries: many puzzles and a possible explanation. J Publ Econ 93(7–8):855–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hindriks J, Keen M, Muthoo A (1999) Corruption, extortion and evasion. J Publ Econ 74:395–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson S, Kaufman D, Zoido-Lobaton P (1999) Corruption, public finances, and the unofficial economy. The World Bank, WPS 2169

  • Kofman F, Lawarree J (1993) Collusion in hierarchical agency. Econometrica 61(3):629–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laffont JJ, Tirole J (1992) Cost padding, auditing and collusion. Ann D’écon Stat 25/26:26–205

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont JJ, Tirole J (1993) A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation. MIT Press, New York, p 705

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindauer D, Meesook O, Suebsaeng P (1988) Government wage policy in Africa: some findings and policy issues. World Bank Res Obs 3(1):1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lui F (1985) An equilibrium queuing model of bribery. J Polit Econ 93(4):760–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mauro P (1995) Corruption and growth. Q J Econ 110:681–712

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mishra A (2006) Corruption, hierarchies and bureaucratic structure. In: Rose-Ackerman S (ed) International handbook on the economics of corruption, pp 189–215

  • Mookherjee D, Png IPL (1995) Corruptible law enforcers: how should they be compensated? Econ J 105:145–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olken B (2007) Monitoring corruption: evidence from a field experiment in indonesia. J Polit Econ 115(2):200–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olken B, Barron P (2007) The simple economics of extortion: evidence from trucking in aceh. J Polit Econ 117(3):417–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olken B, Pande R (2012) Corruption in developing countries. Ann Rev Econ 4(1):479–509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett L, Sethi G (1994) Tariff rates, tariff revenue, and tariff reform: some new facts. World Bank Econ Rev 8(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose-Ackerman S (1997) The political economy of corruption. In: Eliott KA (ed) Corruption and the global economy. Institute for International Economics

  • Rose-Ackerman S (2004) Governance and corruption. In: Lomborg B (ed) Global crisis, global solutions. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Sequeira S, Djankov S (2008) On the waterfront: an empirical study of corruption in ports. In: Working paper. Harvard University, Cambridge

  • Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1993) Corruption. Q J Econ 108(3):599–617

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson J (2003) Who must pay bribes and how much? Evidence from a cross section of firms. Q J Econ 118(1):207–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson J (2005) Eight questions about corruption. J Econ Perspect 19(3):19–42

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanzi V (2002) Corruption around the world: causes, consequences, scope, and cures. In: Abed GT, Gupta S (eds) Governance corruption, and economic performance. International Monetary Fund, pp 19–58

  • Tanzi V, Davoodi HR (2002) Corruption, public investment, and growth. In: Abed GT, Gupta S (eds) Governance, corruption, and economic performance. International Monetary Fund, pp 280–299

  • TI (2009) Global corruption barometer report. Transpar Int. http://www.transparency.org/whatwedo/publication/global_corruption_barometer_20091

  • Tirole J (1986) Hierarchies and bureaucracies: on the role of collusion in organization. J Law Econ Org 2(2):181–214

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Rijckeghem C, Weder B (2001) Bureaucratic corruption and the rate of temptation: do wages in the civil service affect corruption, and by how much? J Dev Econ 65(2):307–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2004) World development report 2005: a better investment climate for all. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Yang D (2008) Integrity for hire: an analysis of a widespread customs reform. J Law Econ 51(1):25–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This paper was previously circulated as “The effect of fiscal policy and corruption control mechanisms on firms’ growth and social welfare: theory and evidence”. We thank participants at various seminars and conferences. We thank an anonymous referee and the associate editor for their insightful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Jonathan Goyette.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof of proposition 1

Net tax revenues to the government are as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} RN\tau _1= & {} {\frac{p_1}{(1 - p_1)}} w - c_{1} - {\alpha p}_{1} \\ RN\tau _2= & {} (1 - \pi _{1}) \left( {\frac{p_2}{(1 - p_{2})}} w - c_2\right) - {\alpha p}_{2} \end{aligned}$$

We calculate the critical proportion of type 1 bureaucrats yielding higher net revenues under a flexible regime than under a no-corruption regime:

$$\begin{aligned}&RN\tau _1 < {RN\tau _2} \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow {\frac{p_{1} w}{( 1 - p_{1})}} - c_{1} - {\alpha p}_{1} < (1 - \pi _{1}) \left( {\frac{p_{2} w}{( 1 - p_{2})}} - c_{2} \right) - {\alpha p}_{2} \end{aligned}$$

where:

$$\begin{aligned} p_1= & {} 1 - \left( {\frac{w}{\alpha }}\right) ^{1/2}; \quad p_2 = 1 - \left( {\frac{(1 - \pi _{1})w}{\alpha }} \right) ^{1/2}; \\ {\frac{p_{1} w}{(1-p_{1})}}= & {} (\alpha w)^{1/2} - w; \quad {\frac{p_{2} w}{(1-p_{2})}} = \left( {\frac{\alpha w}{1-\pi _{1}}}\right) ^{1/2} - w \end{aligned}$$

Thus,

$$\begin{aligned}&({\alpha w})^{1/2} - w - c_{1} - \alpha + ({\alpha w})^{1/2} < (1-\pi _{1}) \left[ \left( {\frac{\alpha w}{1-\pi _{1}}}\right) ^{1/2} - w - c_{2} \right] \\&\qquad - \alpha + ((1-\pi _{1}) {\alpha w})^{1/2} \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow 2 ({\alpha w})^{1/2} - w - c_{1} < 2( (1-\pi _{1}) {\alpha w})^{1/2} - (1-\pi _{1})w - (1-\pi _{1}) c_{2} \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow (1-\pi _{1}) (w+c_{2}) - 2(1-\pi _{1})^{1/2} ({\alpha w})^{1/2} + 2({\alpha w})^{1/2} - w - c_{1} < 0 \end{aligned}$$

Substituting,

$$\begin{aligned} x = (1-\pi _{1})^{1/2} \quad \hbox {et}\quad x^2 = (1-\pi _{1}) \end{aligned}$$

We have:

$$\begin{aligned} x^2 (w+c_{2}) - 2x({\alpha w})^{1/2} + 2({\alpha w})^{1/2} - w - c_{1} < 0 \end{aligned}$$

Solutions to this inequality are:

$$\begin{aligned} x_{1}= & {} {\frac{ \sqrt{\alpha w} - \sqrt{\alpha w - 4( w + c_{2}) ( 2 \sqrt{\alpha w} - w - c_{1})}}{2(w + c_{2})}} \\ x_{2}= & {} {\frac{\sqrt{\alpha w} + \sqrt{\alpha w - 4( w + c_{2} )( 2 \sqrt{\alpha w} - w - c_{1})}}{2( w + c_{2})}} \end{aligned}$$

Hence, \((1 - x_1^2) > \pi _{1} > (1 - x_2^2)\) \(\square \)

Proof of Proposition 2

Social costs under the no-corruption regime \((SC_{sc})\) are:Footnote 26

$$\begin{aligned} SC_{sc} = \pi _{1} c_{1} + (1 - \pi _{1}) c_{2} + \alpha p_{1} \end{aligned}$$

While social costs under the flexible regime \((SC_{c})\) are:

$$\begin{aligned} SC_{c} = (1 - \pi _{1}) c_{2} + \alpha p_{2} \end{aligned}$$

Comparing these costs, we have:

$$\begin{aligned}&SC_{sc} > SC_{c} \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \pi _{1} c_{1} + (1 - \pi _{1}) c_{2} + \alpha p_{1} > (1-\pi _{1}) c_{2} + \alpha p_{2} \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \pi _{1} c_{1} + \alpha p_{1} > \alpha p_{2} \end{aligned}$$

This inequality always holds since \(p_{1} > p_{2}\). Social costs are thus lower under a policy that allows some level of corruption then under a fiscal regime that completely eliminates it.Footnote 27

Let us turn now to the costs imposed on firms \((FC_{sc})\) under these two fiscal regimes. Under the no-corruption regime, firm costs are:

$$\begin{aligned} FC_{sc} = \pi _{1} (T_{1} + c_{1}) + (1 - \pi _{1}) ( T_{1} + c_{2}) \end{aligned}$$

Costs imposed on firms \((FC_{c})\) under the flexible regime are:

$$\begin{aligned} FC_c = \pi _{1} B + (1 - \pi _{1} ) (T_{2} + c_{2}) \quad \hbox {where} \quad B = (T_{2} + c_{1}) \end{aligned}$$

Comparing these costs, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} FC_{sc} > FC_{c} \end{aligned}$$

If we compare the first term of each equation, we note that:

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _{1} (T_{1} + c_{1}) < \pi _{1} (T_{2} + c_{1}) \end{aligned}$$

While for the second term, we have:

$$\begin{aligned} (1 - \pi _{1}) ( T_{1} + c_{2} ) < ( 1 - \pi _{1} ) (T_{2} + c_{2}) \end{aligned}$$

This implies that the costs imposed on firms are higher under the flexible regime. Hence, while the flexible regime yields higher net tax revenues and lower social costs than the no-corruption regime, we see that the costs imposed on firms are greater under the flexible regime than under the no-corruption regime. Under the flexible regime, corrupt firms pay bribes equal to \(T_{2}+c_{1}\) to type 1 bureaucrats, while honest firms pay higher tax transfers (i.e. \(\tau _{2} > \tau _{1}\)). \(\square \)

Proof of Equation (7)

We have:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _B&(T + c - B)^\eta \left( B - {\frac{pw}{(1 - p)}}\right) ^{1-\eta } \\ \hbox {s.t : }&B \ge {\frac{p}{(1 - p)}} w \\&B \le T + c \end{aligned}$$

From first order conditions, we get:

$$\begin{aligned}&-\eta (T+c-B)^{\eta -1} \left( B - \left( {\frac{pw}{(1-p)}} \right) \right) ^{1-\eta } \\&\quad \quad + (T+c-B)^{\eta } (1-\eta ) \left( B - \left( {\frac{pw}{(1-p)}} \right) \right) ^{-\eta } = 0 \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \eta ( T+c-B)^{\eta -1} \left( B - \left( {\frac{pw}{(1-p)}} \right) \right) ^{1-\eta } \\&\quad = (T+c-B)^{\eta } (1-\eta ) \left( B - \left( {\frac{pw}{(1-p)}} \right) \right) ^{-\eta } \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \eta \left( B - {\frac{pw}{(1-p)}} \right) = (1-\eta ) (T+c-B) \end{aligned}$$

which yields the following relationship:

$$\begin{aligned} B = \eta {\frac{pw}{(1 - p)}} + (1 - \eta ) (T + c) \end{aligned}$$

\(\square \)

Corollary 3

Derivation of critical bargainning power \(\eta ^{*}\).

Proof

To obtain firms’ costs that are lower when a government chooses a flexible fiscal regime, we need:

$$\begin{aligned}&FC_{sc} > FC_c \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow (1 - \pi _{1}) (T_{1} + c_{2}) + \pi _{1} (T_{1} + c_{1}) \\&\quad \quad > ( 1 - \pi _{1}) (T_{2} + c_{2}) + \pi _{1} \left[ (1 - \eta ) ( T_2 + c_1) + \eta \left( {\frac{p_{2} w}{(1 - p_{2})}} \right) \right] \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow (1-\pi _{1}) (T_{1} - T_{2}) > \pi _{1} \left[ T_{2} + c_{1} - \eta \left( T_{2} + c_{1} - {\frac{p_{2} w}{(1-p_{2})}} \right) - (T_{1} + c_{1}) \right] \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow (1-\pi _{1}) (T_{1} - T_{2}) + \pi _{1} (T_{1} - T_{2}) > -\eta \pi _{1} \left[ T_{2} + c_{1} - {\frac{p_{2} w}{(1-p_2)}} \right] \\&\quad \Leftrightarrow -\eta < {\frac{(T_{1} - T_{2})}{\pi _{1} \left[ T_{2} + c_{1} - {\frac{p_{2} w}{(1-p_2)}} \right] }}\\&\quad \Leftrightarrow \eta ^{*} = {\frac{(T_{2} - T_{1})}{\pi _{1} \left[ T_{2} + c_{1} - {\frac{p_{2} w}{(1-p_{2})}}\right] }} \end{aligned}$$

Hence, \(\upeta >\upeta ^{*}\) to have \(FC_{sc} > FC_{c}\) \(\square \)

Proposition 4c

Under a fixed proportion \(\pi _1\) of corrupt type 1 bureaucrats, there may be an efficient fiscal policy \((\tau _{2l-w}, p_1)\) that we call lose–win where the government sees its tax revenues decrease and firms see their transfers decrease by reducing the tax rate, \(\tau _2\), in order to keep all bureaucrats opportunity cost under \(P_{1}\). In such circumstances the tax rate is:

$$\begin{aligned} \tau _{2l-w} < {\frac{p_{1} w}{V(1-p_1)}} - {\frac{c_2}{V}} \end{aligned}$$
Fig. 6
figure 6

Win–win versus lose–win situation

Proof

Given \((\tau _{2l-w}, p_{1})\), the opportunity cost of both types of bureaucrats is now at \(P_{2 l-w}\) in Fig. 6. The Government’s tax revenues from bureaucrat 2 decline from \(T_{2w-w}+c_{2}\) to \(T_{2l-w}+c_{2}\). However, the situation is to the advantage of firms dealing with type 1 bureaucrats since the lowering of the bureaucrats’ opportunity cost has the effect of lowering the minimal bribe a bureaucrat is willing to accept. In Fig. 6, there is a range (brace \(A_{l-w}\)) where firms with sufficient bargaining power can lower their bribe to an amount smaller than what they would have paid in fiscal obligations under a no-corruption policy \(T_{1}+c_{1}\). We also note that \(B_{min \, l-w}\) is effectively smaller than \(B_{min \, w-w}= T_{1}+c_{1}\). \(\square \)

Corollary to Proposition 4c

There is an optimal tax rate \(\tau _2^{**}\) set accordingly to \(\eta ^{*}\) for which gains made by firms dealing with corrupt type 1 bureaucrats make up for the government’s losses due to the reduction of tax revenues. This optimal tax rate is such that:

$$\begin{aligned} \tau _2^*= {\frac{\left( \tau _{1} + {\frac{\eta ^{*} \pi _{1} c_{1}}{V}} - {\frac{\eta ^{*} \pi _{1} p_{2} w}{V(1-p_2)}} \right) }{(1-\eta ^{*} \pi _{1})}} \end{aligned}$$

Proof

By comparing the effect of the flexible policy and the no-corruption policy on firm cost we obtained a critical bargaining power \(\eta ^{*}\). Transforming this equation and isolating \(\tau _2^{**}\) yields the optimal tax rate under which firms dealing with corrupt bureaucrats minimize their bribes while the government still collects higher tax revenues with a flexible policy than with a no-corruption policy. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gauthier, B., Goyette, J. Fiscal policy and corruption. Soc Choice Welf 46, 57–79 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0903-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-015-0903-6

JEL Classification

Navigation