Skip to main content
Log in

Veblen’s theory of the leisure class revisited: implications for optimal income taxation

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Several previous studies have demonstrated the importance of relative consumption comparisons for public policy. Yet, almost all of them have ignored the role of leisure for status comparisons. Inspired by Veblen (The theory of the leisure class. Macmillan, New York, 1899), this paper assumes that people care about their relative consumption and that leisure has a displaying role in making relative consumption more visible, based on a two-type model of optimal income taxation. While increased importance of relative consumption typically implies higher marginal income tax rates, in line with previous research, the effect of leisure-induced consumption visibility is to make the income tax more regressive in terms of ability.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Abel AB (2005) Optimal taxation when consumers have endogenous benchmark levels of consumption. Rev Eco Stud 72: 1–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof GA (1997) Social distance and social decisions. Econometrica 65: 1005–1027

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alpizar F, Carlsson F, Johansson-Stenman O (2005) How much do we care about absolute versus relative income and consumption?. J Econ Behav Organ 56: 405–421

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson T, Johansson-Stenman O (2008) When the Joneses’ consumption hurts: optimal public good provision and nonlinear income taxation. J Public Econ 92: 986–997

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson T, Johansson-Stenman O (2010) Positional concerns in an OLG model: optimal labor and capital income taxation. Int Econ Rev 51: 1071–1095

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aronsson T, Johansson-Stenman O. Conspicuous leisure: optimal income taxation when both relative consumption and relative leisure matter. Scand J Econ (forthcoming)

  • Blanchflower DG, Oswald AJ (2004) Well-being over time in Britain and the USA. J Public Econ 88: 1359–1386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blumkin T, Sadka E (2007) A case for taxing charitable donations. J Public Econ 91: 1555–1564

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boskin MJ, Sheshinski E (1978) Individual welfare depends upon relative income. Q J Econ 92: 589–601

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles S, Park Y-J (2005) Inequality, emulation, and work hours: was thorsten veblen right?. Econ J 15: F397–F413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brekke K-A, Howarth RB (2002) Affluence well-being and environmental quality. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

  • Carlsson F, Johansson-Stenman O, Martinsson P (2007) Do you enjoy having more than others? Survey evidence of positional goods. Economica 74: 586–598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark AE, Frijters P, Shields MA (2008) Relative income, happiness and utility: an explanation for the Easterlin paradox and other puzzles. J Econ Lit 46: 95–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark A, Senik C (2010) Who compares to whom? The anatomy of income comparisons in Europe. Econ J 120: 573–594

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole HL, Mailath GJ, Postlewaite A (1992) Social norms, savings behavior, and growth. J Polit Econ 100: 1092–1125

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cole HL, Mailath GJ, Postlewaite A (1998) Class systems and the enforcement of social norms. J Public Econ 70: 5–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corazzini L, Esposito L, Majorano F (2012) Reign in hell or serve in heaven? A cross-country journey into the relative vs absolute perceptions of wellbeing. J Econ Behav Organ 81: 715–730

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G, Jeanne O (1997) Conspicuous consumption, snobbism and conformism. J Public Econ 66: 55–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corneo G, Jeanne O (2001) Status, the distribution of wealth, and growth. Scand J Econ 103: 283–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dohmen T, Falk A, Fliessbach K, Sunde U, Weber B (2011) Relative versus absolute income, joy of winning, and gender: brain imaging evidence. J Public Econ 95: 279–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duesenberry JS (1949) Income, saving and the theory of consumer behavior. Harvard Univeristy Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Dupor B, Liu WF (2003) Jealousy and overconsumption. Amer Econ Rev 93: 423–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin RA (2001) Income and happiness: towards a unified theory. Econ J 111: 465–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eckerstorfer P (2011) Relative consumption concerns and the optimal tax mix. Working paper 1114, Department of Economics, University of Linz, Austria

  • Ferrer-i-Carbonell A (2005) Income and well-being: an empirical analysis of the comparison income effect. J Public Econ 89: 997–1019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fliessbach K, Weber B, Trautner P, Dohmen T, Sunde U, Elger CE, Falk A (2007) Social comparison affects reward-related brain activity in the human ventral striatum. Science 318: 1305–1308

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank RH (1985) The demand for unobservable and other nonpositional goods. Am Econ Rev 75: 101–116

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank RH (2005) Positional externalities cause large and preventable welfare losses. Am Econ Rev 95: 137–141

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frank RH (2008) Should public policy respond to positional externalities?. J Public Econ 92: 1777–1786

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins E, Kornienko T (2004) Running to keep in the same place: consumer choice as a game of status. Am Econ Rev 94: 1085–1107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hopkins E, Kornienko T (2009) Status, affluence, and inequality: rank-based comparisons in games of status. Games Econ Behav 67: 552–568

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ireland NJ (2001) Optimal income tax in the presence of status effects. J Public Econ 81: 193–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson-Stenman O, Carlsson F, Daruvala D (2002) Measuring future grandparents’ preferences for equality and relative standing. Econ J 112: 362–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur R, Tuomala M (1994) Inherent inequality and the optimal graduation of marginal tax rates. Scand J Econ 96: 275–82

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur R, Tuomala M (2010) Relativity, inequality and optimal nonlinear income taxation. Working paper, Cornell University

  • Layard R (1980) Human satisfaction and public policy. Econ J 90: 737–750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist L, Uhlig H (2000) Tax policy and aggregate demand management under catching up with the Joneses. Am Econ Rev 90: 356–366

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luttmer EFP (2005) Neighbors as negatives: relative earnings and well-being. Q J Econ 120: 963–1002

    Google Scholar 

  • Micheletto L (2008) Redistribution and optimal mixed taxation in the presence of consumption externalities. J Public Econ 92: 2262–2274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Micheletto L (2011) Optimal nonlinear redistributive taxation and public good provision in an economy with veblen effects. J Public Econ Theory 13: 71–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng Y-K (1987) Relative income effects and the appropriate level of public expenditure. Oxf Econ Pap 39: 293–300

    Google Scholar 

  • Oswald A (1983) Altruism, jealousy and the theory of optimal non-linear taxation. J Public Econ 20: 77–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rayo L, Becker GS (2007) Evolutionary efficiency and happiness. J Polit Econ 115: 302–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson L (2004) Information-based relative consumption effects. Econometrica 72: 93–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schor J (1998) The overspent American. Haperperennial, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Solnick S, Hemenway D (2005) Are positional concerns stronger in some domains than in others?. Am Econ Rev 45: 147–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stern NH (1982) Optimum taxation with errors in administration. J Public Econ 17: 181–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B, Wolfers J (2008) Economic growth and subjective well-being: reassessing the Easterlin paradox. Brookings Pap Econ Act, Spring, 1–87

  • Stiglitz JE (1982) Self-selection and pareto efficient taxation. J Public Econ 17: 213–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tuomala M (1990) Optimal income tax and redistribution. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen T (1899) The theory of the leisure class. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wendner R, Goulder LH (2008) Status effects, public goods provision, and the excess burden. J Public Econ 92: 1968–1985

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wendner R (2010) Conspicuous consumption and generation replacement in a model with perpetual youth. J Public Econ 94: 1093–1107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wendner R (2011) Will the consumption externalities’ effects in the ramsey model please stand up?. Econ Lett 111: 210–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Thomas Aronsson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Aronsson, T., Johansson-Stenman, O. Veblen’s theory of the leisure class revisited: implications for optimal income taxation. Soc Choice Welf 41, 551–578 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-012-0701-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-012-0701-3

JEL Classification

Navigation