Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Using household-level data to guide borrower-based macro-prudential policy

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Many countries introduced borrower-based instruments to constrain credit to households exceeding a limit on their loan-to-value ratio, their (mortgage) debt-to-income ratio or their debt service-to-income ratio. We evaluate how well borrower-based instruments can target households that would become vulnerable after a shock. We apply the signals approach to derive “optimal” limits that minimize classification errors (either granting credit to financially vulnerable households or constraining credit to households that are not vulnerable). To illustrate, we simulate an adverse scenario using household-level data from Luxembourg. We find that combining several ratios could better target households that would become vulnerable after a shock.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Source: Own calculations based on waves 1, 2 and 3 of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; only households with recent HMR mortgages. Panel (a) Cumulative distribution functions are calculated across all 5 implicates each year. Vertical lines indicate lowest and highest limits envisaged by the law. We omit the upper tail of the cumulative distribution functions. Panel (b) Shares among households with recent HMR mortgages calculated across all 5 implicates in 2018

Fig. 2

Source: Own calculations based on waves 2 and 3 of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; only households with recent HMR mortgages. Panel (a) Cumulative distribution functions are calculated across all 5 implicates for each year. Vertical lines indicate lowest and highest limits envisaged by the law. We omit the upper tail of the cumulative distribution functions. Panel (b) Shares among households with recent HMR mortgages calculated across all 5 implicates in 2018

Fig. 3

Source: Own calculations based on waves 2 and 3 of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; only households with recent HMR mortgages. Panel (a) Cumulative distribution functions are calculated across all 5 implicates for each year. Vertical lines indicate lowest and highest limits envisaged by the law. We omit the upper tail of the cumulative distribution functions. Panel (b) Shares among households with recent HMR mortgages calculated across all 5 implicates in 2018

Fig. 4

Source: Own calculations based on waves 1, 2 and 3 of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; only households with recent HMR mortgages. Panel (a) Cumulative distribution functions are calculated across all 5 implicates for each year. Vertical lines indicate lowest and highest limits envisaged by the law. Panel (b) Shares among households with recent HMR mortgages calculated across all 5 implicates in 2018

Fig. 5

Source: Own calculations based on the 3rd wave of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; the statistics are calculated by pooling all implicates. Note: Peaks in average LGD difference between compliant and affected households (dashed black line) indicate best limits

Fig. 6

Source: Own calculations based on the 3rd wave of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; classification errors are calculated by pooling all implicates

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See https://www.esrb.europa.eu/national_policy/html/index.en.html.

  2. See Sangaré (2019) for a study based on a DSGE modelling approach applied to Luxembourg.

  3. See http://data.legilux.public.lu/file/eli-etat-leg-loi-2019-12-04-a811-jo-fr-pdf.pdf

  4. Other studies reached similar conclusion using different methodologies, data and approaches. Grodecka’s (2020) theoretical exercise provides the arguments underlying our results. In a DSGE framework calibrated for Sweden, Chen et al. (2016) find that a mix of macroprudential measures is needed to deliver the maximum welfare benefit.

  5. See http://cdrs.lu/9-novembre-2020/.

  6. See http://data.legilux.public.lu/file/eli-etat-leg-rcsf-2020-12-03-a969-jo-fr-pdf.pdf.

  7. In the category of loans for principal residences granted to borrowers who are not first-time buyers, lending institutions may grant individual loans with an LTV ratio of up to 100%, provided that the aggregate amount of the loans benefiting from this derogation (90% < LTV ratio ≤ 100%) represents no more than 15% of the annual aggregate amount of this category of loans granted by this institution.

  8. To facilitate reading, “debt burden ratios” in the text also include the limit on mortgage maturity.

  9. Evidence in Ferreira (2018) suggests that such a feedback loop may have been active in Luxembourg.

  10. http://legilux.public.lu/eli/etat/leg/loi/2019/12/04/a811/jo

  11. The initial amount of the most recent HMR mortgage is reported directly in the survey. If the household has more than one mortgage, we adjust older mortgages using a linear approximation based on the difference between the initial value of the older loan and its outstanding amount at the survey date.

  12. For each debt burden indicator, we run a quantile regression (results not reported) to confirm that age and wealth are not statistically significant when accounting for other household characteristics (listed in Table 12).

  13. Mortgage rates reported by banks in Table 03.02 on www.bcl.lu declined from 2.15% in 2014 to 1.85% in 2018.

  14. Some less regular mortgage maturities are also visible, reflecting some irregular values as reported by survey participants.

  15. Fixed-rate mortgages usually involve higher interest rates.

  16. See Albacete and Fessler (2010), Ampudia et al. (2016), Giordana and Ziegelmeyer (2020) and Meriküll and Rõõm (2020).

  17. Leika and Marchettini (2017) call this measure “probability of incurring distress”.

  18. See Hallissey et al. (2014) and Nier et al. (2019) for studies using loan-level data to help calibrate a macro-prudential tool. Since these authors observe defaults directly, they do not need model-generated default rates or survey-based measures.

  19. We measure liquid assets as the sum of bank deposits (mainly sight and saving accounts), stocks (publicly traded stocks, mutual funds, managed accounts, hedge funds), bonds, and potentially less liquid assets (including private businesses other than self-employment and other assets).

  20. Basic living costs are estimated using household specific amounts spent on utilities (e.g. electricity, water, gas, telephone…) and on food consumed at home, as well as 50% of the amounts spent on food outside the home.

  21. Unemployment benefits in Luxembourg are 80% of the last gross wage or 85% if the unemployed person receives child benefits for his/her dependents. Unemployment benefits cannot exceed 2.5 times the minimum wage during the first 6 months and 2.0 times the minimum wage in the following 6 months.

  22. For a detailed description of the REVIS with respect to eligibility conditions and the amount of the benefit please consult: https://guichet.public.lu/en/citoyens/sante-social/action-sociale/aide-financiere/revenu-inclusion-sociale-revis.html#bloub-11

  23. See Albacete et al. (2018), Leika and Marchettini (2017), and Bańbuła et al. (2016).

  24. This approach has also been used to evaluate indicators of economic recessions and expansions (Berge and Jordà 2011), to evaluate the performance of investment strategies (Jordà and Taylor 2011), to evaluate indicators of real credit contractions and expansions (Jordà, 2012), and to evaluate early-warning systems for bank distress (Betz et al. 2014), for banking crises (Drehmann and Juselius 2014), or for financial crises (Candelon et al. 2012; Detken et al. 2014).

  25. The Receiver Operating Characteristic (ROC) curve plots the True Positive Rate (TPR) against type I error for all candidate limits in our grid search. See Hanley and McNeil (1982) for a definition.

  26. See Hsieh and Turnbull (1996) for further definitions.

  27. This limit will only be “optimal” in the sense of minimizing classification errors. In our application, this will not necessarily correspond to minimizing the policymaker’s loss function, which would require specifying the links between classification errors, systemic risk and social welfare.

  28. Alternatively, Buckmann et al. (2023) identify “optimal” limits by targeting specific thresholds for type I errors (or “hit rates”). However, this alternative approach to selecting the optimal point in the ROC curve appears less suitable for examining survey data without information on actual credit defaults, where hit rates would be difficult to interpret. Buckmann et al. (2023) observe banks that failed in the aftermath of the 2007–2008 global financial crisis directly in their data. Therefore, with such a condition variable, it makes sense to target for specific values of type I errors to identify “optimal” limits. For borrower-based measures, it would be similar if loan defaults were observed and the condition variable took the value one for households in arrears and zero otherwise. However, in our application, household financial vulnerability is not directly observed but estimated using a measure of the probability of default. The advantage of using the probability of default is that we can simulate adverse scenarios. This helps to find optimal limits under adverse conditions if crises episodes are not observed.

  29. Mortgage maturity is not really a debt burden ratio (Sect. 2.2), so we only analyse it in combination with other ratios.

  30. Given our nonparametric approach, the limited number of observations and their heterogeneous nature produces ROC curves that are kinked rather than smooth parabolas (see Fig. 7). As a result, outlying points on the ROC curve may be optimal for several values of the policy parameter, corresponding to different slopes of the tradeoff between Type I and Type II errors.

  31. Table 13 in the appendix evaluates the performance of all combined rules in the adverse scenario. Table 14 provides a robustness check by replacing DI with MDI in the set of ratios being combined.

  32. Only final household weights were considered to ensure their statistical representativeness in the population.

  33. We adapted Fawcett’s (2006) proposal to focus on the costs of classification errors instead of plotting benefits of true positives against cost of false negatives.

  34. Table 5 provides definitions of the classification errors and the loss function.

  35. This includes all individuals between 16 and 64 years of age who reported their primary labour status as 1—Doing regular work for pay/self-employed/working in family business; or 2—On sick/maternity/other leave (except holidays), planning to return to work; or 3—Unemployed.

  36. According to official figures (Statec Table B3019), the seasonally adjusted unemployment rate averaged 5.4% between April and November 2018 (when fieldwork took place for HFCS wave 3). This falls within our estimated confidence interval (3.8% to 5.6%).

References

  • Akinci O, Olmstead-Rumsey J (2018) How effective are macroprudential policies? An empirical investigation. J Financ Intermed 33:33–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Albacete N, Fessler P (2010) Stress testing Austrian Households. Österreichische Nationalbank Financial Stability Report 19, June

  • Albacete N, Lindner P (2017) Simulating the impact of borrower-based macroprudential policies on mortgages and the real estate sector in Austria—evidence from the Household Finance and Consumption Survey 2014. Financial Stability Report 33, Österreichische Nationalbank, June

  • Albacete N, Fessler P, Lindner P (2018) One policy to rule them all? On the effectiveness of LTV, DTI and DSTI ratio limits as macroprudential policy tools. Financial Stability Report 35, Österreichische Nationalbank, June

  • Ampudia M, van Vlokhoven H, Zochowski D (2016) Financial fragility of euro area households. J Financ Stab 27:250–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Araujo J, Patnam DM, Popescu A, Valencia F, Yao W (2020) Effects of macroprudential policy: evidence from over 6,000 estimates. IMF Working Paper WP/20/67

  • Bańbuła P, Kotuła A, Przeworska J, Strzelecki P (2016) Which households are really financially distressed: How micro data could inform the macroprudential policy. In: IFC Bulletins chapters, Bank for International Settlements (eds), Combining micro and macro statistical data for financial stability analysis, vol 41. Basle

  • Berge TJ, Jordà Ò (2011) Evaluating the classification of economic activity into recessions and expansions. Am Econ J Macroecon 3(2):246–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Betz F, Opricǎ S, Peltonen TA, Sarlin P (2014) Predicting distress in European banks. J Bank Finance 45:225–241

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckmann M, Gallego Marquez P, Gimpelewicz M, Kapadia S, Rismanchi K (2023) The more the merrier? Evidence on the value of multiple requirements in bank regulation. J Bank Finance 149:106753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Candelon B, Dumitrescu E, Hurlin C (2012) How to evaluate an early-warning system: toward a unified statistical framework for assessing financial crises forecasting methods. IMF Econ Rev 60(1):75–113

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantú C, Gambacorta L, Shim I (2020) How effective are macroprudential policies in Asia-Pacific? Evidence from a meta-analysis. In: Measuring the effectiveness of macroprudential policies using supervisory bank-level data, BIS Papers No 110, February

  • Cerutti E, Claessens S, Laeven L (2017) The use and effectiveness of macroprudential policies: new evidence. J Financ Stab 28:203–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • CGFS (2016) Experiences with the ex-ante appraisal of macroprudential instruments. CGFS Paper No. 56

  • Chen J, Columba F, Beaumont C (2016) Macroprudential and monetary policy interactions in a DSGE model for Sweden, IMF Working Paper WP/16/74

  • Chen Y, Mathä T, Pulina G, Schuster B, Ziegelmeyer M (2020) The Luxembourg Household Finance and Consumption Survey: results from the third wave. Banque centrale du Luxembourg Working Paper 142

  • Detken C, Weeken O, Alessi L, Bonfim D, Boucinha M, Castro C, Frontczak S, Giordana G, Giese J, Jahn N, Kakes J, Klaus B, Lang J, Puzanova N, Welz P (2014) Operationalising the countercyclical capital buffer: indicator selection, threshold identification and calibration options. ESRB Occas Pap Ser 5:1–95

    Google Scholar 

  • Drehmann M, Juselius M (2014) Evaluating early warning indicators of banking crises: satisfying policy requirements. Int J Forecast 22(3):493–518

    Google Scholar 

  • Epure M, Mihai I, Minoiu C, Peydró J-L (2018) Household credit, global financial cycle, and macroprudential policies: credit register evidence from an emerging country. IMF Working Paper WP/18/13

  • ESRB (2017) The ESRB handbook on operationalising macroprudential policy in the banking sector. Eur Syst Risk Board. https://doi.org/10.2849/04791

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fawcett T (2006) ROC graphs with instance-varying costs. Pattern Recogn Lett 27(8):882–891

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira Filipe S (2018) Housing prices and mortgage credit in Luxembourg. BCL Working Paper 117. February 2018

  • Gambacorta L, Murcia A (2020) The impact of macroprudential policies in Latin America: an empirical analysis using credit registry data. J Financ Intermed 42:100828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrido F, Verbeke W, Bravo C (2018) A Robust profit measure for binary classification model evaluation. Expert Syst Appl 92:154–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giordana G (2016) Welfare and stochastic dominance for the measurement of banks’ domestic systemic importance: analytical framework and application. Int J Financ Econ 21:192–208

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giordana G, Ziegelmeyer M (2020) Stress testing household balance sheets in Luxembourg. Q Rev Finance Econ 76:115–138

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girshina A, Mathä TY, Ziegelmeyer M (2017) The Luxembourg Household Finance and Consumption Survey: results from the 2nd wave, BCL Working Paper 106

  • Godoy de Araujo DK, Barroso JBRB, Gonzalez RB (2020) Loan-to-value policy and housing finance: effects on constrained borrowers. J Financ Intermed 42:100830

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Górnicka L, Valderrama L (2020) Stress testing and calibration of macroprudential policy tools. IMF Working Paper WP/20/165

  • Grodecka A (2020) On the effectiveness of loan-to-value regulation in a multiconstraint framework. J Money Credit Bank 52(5):1231–1270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gross M, Población García FJ (2017) Assessing the efficacy of borrower-based macroprudential policy using an integrated micro-macro model for European households. Econ Model 61:510–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallissey N, Kelly R, O'Malley T (2014) Macro-prudential tools and credit risk of property lending at Irish banks. No. 10/EL/14. Central Bank of Ireland

  • Hanley JA, McNeil B (1982) The meaning and use of the area under a receiver operating characteristic (ROC) curve. Radiology 143(1):29–36

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Hodula M, Melecký M, Pfeifer L, Szabo M (2023) Cooling the mortgage loan market: the effect of borrower-based limits on new mortgage lending. J Int Money Financ 132:102808

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh F, Turnbull BW (1996) Nonparametric and semiparametric estimation of the receiver operating characteristic curve. Ann Stat 24(1):25–40

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Igan D, Kang H (2011) Do loan-to-value and debt-to-income limits work? Evidence from Korea. IMF Working Paper WP/11/297

  • Jordà Ò (2012) Discussion of ’Anchoring countercyclical capital buffers: the role of credit aggregates’. Int J Cent Bank 7(4):241–259

    Google Scholar 

  • Jordà Ò, Taylor A (2011) Performance evaluation of zero net-investment strategies. NBER Working Paper, No 17150

  • Jurča P, Klacso J, Tereanu E, Forletta M, Gross M (2020) The effectiveness of borrower-based macroprudential measures: a quantitative analysis for Slovakia. IMF Working Paper WP/20/134

  • Kaminsky G, Lizondo S, Reinhart C (1998) Leading indicators of currency crises. IMF Staff Pap 45(1):1–48

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim J, Choi K, Kim G, Suh Y (2012) Classification cost: an empirical comparison among traditional classifier, cost-sensitive classifier, and MetaCost. Expert Syst Appl 39(4):4013–4019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuttner KN, Shim I (2016) Can non-interest rate policies stabilize housing markets? Evidence from a panel of 57 economies. J Financ Stab 26:31–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leika M, Marchettini D (2017) A generalized framework for the assessment of household financial vulnerability. IMF Working Paper WP/17/228

  • Lim CH, Costa A, Columba F, Kongsamut P, Otani A, Saiyid M, Wezel T, Wu X (2011) Macroprudential policy: What instruments and how to use them? Lessons from country experiences. IMF Working Paper WP/11/238

  • Makdissi P, Wodon Q (2002) Consumption dominance curves: testing for the impact of indirect tax reforms on poverty. Econ Lett 75(2):227–235

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Malovaná S, Hodula M, Gric Z, Bajzik J (2022) Borrower-based macroprudential measures and credit growth: How biased is the existing literature? Preprint version available at Research Square. https://doi.org/10.21203/rs.3.rs-1811177/v1

  • Meriküll J, Rõõm T (2020) Stress tests of the household sector using microdata from survey and administrative sources. Int J Cent Bank 16(2):203–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Nier E, Popa R, Shamloo M, Voinea L (2019) Debt service and default: calibrating macroprudential policy using micro data. IMF Working Paper WP/19/182

  • Richter B, Schularick M, Shim I (2019) The costs of macroprudential policy. J Int Econ 118:263–282

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sangaré I (2019) Housing sector and optimal macro-prudential policy in an estimated DSGE model for Luxembourg. BCL Working Paper 129

Download references

Acknowledgements

This paper should not be reported as representing the views of the BCL or the Eurosystem. The views expressed are those of the authors and may not be shared by other research staff or policymakers in the BCL, the Eurosystem or the Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network. We give special thanks to Paolo Guarda. In addition, we would like to thank Giuseppe Pulina, Emmanuel Thibault, Martial Dupaigne, our colleagues from the Financial Stability Department and internal seminar participants for useful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael Ziegelmeyer.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Tables and figures for debt burden ratios

Table 10 Median debt burden ratios in 2018 for households with a recent HMR mortgage, by household characteristic.
Table 11 Debt burden ratios at loan origination: households with recent HMR or OREP mortgages.

Appendix B: Signals approach—robustness analysis

This appendix provides a robustness analysis of the signals approach exercise, using an alternative criterion to identify financially vulnerable households. The benchmark exercise in the main text focused on the impact of household financial vulnerability on banks, identifying vulnerable households as those with a loss given default (LGD) greater than zero. Instead, the robustness exercise focuses on those households that could potentially face problems servicing their debt, identifying vulnerable households as those with a probability of default (PD) greater than zero. PD > 0 is a less restrictive criterion, since only some households with PD > 0 have LGD > 0, while all households with LGD > 0 have PD > 0 (see Sect. 3).

As in the benchmark exercise (LGD > 0), using individual ratios is less effective than a classification rule combining several ratios. However, looking at the individual ratios, the LTV ratio outperforms all the other ratios in terms of AUROC (Table 12). The optimal limits for the LTV ratio are 185%, 95% and 75% depending on the loss function (\(\theta\) equal to 0.25, 0.5 and 0.75, respectively). Policies that combine ratios are less effective than in the benchmark exercise (Table 13) except for rule 1. Moreover, optimal limits are outside the legal range, in particular for the MDI ratio (Table 14).

Table 12 Performance of individual debt burden ratios in adverse scenario (PD > 0).
Table 13 Performance of combined debt burden ratios in adverse scenario: DI, DSI, LTV and MM.
Table 14 Performance of combined ratios in the adverse scenario: MDI, DSI, LTV and MM.

Figure 7 depicts the Receiver Operating Characteristic (ROC) curves for each debt burden ratio in the adverse scenario. The ROC curve plots type I and type II classification errors for all the limits evaluated in the grid search. The y-axis reports the True Positive Rate (1 – type II error) and the x-axis reports the False Positive Rate (type I error). The origin represents the highest value considered for the limit (misses all vulnerable households but avoids misclassifying non-vulnerable households). Moving away from the origin along the dashed 45° line, the value of the limit declines, reducing type II errors but raising type I errors. Therefore, the line represents a poor performance (linear combinations of the maximum type II error at the origin with the maximum type I error at the top right corner).

Fig. 7
figure 7

Source: Own calculations based on the 3rd wave of the LU-HFCS; data are multiply imputed and weighted; the classification errors are calculated by pooling all the implicates

Receiver operating characteristic (ROC) curves of individual debt burden ratios in the adverse scenario.

In panel (a) of Fig. 7, the condition variable is unity for households with PD > 0. On this definition of financial vulnerability, the DI ratio (yellow), MDI ratio (green), DSI ratio (grey) and LTV ratio (red) deviate from the 45° line and therefore, are effective at identifying financially vulnerable households. For all ratio, the ROC rises below the 45° line near the origin. Thus, as the limit is lowered from very high levels, type I error increases more rapidly than type II error diminishes. This suggests that high limits on debt burden ratios are ineffective at identifying financially vulnerable households. However, the ROC soon jumps above the 45° line, suggesting that at lower levels of the limit, type II error does decline at least as rapidly as type I error increases. This suggests that, in the adverse scenario most financially vulnerable households are characterized by debt burden ratios at the centre of the evaluated range.

In panel (b) of Fig. 7, the condition variable is unity for households with LGD > 0. The LTV ratio performs slightly worse than with PD > 0 in panel (a), while the other three ratios perform better.

Appendix C: Unemployment shock

The unemployment shock is likely to focus on households or individuals with certain characteristics. To allow for the non-uniform distribution of the shock, we estimate a logit model for the probability that an individual is unemployed using survey data for all household members who were part of the active work force in the 2018 wave (Table 15).Footnote 35

The vector of explanatory variables includes the following individual and household characteristics: gender, age, country of birth, marital status, highest educational attainment, household size, homeowner/tenant status, net wealth quintile. Explanatory variables also include the following characteristics that were only available in the 2018 wave: region dummies, current labour status or (if unemployed) previous labour status, language skills and current sector of employment (based on NACE codes) or previous sector of employment (if unemployed). Standard errors are clustered at the household level.

The unemployment rate observed across all individuals in the active work force covered by the 2018 HFCS wave was 4.7%.Footnote 36 After estimating the logit model, we adjust the intercept term to simulate the average unemployment rate increasing to 12%. Following Albacete and Fessler (2010) or Meriküll and Rõõm (2020), for each individual we draw a random number from the uniform distribution over the interval (0,1) and compare it to the logit-determined probability for the given individual to determine whether he or she becomes unemployed. We then adjust household net income as described in Sect. 3 and recalculate the financial margin, probability of default and loss given default at the household level. Sections 4.2 and 5 report estimated statistics for the adverse economic scenario that are averages across 1000 Monte Carlo iterations of this process. Each iteration requires simulating the employment status of every active individual.

Table 15 Logit coefficients of being unemployed.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Giordana, G., Ziegelmeyer, M. Using household-level data to guide borrower-based macro-prudential policy. Empir Econ 66, 785–827 (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-023-02477-9

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-023-02477-9

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation