Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

International trade and domestic distortions

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

When full competition prevails in product, labor, and capital markets, positive or negative external trade shocks may be accommodated by the migration of jobs between sectors; the negative impact on some households’ income of lower nominal wages will be more than offset by lower prices of imported final goods. Unemployment, if any, will be temporary, unless labor market rigidities prevent the necessary adjustment. By contrast, we argue that trade shocks trigger a process of creative destruction that necessarily causes distortions in the structure of productive capacity and, hence, market disequilibria. Therefore, the structural change that follows trade shocks can no longer be analyzed within an equilibrium framework. The transition following a shock may be characterized by increasing imbalances, and create scope for policy intervention. The model presented in this paper, which focuses on the time dimension of production and market imbalances, allows us to clarify the debate.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We assume that these export quotas are not related to domestic factors. For example, the penetration of low cost goods from China and other emerging economies is based on cost differentials so wide in size that they reduce the capacity to export of some (basic) sectors regardless of domestic pricing policies.

  2. Upper case variables usually denote economy-wide variables, while lower cases denote firm specific ones.

  3. Notice that an issue of strategic behavior could arise here: knowing the rationing rule, firms could modify their behavior in order to obtain, once rationed, their optimal quantity. We overlook this issue, as it presupposes perfect knowledge by the firm of the behavior of its competitors in their own as well as in the other sector.

  4. Specifically, we have κ b  = 1.6, κ a  = 0.8, λ b  = 0.2, λ a  = 10. Overall productivity in the two sectors is then X b /L b  = 0.17 and X a /L a  = 0.74. As the model that we build is strongly stylized, the parameter values we choose are simply meant to capture qualitative features of the system.

  5. This simulation extends to a disequilibrium framework Keynes’ argument for wage rigidity as a means to avoid cumulative aggregate demand-aggregate supply downward spiraling (see the chapter on wages of Keynes 1936). For a detailed discussion of this argument, refer to Amendola et al. (2004) and Saraceno (2004).

References

  • Amendola M, J-L Gaffard (1998) Out of equilibrium. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Amendola M, J-L Gaffard, Saraceno F (2004) Wage flexibility and unemployment: the Keynesian perspective revisited. Scott J Polit Econ 51(5):654–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benassy J-P (1982) The economics of market disequilibrium. Academic Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Brecher RA (1974) Minimum wage rates and the pure theory of international trade. Q J Econ 88:98–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomory RE, WJ Baumol (2000) Global trade and conflicting national interests. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1953) An inaugural lecture. Oxf Econ Pap 5:117–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1973) Capital and time. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1985) A technology gap model of international trade. In: Jungenfelt K, Hague D (eds) Structural adjustment in advanced economies. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas RE (1993) Making a miracle. Econometrica 61(2):251–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (1998) The debate over globalization: how to move forward by looking backward. In: Conference on the future of the world trading system. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (2004) Where Ricardo and Mill rebut and confirm arguments of mainstream economists supporting globalization. J Econ Perspect 18(3):135–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saraceno F (2004) Wage regimes, accumulation, and finance constraints: Keynesian unemployment revisited. Document de Travail de l’OFCE, Paris, 2004-1

  • Stiglitz JE, Charlton A (2006) Fair trade for all. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper benefited of funding from the European Community’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007–2013) under Socio-economic Sciences and Humanities, grant agreement no. 225408 (POLHIA). We thank Mario Amendola, Uwe Cantner, and an anonymous referee for comments and suggestions on a previous draft. Our work also benefited from interaction with participants to the workshop on Openness and Innovation in Emerging Financial Markets, Beijing, March 2007, and to the International Economic Association Conference, Istanbul, June 2008. The usual disclaimers apply.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francesco Saraceno.

Appendix: Proof of propositions

Appendix: Proof of propositions

Proof of Proposition 1   \(\frac{d\alpha}{dW_{a}}>0\) and \(\frac{d\alpha}{dW_{b}}<0.\)

Proof

\(\frac{d\alpha}{dW_{a}}>0:\)

$$ \begin{array}{c} \left( \dfrac{\sqrt{\xi_{b}}}{\sqrt{\xi_{a}}}\left( 1-\gamma+\gamma \delta\right) -\dfrac{\sqrt{\xi_{a}}}{\sqrt{\xi_{b}}}\gamma(1-\delta)\right) >0\\ \iff\\ \xi_{b}\left( 1-\gamma+\gamma\delta\right) -\xi_{a}\gamma(1-\delta)>0 \end{array} $$

Substituting:

$$ \begin{array}{rll} &&\left( \left( 1-\gamma\delta\right) W_{b}+\gamma\left( 1-\delta\right) W_{a}\right) \left( 1-\gamma+\gamma\delta\right) \\ &&\quad -(\gamma-\gamma\delta)\left( \gamma\delta W_{b}+\left( 1-\gamma\left( 1-\delta\right) \right) W_{a}\right) \\ &&\quad=\allowbreak W_{b}(1-\gamma)>0 \end{array} $$

\(\frac{d\alpha}{dW_{b}}<0:\)

$$ \begin{array}{c} \left( \dfrac{\sqrt{\xi_{b}}}{\sqrt{\xi_{a}}}\gamma\delta-\dfrac{\sqrt{\xi_{a} }}{\sqrt{\xi_{b}}}(1-\gamma\delta)\right) <0\\ \iff\\ \left( \xi_{b}\gamma\delta-\xi_{a}(1-\gamma\delta)\right) <0 \end{array} $$

Substituting:

$$ \begin{array}{rll} && \left( \left( 1-\gamma\delta\right) W_{b}+\gamma\left( 1-\delta\right) W_{a}\right) \gamma\delta\\ & &\quad-(1-\gamma\delta)\left( \gamma\delta W_{b}+\left( 1-\gamma\left( 1-\delta\right) \right) W_{a}\right) \\ & &\quad =(\gamma-1)W_{a}<0 \end{array} $$

Proof of Proposition 2   \(\frac{d\pi_{a}}{dW_{a}}>0\) and \(\frac{d\pi_{a}}{dW_{b}}>0.\)

Proof

Equilibrium profit can be defined, from Eqs. 7 and 8a:

$$ \pi_{a}(=\pi_{b})=\frac{\xi_{a}}{\alpha^{2}}=\frac{\left( \sqrt{\xi_{b} }+\sqrt{\xi_{a}}\right) ^{2}}{N^{2}} $$

As ξ a and ξ b are positively affected by both W a and W b , we conclude that any increase in external demand increases equilibrium profits. □

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Gaffard, JL., Saraceno, F. International trade and domestic distortions. J Evol Econ 22, 275–301 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0244-2

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-011-0244-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation