Skip to main content
Log in

Habit formation and indeterminacy in overlapping generations models

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Economic Theory Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I introduce habit formation into an otherwise standard overlapping generations economy with pure exchange populated by three-period-lived agents. Habits are modeled in such a way that current consumption increases the marginal utility of future consumption. With logarithmic utility functions, I demonstrate that habit formation gives rise to stable monetary steady states in economies with hump-shaped endowment profiles and reasonably high discount factors. Intuitively, habits imply adjacent complementarity in consumption, which in turn explains why income effects are sufficiently strong in spite of the logarithmic utility. The three-period horizon further strengthens the income effect.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Theoretical foundations for several versions of intrinsic habit formation have been recently provided by Rozen (2010).

  2. However, out of equilibrium, homotheticity alone does not ensure that the marginal utilities of consumption are positive for all values in the consumption space. I thank one referee for pointing this out.

  3. In period \(0\), the competitive equilibrium satisfies an initial condition corresponding to a transitional period. Since the oldest generation alive holds zero assets at the end of life, there are two asset holding generations at any time. Thus the initial condition clears the asset market when transitional generations are still alive.

  4. Homotheticity rules out the nonnegativity constraints on consumption. Also, since \(U\) is strictly increasing in \(\tilde{c}_{2,t+1}\) and \(\tilde{c}_{3,t+2}\), the nonnegativity constraints on effective consumption are nonbinding. Notwithstanding, effective consumption may be negative out of equilibrium for some values in the consumption space.

  5. I do not study the Classical case in Gale (1973), in which \(A^{*}<0\), because it is well known that in such a case the competitive equilibrium is indeterminate.

  6. The Hartman-Grobman theorem asserts that if \(R^{*}\) is a hyperbolic steady state of (5) and if the Jacobian matrix \(\mathbf G \) is invertible (which is the case since \(\mathbf G \) has full rank), then there is a neighborhood \(\mathfrak R \) of \(R^{*}\) in which the first-order Taylor series expansion with Jacobian matrix \(\mathbf G \) is topologically equivalent to the original nonlinear system. In principle, there is no need to worry about nonhyperbolic equilibria. Given an arbitrary system \(x_{t}=F\left[ x_{t-1},a\right]\) with \(F\left[ \cdot ,a\right] \in C^{1}\), the moduli of eigenvalues are continuous functions of the parameter \(a\). If the steady state of \(F\left[ \cdot ,a\right]\) is nonhyperbolic at \(a=a_{0}\), then generically any small change in the value of \(a\) yields a hyperbolic equilibrium close to the old one, provided that the steady state itself does not disappear (see De la Fuente 2000).

  7. The discount factor is smaller than in representative agent models. These values are not implausible, however, because each period in OLG models of this sort typically consists of 20 years. For example, Kehoe and Levine (1990) and Geanakoplos et al. (2004) set the discount factor to \(0.5=(0.96594)^{20}\), while Constantinides et al. (2002) assume the discount factor is 0.44.

  8. If the habit parameter were set to zero in (1), the perfect foresight dynamics of rates of return would be given by a second-order nonlinear difference equation \(R_{t+1}=\hat{F_{1}}[R_{t},R_{t-1}]\), in which there is one jump variable. Moreover, all stationary economies in which \(A^{*}>0\) would be locally saddle-path stable, because the \(2 \times 2\) Jacobian matrix of the Taylor expansion would admit only one unstable eigenvalue.With habit formation, there is not only an additional jump variable in (5), but also an additional unstable eigenvalue in those economies located in the dark gray areas, and as a result the former remain locally saddle-path stable.

  9. Demichelis and Polemarchakis (2007) also show that the competitive equilibrium is determinate in OLG models with many periods and logarithmic utility functions.

  10. This parameterization suggests that agents get 90 percent of their lifetime income when middle-aged. In the literature, it is possible to encounter similar specifications, for instance, if agents earn labor income only in the second period of their life, as in Japelli and Pagano (1994).

  11. See Davila et al. (2007) for the generalization of the notion of local sunspot equilibria.

  12. Even after taking into account that in two-period models each period consists of 30 years, the highest value of \(\beta \) in Fig. 2 corresponds approximately to an annual discount factor of 0.9261, since \(0.1=(0.9261)^{30}\).

  13. The two pairs satisfy the market-clearing condition \(\alpha _{t+1}=R_{t} \alpha _{t}\). To begin with, the pair (0,0) is the autarkic equilibrium. On the other hand, given that the savings function in the two-period model is \(\alpha _{t}= \beta \omega _{1} /(1+\beta ) + (\gamma \omega _{1} - \omega _{2})/\{ (R_{t} + \gamma ) ( 1 + \beta )\}\), in equilibrium the young save \(\hat{\alpha }=\{ \beta \gamma \omega _{1} + (\gamma \omega _{1} - \omega _{2})\}/ \{ (1 + \beta )\gamma \}\) when the gross rate of return is zero, and hence the pair \((\hat{\alpha },0)\) is legitimate as well.

  14. In one-sector overlapping generations economies, Michel and Venditti (1997) also find that if the utility function is nonseparable in consumption, the optimal growth path follows a two-period cycle.

  15. It would be straightforward to assume that \(\omega _{3}\) is positive (but relatively small), in which case the results presented in this paper would hold by means of a continuity argument.

References

  • Azariadis, C., Guesnerie, R.: Sunspots and cycles. Rev. Econ. Stud. 53(5), 725–737 (1986)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C., Lambertini, L.: Endogenous debt constraints in lifecycle economies. Rev. Econ. Stud. 70(3), 461–487 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C., Bullard, J., Ohanian, L.: Trend-reverting fluctuations in the life-cycle model. J. Econ. Theory 119(2), 334–356 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balasko, Y., Shell, K.: The overlapping generations model. iii. the case of log-linear utility functions. J. Econ. Theory 24(1), 143–152 (1981)

    Google Scholar 

  • Barnett, W., Duzhak, E.: Empirical assessment of bifurcation regions within new keynesian models. Econ. Theory 45(1–2), 99–128 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, J., Russell, S.: Two-period cycles in a three-period overlapping generations model. J. Econ. Theory 109(2), 378–401 (2003)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., Fischer, S.: Lectures on Macroeconomics. MIT Press, Cambridge (1989)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bossi, L., Gomis-Porqueras, P.: Consequences of modelling habit persistence. Macroecon. Dyn. 13(3), 349–365 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cass, D., Okuno, M., Zilcha, I.: The role of money in supporting the pareto optimality of competitive equilibrium in consumption-loan type models. J. Econ. Theory 20(1), 41–80 (1979)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides, G., Donaldson, J., Mehra, R.: Junior can’t borrow: a new perspective on the equity premium puzzle. Q. J. Econ. 117(1), 269–296 (2002)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davila, J., Gottardi, P., Kajii, A.: Local sunspot equilibria reconsidered. Econ. Theory 31(3), 401–425 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De la Fuente, A.: Mathematical Methods and Models for Economists. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (2000)

  • Demichelis, S., Polemarchakis, H.: The determinacy of equilibrium in economies of overlapping generations. Econ. Theory 32(3), 461–475 (2007)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gale, D.: Pure exchange equilibrium of dynamic economic models. J. Econ. Theory 6(1), 12–36 (1973)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geanakoplos, J., Magill, M., Quinzii, M.: Demography and the long-run predictability of the stock market. Brookings Pap. Econ. Act. 1, 241–307 (2004)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guckenheimer, J., Holmes, P.: Nonlinear Oscillations, Dynamical Systems and Bifurcations of Vector Fields. Springer, New York (1983)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Henriksen, E., Spear, S.: Endogenous market incompleteness without market frictions: dynamic suboptimality of competitive equilibrium in multiperiod overlapping generations. J. Econ. Theory 147(2), 426–449 (2012)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Japelli, T., Pagano, M.: Saving, growth, and liquidity constraints. Q. J. Econ. 109(1), 83–109 (1994)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, T., Levine, D.: The economics of indeterminacy in overlapping generations models. J. Public Econ. 42(2), 219–243 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, T., Levine, D., Mas-Colell, A., Woodford, M.: Gross substitutability in large-square economies. J. Econ. Theory 54(1), 1–25 (1991)

    Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, T., Levine, D., Romer, P.: On characterizing equilibria of economies with externalities and taxes as solutions to optimization problems. Econ. Theory 2(1), 43–68 (1992)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri, A., Puhakka, M.: Habit persistence in overlapping generations economies under pure exchange. J. Econ. Theory 78(1), 176–186 (1998)

    Google Scholar 

  • Michel, P., Venditti, A.: Optimal growth and cycles in overlapping generations models. Econ. Theory 9(3), 511–528 (1997)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orrego, F: Habit formation and sunspots in overlapping generations models. Working Papers Series 013, Central Bank of Peru (2011)

  • Rozen, K.: Foundations of intrinsic habit formation. Econometrica 78(4), 1341–1373 (2010)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spear, S., Srivastava, S., Woodford, M.: Indeterminacy of stationary equilibrium in stochastic overlapping generations models. J. Econ. Theory 50(2), 265–284 (1990)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Fabrizio Orrego.

Additional information

This paper is based on my PhD dissertation at Carnegie Mellon University. I wish to thank my adviser Stephen Spear for his support and detailed advice throughout this project. I am also grateful to Laurence Ales and Yaroslav Kryukov, four anonymous referees and the coeditor Timothy Kehoe for useful ideas and suggestions on this paper. I also benefited from comments made by seminar participants at Carnegie Mellon University, the University of Pittsburgh and the Central Bank of Peru.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proofs

Proof

(Proposition 1) Note that \(a_{1,t}\left[ R_{t+1},R_{t}\right] =\omega _{1}-c_{1,t}\), and \(a_{2,t}\left[ R_{t},R_{t-1}\right] =R_{t-1}\omega _{1}+\omega _{2}-\left( R_{t-1}c_{1,t-1}+c_{2,t}\right) \), where \(c_{1,t}\) and \(c_{2,t+1}\) are defined as (3) and (4), respectively. The market-clearing condition \(A_{t+1}\left[R_{t+2},R_{t+1},R_{t}\right]=R_{t}A_{t}\left[R_{t+1},R_{t},R_{t-1}\right]\) can be written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} R_{t+2}=\frac{\gamma ^2\left( \omega _{1}-R_{t}A_{t}\left[ R_{t+1},R_{t},R_{t-1}\right] \right) }{\delta \left(R_{t+1}\omega _{1}+\omega _{2}\right) -\left( \omega _{1}-R_{t}A_{t}\left[ R_{t+1},R_{t},R_{t-1}\right] \right) \left( R_{t+1}+\gamma \right)} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\delta =\left( 1+\beta +\beta ^{2}\right) ^{-1}\). Clearly, this last expression corresponds to (5) in the text. \(\square \)

Proof

(Proposition 2) At any stationary equilibrium, \(R_{t}=R^{*}\). Then, \(a_{1} ^{*} =\omega _{1}-c_{1} ^{*}\), where \(c_{1} ^{*}=\left( \omega _{1}+\omega _{2}\right) \left\{ \left( 1+\beta +\beta ^{2}\right) \left( 1+\gamma +\gamma ^{2}\right)\right\} ^{-1}\). In the same fashion:

$$\begin{aligned} a_{2} ^{*} =\omega _{1}+\omega _{2} -\{ 1+(1+\beta )\gamma +\beta /\left( 1+\gamma \right) \} c_{1} ^{*} \end{aligned}$$

Hence, \(A^{*} \equiv a_{1} ^{*}+a_{2}^{*}\) is nonnegative as long as \(\left( 2-\lambda \right)\omega _{1} +\left( 1-\lambda \right)\omega _{2}\) is nonnegative, where \(\lambda =\frac{\left( 1+\beta \right) \left( 1+\gamma +\gamma ^{2}\right) +1+2\gamma }{\left( 1+\beta +\beta ^{2}\right) \left( 1+\gamma +\gamma ^{2}\right) \left( 1+\gamma \right) }\). Moreover, \(\mathrm sgn (A^{*}) = \mathrm sgn \{\left( 2-\lambda \right)\omega _{1} +\left( 1-\lambda \right)\omega _{2}\}\). \(\square \)

Proof

(Proposition 5) The aggregate savings function is given by \(A_{t} \equiv \alpha _{1,t}+ \alpha _{2,t} = \omega _{1} + \omega _{2} - (c_{1,t} + c_{2,t}) + R_{t-1}(\omega _{1} - c_{1,t-1})\). The partial derivative \(\partial A_{t}/ \partial R_{t}\), evaluated at the monetary steady state in which \(R_{t-1}=R_{t}=R_{t+1}=R^{*}=1\) (and given that \(\omega _{1}+\omega _{2}=1\)), is equal to:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial A_{t}}{\partial R_{t}}=-\left\{ \frac{\partial c_{1,t}}{\partial R_{t}} + \frac{\partial c_{2,t}}{\partial R_{t}} + \frac{\partial c_{1,t-1}}{\partial R_{t}} \right\} \end{aligned}$$

where:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial c_{1,t}}{\partial R_{t}}&= \frac{ \omega _{1}\{\gamma (1+\gamma )+1\}-1}{(1+\beta + \beta ^2)(1+\gamma + \gamma ^2)^{2}}\\ \frac{\partial c_{2,t}}{\partial R_{t}}&= \frac{\gamma }{(1+\beta + \beta ^2)(1+\gamma +\gamma ^{2})}\left\{ \frac{\beta }{(1+\gamma )^2} + \frac{(1+\beta ) (1+\gamma )\gamma ^{2}+\beta \gamma }{(1+\gamma )(1+\gamma + \gamma ^{2})}\right\} \\ \frac{\partial c_{1,t-1}}{\partial R_{t}}&= \frac{\gamma ^2}{(1+\beta + \beta ^2)(1+\gamma + \gamma ^{2})^{2}} \end{aligned}$$

Provided that \(\{\omega _{1}\{\gamma (1+\gamma )+1\}-1\}\) is positive, the savings function \(A_{t}\) is undoubtedly decreasing in \(R_{t}\) at yields near the golden rule. It is also clear that both \(\partial c_{1,t}/ \partial R_{t}\) and \(\partial c_{1,t-1}/ \partial R_{t}\) are decreasing functions of \(\beta \). These results suggest that if agents got more impatient (\(\beta \) decreases), the savings function would become even more negatively sloped. Nevertheless, the derivative \(\partial c_{2,t}/ \partial R_{t}\) is a decreasing function of \(\beta \) only when \(\beta >\overline{\beta }\) (when \(\beta \) is large). Otherwise, it is an increasing function of \(\beta \). Thus, the behavior of \(\partial c_{2,t}/ \partial R_{t}\) as a function of \(\beta \) explains why indeterminacy may persist for values of \(\beta \) close to 0.5. \(\square \)

1.2 Derivation of the offer curve

Let \(R_{t}=p_{t}/p_{t+1}\). The excess demand function when old is

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{t+1}&= c_{2,t+1}-\omega _{2} \\&= \omega _{1}R_{t}-c_{1,t}R_{t} \\&= \omega _{1}R_{t}-\frac{\omega _{1}R_{t}^{2}+\omega _{2}R_{t}}{\left( 1+\beta \right) \left( R_{t}+\gamma \right) } \\&= \frac{R_{t}\left[ \gamma \omega _{1}-\omega _{2}+\beta \omega _{1}\left( R_{t}+\gamma \right) \right] }{\left( 1+\beta \right) \left( R_{t}+\gamma \right) } \end{aligned}$$

where the second and third lines use \(\alpha _{t+1}=R_{t}\alpha _{t}\) and \(c_{1,t}=\left( \omega _{1}R_{t}+\omega _{2}\right) \left( 1+\beta \right)^{-1}\left( R_{t}+\gamma \right)^{-1}\), respectively. The last expression can be written as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} 0=\lambda _{2}R_{t}^{2}+\lambda _{1}R_{t}+\lambda _{0} \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda _{2}=\beta \omega _{1}, \lambda _{1}=\left( 1+\beta \right) \gamma \omega _{1}-\omega _{2}-\left( 1+\beta \right) \alpha _{t+1}\), and \(\lambda _{0}=-\left( 1+\beta \right) \gamma \alpha _{t+1}\). From this quadratic form, I get:

$$\begin{aligned} \hat{R}=\frac{-\lambda _{1}\pm \left( \lambda _{1}^{2}-4\lambda _{2}\lambda _{0}\right)^{\frac{1}{2}}}{2\lambda _{2}} \end{aligned}$$

By Descarte’s rule of signs, there is only one positive root \(\hat{R}^{+}\) (because \(\lambda _{2}>0, \lambda _{0}<0\) and \(\lambda _{1}\ne 0\)). Finally, the level of savings is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{t}=\{\omega _{1}[ \gamma +\beta ( \hat{R}^{+}+\gamma ) ] -\omega _{2}\}( 1+\beta )^{-1} (\hat{R}^{+}+\gamma )^{-1} \end{aligned}$$

The offer curve is the locus of points \((\alpha _{t},\alpha _{t+1})\).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Orrego, F. Habit formation and indeterminacy in overlapping generations models. Econ Theory 55, 225–241 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-013-0746-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-013-0746-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation