Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Does access to credit alter migration intentions?

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study investigates whether access to credit affects migration intentions. Using Gallup survey data for the years 2009 and 2010 for 17 African countries, we document a negative link between the ability to borrow and the desire to migrate. Being able to borrow reduces the likelihood of reporting wanting to migrate, especially for those with some education, those with lower income, for individuals with a bank account, and for those who feel their assets are safe. To deal with endogeneity, we assume that migration desire is driven by borrowing which in turn is determined by access to financial services. Therefore, we estimate a two-equation system for migration and borrowing, using variables describing access to financial services as instruments. We verify our findings using identification through heteroscedasticity and using a geographical instrument. Our results indicate that efforts to increase credit access in developing economies can cement residents’ attachment to their home country.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Mesnard (2004) also shows that credit imperfections at home affect migration length and occupational choice of return migrants.

  2. Rubalcava and Teruel (2005) study the effect using similar data over a shorter time horizon but finds that migration decreases.

  3. And given that we look at migration intentions in large samples across individuals, regions, and countries, as available from the GWP, we can mitigate a potential concern that the patterns in our results stem from a systematic measurement error.

  4. We also contribute to the literature documenting the relationship between migration and income (Dao et al. 2018; Clemens 2014; Abramitzky et al. 2013).

  5. It is worth noting that at least 4 out of 10 respondents in Rwanda, Central African Republic, Cameroon,and Kenya say they depend at least a little on community savings groups to make a living, the highest participation in Sub-Saharan Africa.

  6. 43% of Sub-Saharan Africans reported that they have heard of microfinance institutions but they are not available in their community (Marlar 2010a).

  7. From 5% of adult population in 2006 to 36% in 2015.

  8. A single international dollar buys an amount of goods and services in a country similar to the amount bought by a US dollar in the USA.

  9. Full descriptive statistics of all variables can be found in Appendix D, Table 11.

  10. However, this correlation is statistically insignificant. The slope coefficient of the linear trend is .094 with a standard error of .107 and a p value of 0.395.

  11. For example, a risk-taking individual may be more likely to use their own money or assets in order to invest, rather than borrow, and is more likely to engage in the risky endeavor of migration, compared to a respondent with identically measured characteristics.

  12. With the null hypothesis of exogeneity, the Durbin \(\chi ^2\) test statistic is 4.48773, with a p value of 0.0341 and the Wu–Hausman F statistic is 4.47981 with a p value of 0.0343.

  13. The marginal effects are presented in Table 8 and are discussed in Sect. 4.

  14. The discussion in this section is based on Baum and Lewbel (2019).

  15. The first-stage coefficient of the geographical IV model is negative. One explanation could be that limited funds are available for borrowing. Therefore, if many are borrowing elsewhere, few loans are left for the respondent’s region. Alternatively, if certain central regions have bank branches (which can facilitate borrowing in said regions), then neighboring (less central) regions are less likely to have bank branches and residents are less likely to borrow.

  16. See column 1 of Tables 4, 6, and 8.

  17. Brain drain is loosely defined as the international migration of skilled workers. Although some gains exist to the home economies from skilled emigration such as remittances, improved international networks, and expertise brought home through return migration, the extent of these gains is hard to quantify and the empirical evidence of such gains is mixed. While Beine et al. (2001) and Beine et al. (2008) document evidence of brain gain effects, Faini et al. (2003) fails to spot such an effect.

  18. See also Amery and Anderson (1995).

  19. We also find that a model where bank account ownership and cost of banking variables are included in both the migration and borrowing equation delivers a higher AIC and BIC than our model with an exclusion restriction (AIC = 26755.45, BIC = 27170.74).

References

  • Abramitzky R, Boustan LP, Eriksson K (2013) Have the poor always been less likely to migrate? evidence from inheritance practices during the age of mass migration. J Dev Econ 102:2–14

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Naidu S, Restrepo P, Robinson JA (2019) Democracy does cause growth. J Polit Econ 127(1):47–100

    Google Scholar 

  • Ajzen I (1991) The theory of planned behavior. Organ Behav Hum Decis Process 50(2):179–211

    Google Scholar 

  • Ajzen I, Fishbein M (2005) The influence of attitudes on behavior. Handb Attitudes 173(221):31

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen F, Carletti E, Cull R, Qian J, Senbet L, Valenzuela P (2021) Improving access to banking: evidence from kenya. Rev Finance 25(2):403–447

    Google Scholar 

  • Amery HA, Anderson WP (1995) International migration and remittances to a Lebanese village. Canadian Geographer/Le Géographe Canadien 39(1):46–58

    Google Scholar 

  • Angelucci M (2015) Migration and financial constraints: evidence from Mexico. Rev Econ Stat 97(1):224–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Angrist JD (1991) Instrumental variables estimation of average treatment effects in econometrics and epidemiology. NBER technical working papers 0115, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc

  • Ansell BW (2008) Traders, teachers, and tyrants: democracy, globalization, and public investment in education. Int Organ 62(2):289–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Aryeetey E (2005) Informal finance for private sector development in sub-Saharan Africa. J Microfinance 7(1):3

    Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Jayachandran S, Malesky EJ, Olken BA (2019) Firm growth and corruption: empirical evidence from Vietnam. Econ J 129(618):651–677

    Google Scholar 

  • Barajas A, Sahay R, Kyobe A, N’Diaye P, Mitra S, Cihak M, Yousefi S, Mooi Y (2015) Financial inclusion: Can it meet multiple macroeconomic goals? Technical report, International Monetary Fund

  • Baum CF, Lewbel A (2019) Advice on using heteroskedasticity-based identification. Stand Genomic Sci 19(4):757–767

    Google Scholar 

  • Bazzi S (2017) Wealth heterogeneity and the income elasticity of migration. Am Econ J Appl Econ 9(2):219–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Demirguc-Kunt A, Martinez Peria MS (2008) Banking services for everyone? barriers to bank access and use around the world. World Bank Econ Rev 22(3):397–430

    Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Docquier F, Rapoport H (2001) Brain drain and economic growth: theory and evidence. J Dev Econ 64(1):275–289

    Google Scholar 

  • Beine M, Docquier F, Rapoport H (2008) Brain drain and human capital formation in developing countries: winners and losers. Econ J 118(528):631–652

    Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati J, Hamada K (1974) The brain drain, international integration of markets for professionals and unemployment: a theoretical analysis. J Dev Econ 1(1):19–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Buera FJ, Kaboski JP, Shin Y (2021) The macroeconomics of microfinance. Rev Econ Stud 88(1):126–161

    Google Scholar 

  • Cai S (2020) Migration under liquidity constraints: evidence from randomized credit access in China. J Dev Econ 142:102247

  • Clemens MA (2014) Does development reduce migration? Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Creighton MJ (2013) The role of aspirations in domestic and international migration. Soc Sci J 50(1):79–88

    Google Scholar 

  • Czaika M, Parsons C (2017). The gravity of high-skilled migration policies. Demography 54

  • Dabla-Norris E, Deng Y, Ivanova A, Karpowicz I, Unsal F, VanLeemput E, Wong J (2015) Financial Inclusion; zooming in on Latin America. IMF Working Papers 15/206, International Monetary Fund

  • Dang DA, La HA (2019) Does electricity reliability matter? Evidence from rural Vietnam. Energy Policy 131:399–409

    Google Scholar 

  • Dao TH, Docquier F, Parsons C, Peri G (2018) Migration and development: dissecting the anatomy of the mobility transition. J Dev Econ 132:88–101

    Google Scholar 

  • Docquier F, Machado J, Sekkat K (2015) Efficiency gains from liberalizing labor mobility. Scand J Econ 117(2):303–346

    Google Scholar 

  • Dustmann C, Okatenko A (2014) Out-migration, wealth constraints, and the quality of local amenities. J Dev Econ 110:52–63

    Google Scholar 

  • English C (2008) Many Africans count on community savings groups. Technical report, GALLUP

  • Faini R, et al (2003) Is the brain drain an unmitigated blessing. In: UNU-WIDER discussion paper no 2003/64. Citeseer

  • Fishbein M, Ajzen I, et al (1975) Intention and behavior: an introduction to theory and research

  • Gazeaud J, Mvukiyehe E, Sterck O (2023) Cash transfers and migration: theory and evidence from a randomized controlled trial. Rev Econ Stat 105(1):143–157

  • Hajilee M, Stringer DY, Metghalchi M (2017) Financial market inclusion, shadow economy and economic growth: new evidence from emerging economies. Q Rev Econ Finance 66:149–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Hale JL, Householder BJ, Greene KL (2002) The theory of reasoned action. The persuasion handbook: developments in theory and practice 14:259–286

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoop T, Howlett M, Meysonnat A, Desai S, Anderson CL, Schmidt C, Kaminsky M, Sidhu A (2020). Measuring savings group participation rates in Africa: data assessment and recommendations. Technical report, Evidence Consortium on Women’s Groups

  • Kaestner R, Malamud O (2014) Self-selection and international migration: new evidence from Mexico. Rev Econ Stat 96(1):78–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (2012) Using heteroscedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured and endogenous regressor models. J Bus Econ Stat 30(1):67–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (2018) Identification and estimation using heteroscedasticity without instruments: the binary endogenous regressor case. Econ Lett 165:10–12

    Google Scholar 

  • Liebig T, Sousa-Poza A (2004) Migration, self-selection and income inequality: an international analysis. Kyklos 57(1):125–146

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahendra E (2014) Financial constraints, social policy and migration. Technical report, IMI Working Paper, 101

  • Marchal L, Naiditch C (2020) How borrowing constraints hinder migration: theoretical insights from a random utility maximization model. Scand J Econ 122(2):732–761

    Google Scholar 

  • Marlar J (2010a) Few Sub-Saharan Africans aware of local microfinance options. Technical report, GALLUP

  • Marlar J (2010b) Sub-Saharan Africans bank on family for business loans. Technical report, GALLUP

  • Mayr K, Peri G (2008). Return migration as a channel of brain gain. Working paper 14039, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Mesnard A (2004) Temporary migration and capital market imperfections. Oxf Econ Pap 56(2):242–262

    Google Scholar 

  • Miyagiwa K (1991) Scale economies in education and the brain drain problem. Int Econ Rev 32(3):743–59

    Google Scholar 

  • Piracha M, Saraogi A (2017) Remittances and migration intentions of the left-behind. Migr Dev 6(1):102–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Poggi C (2019) Credit availability and internal migration: evidence from Thailand. J Dev Stud 55(5):861–875

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport H (2002) Migration, credit constraints and self-employment: a simple model of occupational choice, inequality and growth. Econ Bull 15(7):1–5

    Google Scholar 

  • Rubalcava L, Teruel G (2005). Conditional public transfers and living arrangements in rural Mexico. California Center for Population Research

  • Singh R et al (2018) Credit constraints and rural migration: evidence from six villages in Uttar Pradesh. Migr Lett 15(3):389–399

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark O, Lucas RE (1988) Migration, remittances, and the family. Econ Dev Cult Change 36(3):465–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock J, Yogo M (2005) Testing for weak instruments in linear IV regression. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp 80–108

  • Stock JH, Wright JH, Yogo M (2002) A survey of weak instruments and weak identification in generalized method of moments. J Bus Econ Stat 20(4):518–529

    Google Scholar 

  • Sy MAN, Maino MR, Massara MA, Saiz HP, Sharma P (2019). FinTech in Sub-Saharan African countries: a game changer? International monetary fund

  • Van Dalen HP, Henkens K (2008). Emigration intentions: mere words or true plans? Explaining international migration intentions and behavior. In: Explaining international migration intentions and behavior (June 30, 2008)

  • Van Dalen HP, Henkens K (2013) Explaining emigration intentions and Behaviour in the Netherlands, 2005–10. Popul Stud 67(2):225–241

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dalen HP, Groenewold G, Fokkema T (2005a) The effect of remittances on emigration intentions in Egypt, Morocco, and Turkey. Popul Stud 59(3):375–392

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Dalen HP, Groenewold G, Schoorl JJ (2005b) Out of Africa: What drives the pressure to emigrate? J Popul Econ 18(4):741–778

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Rooyen C, Stewart R, De Wet T (2012) The impact of microfinance in Sub-Saharan Africa: a systematic review of the evidence. World Dev 40(11):2249–2262

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. The MIT Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge JM (2015) Introductory econometrics: a modern approach. Cengage learning

  • yiu Wong K, Yip CK (1999) Education, economic growth, and brain drain. J Econ Dyn Control 23(5):699–726

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maroula Khraiche.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The authors declare that they have no known competing financial interests or personal relationships that could have appeared to influence the work reported in this paper.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We thank Thanasis Stengos for helpful comments on the paper. All errors are our own.

Appendices

A: Wealth Index construction

Using joint correspondence analysis (JCA) on the following Yes or No questions, we construct a wealth index such that higher values imply higher wealth.

  • Have there been times in the past 12 months when you did not have enough money to provide adequate shelter or housing for you and your family?

  • Have there been times in the past 12 months when you did not have enough money to buy food that you or your family needed?

  • Does your home have a cellular phone?

  • Does your home have a television?

The proportion of variance explained by the first component is 68.37. It is worth noting that in Dustmann and Okatenko (2014) the authors use additional variables capturing internet access and electricity. However, our data do not include such information. Additionally, while Dustmann and Okatenko (2014) use polychoric principal component analysis to construct their index, we use JCA.

Table 9 Weak instruments tests (Appendix B)

B: Two tests for weak instruments

We run two more tests to check whether the IVs are weak and report them in Table 9. We report the test results for specifications in columns 1, 2, and 3 of Table 4. As suggested by Stock et al. (2002), the first test checks for relative bias in our 2SLS estimator compared to the standard OLS. We find that our 2SLS estimator suffers at most 5% of the bias delivered by the OLS estimator. This is evident by the fact that our test statistic reported in Table 9 is larger than the critical value for 5% relative bias. Therefore, our 2SLS estimator is superior to OLS and we can thus conclude that our instruments are not weak. The second test checks for the presence of large size distortions in our 2SLS estimates that can arise if our instruments are weak. As can be seen in Table 9, our test statistic is larger than the critical value, indicating that a Wald test at the 5% level can have an actual rejection rate of no more than 10%. Therefore, we supply additional evidence rejecting the null hypothesis of weak instruments.

Table 10 Bivariate probit estimation (Appendix C)

C: Biprobit model

We rewrite the two equations given by 1 and 2 as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {\textrm{prob}}[m_{ij}=1]&=\Phi [x_{ij}' \beta + b_{ij} \alpha + c_j' \delta _1] \end{aligned}$$
(3)
$$\begin{aligned} {\textrm{prob}}[b_{ij}=1]&=\Phi [z_{ij}' \gamma + c_j' \delta _2], \end{aligned}$$
(4)

where \(\Phi \) is the evaluation of the standard normal cumulative distribution function (cdf). Then, we estimate Eqs. 3 and 4 jointly by Maximum Likelihood (ML) as a biprobit. To do so, we assume that the random errors \(u_{ij}\) and \(v_{ij}\) follow a bivariate normal distribution and allow that \({\textrm{cov}}(v_{ij},u_{ij})=\rho \). Given our discussion above on omitted variables bias and reverse causality, we suspect that \(b_{ij}\) is correlated with the error term \(u_{ij}\) and therefore is not exogenous, we expect the parameter determining the correlation between the aforementioned random errors (\(\rho \)) to not be zero. If \(b_{ij}\) were exogenous, then the correlation would be zero. Although we can use a two-step procedure to estimate a linear probability model using 2SLS, we cannot replicate this procedure here since the endogenous variable in our model is binary (Wooldridge 2010). In any case, Angrist (1991) shows that 2SLS and biprobit can deliver similar results.

The bivariate probit model is econometrically identified without an exclusion restriction. This provides another avenue to evaluate the identification arising from the exclusion restriction by comparing the estimated model that includes the exclusion restriction, to the estimated model that is identified purely from functional form. Therefore, we calculate the Akaike’s information criterion (AIC) and Bayesian information criterion (BIC) for two different models. The first model is the one with the exclusion restriction where we use bank account ownership and cost of banking variables as instruments. The second model is one with the migration and borrowing equations determined by the same exogenous variables and no exclusion restrictions are imposed (variables are listed in Table 10, column 1). We find that the model with the exclusion restrictions delivers a smaller AIC and BIC (AIC = 26753.39, BIC = 27153.29), compared to the model without an exclusion restriction (AIC = 27275.9, BIC = 27660.43). Therefore, the model with the exclusion restriction fits the data best according to these criteria.Footnote 19

D: Descriptive statistics

In Table 11, we report the average, standard deviation, minimum, and maximum of all variables used in the analysis.

Table 11 Descriptive statistics (Appendix D)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Katsaiti, MS., Khraiche, M. Does access to credit alter migration intentions?. Empir Econ 65, 1823–1854 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-023-02393-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-023-02393-y

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation