Skip to main content
Log in

Endogeneity-corrected stochastic frontier with market imperfections

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

While the product and labour market imperfections reveal efficiency losses, they may influence technology adoption and its change, raising the endogeneity issue of productivity and efficiency estimates. Using a two-step approach, this work offers the endogeneity-corrected stochastic frontier for such a contemporaneous relation and accounts for efficiency and productivity losses due to market imperfections. A modified frontier function, defined as the residue per capital unit, has been drawn from the Cobb–Douglas function to estimate the terms containing the product and labour market imperfections along with other factors capturing the levels of technology, scale and technical efficiency. First, a standard frontier panel model estimates technology and technical efficiency terms with a proxy function in polynomials of market imperfection terms used for the contemporaneous relation, and then a GMM approach applies to the residue to estimate the parameters containing market imperfections. The estimated results using the three-digit industries across 17 major Indian states for 2008–2016 reveal a strong presence of product and labour market imperfections and associated efficiency losses. The efficiency in the product market has been lower and has further deteriorated in most industries, but not in the labour market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Annual Survey of Industries, Central Statistical Organisation, Government of India

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. A limited number of firms have enjoyed sufficient market power, evident recently. Some have emerged as super-stars in the global market (Dorn et al. 2017; Kehrig and Vincent 2017). As a result, they may compete with their rivals strategically. The degree of market imperfections, measured in terms of the markup over marginal costs, varies across firms or industries and has risen in several countries recently (De Loecker and Eeckhout 2018). A similar dis-aggregated analysis over 43 countries found that an average price with markup over the marginal cost of production exceeded one during 2016. Applying different data sets, Weche and Wambach (2021) and Calligaris et al. (2017) accounted for almost similar results. Diez et al. (2018) observed a steady and rising trend of mark-ups from the 1980 s and found an accelerated pace from the mid-2000 s in a set of 33 advanced economies. On the other hand, recent studies revealed that workers, too, enjoyed a degree of bargaining power in many countries. The estimated union bargaining power ranges from 0.12 to 0.4 points on a scale from 0 to 1 in Europe and some parts of Asia (Dobbelaere 2004; Maiti 2013).

  2. When a firm typically incurs efficiency losses due to extra input usages compared to the best practice combinations using a given technology, it registers technical inefficiency. On the other hand, any additional cost incurred for an input combination in contrast to the most economical variety at a given price, giving technically the same efficient output, refers to allocative inefficiency.

  3. The shortfall of production from the frontier is captured by the one-sided error and the exponential of the error represents technical efficiency.

  4. This approach is a bit different from Dobbelaere and Mairesse (2013) and Maiti (2013), who have estimated the product and labour market imperfections without consideration of their endogeneity issues and the resultant efficiency losses.

  5. The reform included the gradual withdrawal of trade barriers, dis-investment in the public sector, de-reservation of small-scale industries, de-licensing industrial activities, private sector expansion, removal of the obstacles on foreign capital, financial sector autonomy, and exchange rate convertibility.

  6. The two-stage approach is to be applied here to deal with the endogeneity issue for productivity and technical efficiency terms that use the third-order polynomials of instrumental and state variables. Hence, we kept a simple production function and added the third-order polynomials of instrumental variables. Thus, the productivity and efficiency estimates may not suffer from omitted variable bias.

  7. Since the dependent variable, capturing residual change per unit of capital, used in our model is different from the standard form applied in the standard SFA model, we assume the terms of market imperfections that use k can be simultaneously related and there is no reason to consider k as a separate proxy in the group.

  8. https://www.privacyshield.gov/ps/article?id=India-Trade-Barriers

References

  • Abraham F, Konings J, Vanormelingen S (2009) The effect of globalization on union bargaining and price-cost margins of firms. Rev World Econ 145(1):13–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D (2023) Distorted innovation: Does the market get the direction of technology right? In AEA Papers and Proceedings, vol. 113, pages 1–28. American Economic Association 2014 Broadway, Suite 305, Nashville, TN 37203

  • Aghion P, Burgess R, Redding SJ, Zilibotti F (2008) The unequal effects of liberalization: evidence from dismantling the license raj in India. Am Econ Rev 98(4):1397–1412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Hasanov F, Cherif R (2021) Competition, innovation, and inclusive growth. IMF Working Paper No. 2021/080

  • Amsler C, Prokhorov A, Schmidt P (2016) Endogeneity in stochastic frontier models. J Econom 190(2):280–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsler C, Prokhorov A, Schmidt P (2017) Endogenous environmental variables in stochastic frontier models. J Econom 199(2):131–140

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battese G, Coelli T (1992) Frontier production function. Technical Efficiency

  • Besley T, Burgess R (2004) Can labor regulation hinder economic performance? Evidence from India. Q J Econ 119(1):91–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati J, Srinivasan TN (2002) Trade and poverty in the poor countries. Am Econ Rev 92(2):180–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati JN, Srinivasan TN, et al (1975) Foreign trade regimes and economic development: India. NBER Books

  • Bhattacharjea A (2020) Labour market flexibility in indian industry: a critical survey of the literature. International Labour Review

  • Bhattacharjea A (2021) Labour market flexibility in Indian manufacturing: a critical survey of the literature. Int Lab Rev 160(2):197–217

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Calligaris S, Criscuolo C, Marcolin L (2017) Digital and market transformations. Technical report, Discussion paper, OECD Report

  • Castiglione C, Infante D (2014) Icts and time-span in technical efficiency gains. A stochastic frontier approach over a panel of Italian manufacturing firms. Econ Model 41:55–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Y-Y, Schmidt P, Wang H-J (2014) Consistent estimation of the fixed effects stochastic frontier model. J Econom 181(2):65–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clifford AA (1973) Multivariate error analysis: a handbook of error propagation and calculation in many-parameter systems. Wiley

    Google Scholar 

  • Das DK, Aggarwal SC, Erumban AA, Das PC (2019) What is new about India’s economic growth? an industry level productivity perspective. Indian Growth and Development Review

  • De Loecker J, Eeckhout J (2018) Global market power. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Dhanora M, Sharma R, Khachoo Q (2018) Non-linear impact of product and process innovations on market power: a theoretical and empirical investigation. Econ Model 70:67–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diez MF, Leigh MD, Tambunlertchai S (2018) Global market power and its macroeconomic implications. International Monetary Fund

  • Dobbelaere S (2004) Estimation of price-cost margins and union bargaining power for Belgian manufacturing. Int J Ind Org 22(10):1381–1398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbelaere S, Mairesse J (2013) Panel data estimates of the production function and product and labor market imperfections. J Appl Econom 28(1):1–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domowitz I, Hubbard R, Petersen B (1988) Market structure and cyclical fluctuations in U.S. manufacturing. Rev Econ Stat 70(1):55–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dorn D, Katz LF, Patterson C, Van Reenen J et al (2017) Concentrating on the fall of the labor share. Am Econ Rev 107(5):180–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dutt AK (1984) Stagnation, income distribution and monopoly power. Camb J Econ 8(1):25–40

    Google Scholar 

  • Greene W (2005) Reconsidering heterogeneity in panel data estimators of the stochastic frontier model. J Econom 126(2):269–303

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimalda G (2016) Can labour market rigidity foster economic efficiency? A model with non-general purpose technical change. Eur Bus Rev 6:79–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guan Z, Kumbhakar SC, Myers RJ, Lansink AO (2009) Measuring excess capital capacity in agricultural production. Am J Agric Econ 91(3):765–776

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE (1988) The relation between price and marginal cost in us industry. J Polit Econ 96(5):921–947

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison A (1994) Productivity, imperfect competition and trade reform. J Int Econ 36(1–2):53–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasan R, Mitra D, Ramaswamy KV (2007) Trade reforms, labor regulations, and labor-demand elasticities: empirical evidence from India. Rev Econ Stat 89(3):466–481

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasan R, Mitra D, Ranjan P, Ahsan RN (2012) Trade liberalization and unemployment: theory and evidence from India. J Dev Econ 97(2):269–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu Y, Huang G, Sasaki Y (2020) Estimating production functions with robustness against errors in the proxy variables. J Econom 215(2):375–398

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hung-pin L, Kumbhakar SC (2021) Panel stochastic frontier model with endogenous inputs and correlated random components. J Bus Econ Stat 41(1):80–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jayadev A (2007) Capital account openness and the labour share of income. Camb J Econ 31(3):423–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan M, Kutlu L (2017) Handling endogeneity in stochastic frontier analysis. Econ Bull 39(2):889–901

    Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU (2022) Panel stochastic frontier models with endogeneity. Stata J 22(3):643–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU, Kutlu L (2017) Endogeneity in panel stochastic frontier models: an application to the Japanese cotton spinning industry. Appl Econ 49(59):5935–5939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karakaplan MU, Kutlu L (2019) Estimating market power using a composed error model. Scott J Polit Econ 66(4):489–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kehrig M, Vincent N (2017) Growing productivity without growing wages: the micro-level anatomy of the aggregate labor share decline. Economic Research Initiatives at Duke (ERID) Working Paper, (244)

  • Klein N, Herwartz H, Kneib T (2020) Modelling regional patterns of inefficiency: a bayesian approach to geoadditive panel stochastic frontier analysis with an application to cereal production in england and wales. J Econom 214(2):513–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konings J, Cayseele PV, Warzynski F (2005) The effects of privatization and competitive pressure on firms’ price-cost margins: micro evidence from emerging economies. Rev Econom Stat 87(1):124–134

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konings J, Van Cayseele P, Warzynski F (2001) The dynamics of industrial mark-ups in two small open economies: Does national competition policy matter? Int J Ind Organ 19(5):841–859

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ku HH et al (1966) Notes on the use of propagation of error formulas. J Res Natl Bureau Stand 70(4)

  • Kumbhakar SC, Parmeter CF, Zelenyuk V (2020) Stochastic frontier analysis: foundations and advances i. Handbook of production economics, pp 1–40

  • Kumbhakar SC, Tsionas EG, Sipiläinen T (2009) Joint estimation of technology choice and technical efficiency: an application to organic and conventional dairy farming. J Prod Anal 31(3):151–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Wang H, Horncastle AP (2015) A practitioner’s guide to stochastic frontier analysis using Stata. Cambridge University Press

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SC, Wang H-J (2005) Estimation of growth convergence using a stochastic production frontier approach. Econ Lett 88(3):300–305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumbhakar SL, Lovell K (2000) Stochastic frontier analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L (2010) Battese–Coelli estimator with endogenous regressors. Econ Lett 109(2):79–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Sickles RC (2012) Estimation of market power in the presence of firm level inefficiencies. J Econom 168(1):141–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Tran KC, Tsionas MG (2019) A time-varying true individual effects model with endogenous regressors. J Econom 211(2):539–559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kutlu L, Wang R (2018) Estimation of cost efficiency without cost data. J Prod Anal 49(2):137–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai H-P, Kumbhakar SC (2019) Technical and allocative efficiency in a panel stochastic production frontier system model. Eur J Oper Res 278(1):255–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70(2):317–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li Q, Racine JS (2007) Nonparametric econometrics: theory and practice. Princeton University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Maiti D (2013) Market imperfections, trade reform and total factor productivity growth: theory and practices from India. J Prod Anal 40(2):207–218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maiti D (2019) Trade, labor share, and productivity in India’s industries. In: Labor income share in Asia, Springer, pp 179–205

  • Nin-Pratt A, Yu B, Fan S (2010) Comparisons of agricultural productivity growth in china and India. J Prod Anal 33(3):209–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nishimizu M, Page JM (1982) Total factor productivity growth, technological progress and technical efficiency change: dimensions of productivity change in yugoslavia, 1965–78. Econ J 92(368):920–936

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orea L, Álvarez IC (2019) A new stochastic frontier model with cross-sectional effects in both noise and inefficiency terms. J Econom 213(2):556–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orea L, Steinbuks J (2018) Estimating market power in homogenous product markets using a composed error model: application to the california electricity market. Econ Inq 56(2):1296–1321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pagan A, Ullah A (1999) Nonparametric econometrics. Cambridge University Press

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Parello CP (2011) Labor market rigidity and productivity growth in a model of innovation-driven growth. Econ Model 28(3):1058–1067

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Petrin A, Sivadasan J (2013) Estimating lost output from allocative inefficiency, with an application to Chile and firing costs. Rev Econ Stat 95(1):286–301

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pires JO, Garcia F (2012) Productivity of nations: a stochastic frontier approach to TFP decomposition. Econ Res Int 2012

  • Porter ME (1990) The competitive advonioge of notions. Harv Bus Rev 73:91

    Google Scholar 

  • Shee A, Stefanou SE (2015) Endogeneity corrected stochastic production frontier and technical efficiency. Am J Agric Econ 97(3):939–952

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sung N (2007) Information technology, efficiency and productivity: evidence from Korean local governments. App Econ 39(13):1691–1703

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang H-J, Ho C-W (2010) Estimating fixed-effect panel stochastic frontier models by model transformation. J Econom 157(2):286–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weche JP, Wambach A (2021) The fall and rise of market power in Europe. Jahrbücher für Nationalökonomie und Statistik 241(5–6):555–575

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dibyendu Maiti.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank the editor, associate editor and two anonymous referees for the excellent suggestions that helped to improve this version of the paper. We further thank Sattwik Santra, Sandip Datta and Surender Kumar for their technical support in estimation. Usual disclaimers apply.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Nash bargaining solution

The Nash bargaining expression is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{w,L}\Omega =(Lw+(\bar{L}-L)w_0-\bar{L}w_0)^\theta (PY-wL)^{1-\theta } \end{aligned}$$
(A.24)

Differentiating with respect to wage and employment and then arranging terms, it can be expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} w= & {} (1-\theta )w_0+\theta \frac{pY}{L} \end{aligned}$$
(A.25)
$$\begin{aligned} w= & {} \frac{\theta }{1-\theta }\frac{pY-wL}{L}+\frac{\partial (pY)}{\partial L} \end{aligned}$$
(A.26)

One can find that \(\frac{\partial (pY)}{\partial L}=\frac{\partial (pY)}{\partial Y} \frac{\partial (Y)}{\partial L}=\frac{p}{m}\frac{\partial Y}{\partial L}\). where, \(\frac{\partial (pY)}{\partial Y}= p(1-\frac{1}{|e_p|}); |e_p|= -\frac{\partial p}{\partial Y}\frac{Y}{p}>1; m=\frac{|e_p|}{|e_p|-1}\) and \(|e_p|=\frac{\partial Y}{\partial p}\frac{p}{Y}\)

Table 5 Results of simple stochastic frontier model
Table 6 Results of endogeneity-corrected stochastic frontier model

Multiply by L and then dividing by pY of (A.26), we get

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{wL}{pY}=\frac{\theta }{1-\theta }\big (1-\frac{wL}{pY}\big )+\frac{1}{m}\frac{\partial Y}{\partial L} \frac{L}{Y} \end{aligned}$$

It is assumed that \(s^U_L=\frac{w L}{pY}\) and \(\beta _L=\frac{\partial Y}{\partial L} \frac{L}{Y}\). Applying these expressions and rearranging the terms, it can expressed as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _L=s_L=m\left[ s^U_L +\frac{\theta }{1-\theta } (s^U_L-1)\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.27)

Use that \(m=\frac{1}{1-\beta }\)

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _L=s_L=\frac{1}{1-\beta }\left[ S^U_L +\frac{\theta }{1-\theta } (s^U_L-1)\right] \end{aligned}$$
(A.28)

Using the above expression and ignoring subscripts from Eq. (4), we get

$$\begin{aligned} (y-k)-\frac{1}{1-\beta }\left[ s^U_L +\frac{\theta }{1-\theta } (s^U_L-1)\right] (l-k)=\lambda k +a+v-u \end{aligned}$$

Rearranging the terms, we find the following expression.

$$\begin{aligned}{} & {} (y-k)- s^U_L (l-k)= \beta (y-k)+\frac{\theta }{1-\theta } (s^U_L-1)](l-k)\nonumber \\{} & {} \quad +\frac{\lambda }{\mu } k +(1-\beta ) (a+v-u) \end{aligned}$$
(A.29)

1.2 Frontier regression results

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Maiti, D., Neogi, C. Endogeneity-corrected stochastic frontier with market imperfections. Empir Econ (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-024-02577-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-024-02577-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation