Skip to main content
Log in

Financial development and declining market dynamics: Another dark side of “too much finance”?

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper empirically investigates whether financial development has played a role in the rise of market concentration over the past decades. Using an industry-level panel of 41 countries over the period 1989–2010, we document a strong threshold effect of financial development on market competition. Specifically, the deregulation of capital and financial markets promotes product market competition in countries with initially low level of financial development. However, such positive effects vanish with the deepening of credit and stock markets. We identify two mechanisms through which financial development affects market competition in a nonlinear form: external finance dependence and technology gap within an industry. Our results further suggest that financial development may play a role in explaining the modern productivity growth slowdown puzzle.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Competition in banking industry reduces bank’s incentive to screen, creating inefficiencies as more incumbents with less innovation are more likely to obtain financing and remain in the market (Marquez 2002)

  2. Note that OECD countries have a relatively higher level of credits.

  3. For a definition of modern productivity growth slowdown, see Brynjolfsson et al. (2020)

  4. For discussions of four mainstream explanations, see Brynjolfsson et al. (2020)

  5. Source: https://comparativecompetitionlaw.org/data/ For more details, see Bradford et al. (2019).

  6. For example, the start-up costs, number of Procedures necessary to incorporate a business, and days required to start a business. These variables are available on World dEVELOPMENT Indicator database (WDI), but there are many missing values.

  7. Similar evidence can be found in the equity markets. The median capitalization was 48.98% in the period 1989–1999 and 71.17% in the period 2000–2010.

  8. The estimated equation is \(y_t = \underset{(0.071)}{0.464}+ \underset{(0.093)}{0.412}y_{t-1} +\underset{(0.057)}{0.153}y_{t-2} + \underset{(0.071)}{0.088}y_{t-3} -\underset{(0.070)}{0.094}y_{t-4} + \underset{(0.054)}{0.058}y_{t-5}\), where \(y_t\) is the competition index. Robust standard errors are in parenthesis.

  9. Specifically, we estimate the following model: \(y_{ci,t} = \sigma _0 + \alpha _L \textrm{FD}_{c,t} * I(\textrm{FD}_{c,t} \le \gamma _1 ) +\alpha _M \textrm{FD}_{c,t} * I(\gamma _1<\textrm{FD}_{c,t} \le \gamma _2 )+ \alpha _H \textrm{FD}_{c,t} * I(\textrm{FD}_{c,t} > \gamma _2 ) + {\textbf {X}}_{ci,t} \delta + \eta _{ci} +v_t + \varepsilon _{c,i,t}\), where \(\alpha _M\) is the coefficient on the middle regime. \({\textbf {X}}_{ci,t}\) includes the controls and lagged dependent variable.

  10. To capture the picture of productivity growth slowdown, Fig. 3 and Table 11 show the annual total factor productivity growth rate for G7 from 1985 to 2017. The US TFP growth rate witnessed an increase from 0.732% to 1.623% between the 1980s to 2004, and then declined after 2004, even before the financial crisis. A similar pattern is observed in other G7 countries, with a mere exception of Italy, whose TFP growth rate has been declining since the mid-1980s. We can also capture a sharp decline in TFP growth rate in the G7 countries during 2007–2008, followed by an immediate recovery to a level below 1%. This has been a puzzle because we are in the midst of a technological revolution, driven by technological advances such as the emergence of artificial intelligence and industrial robots, which are perceived to contribute significantly to productivity growth.

  11. Since the productivity growth rate had declined prior to the financial crisis, explanations related to the financial crisis do not explain the pre-crisis decline very well. Several theories have been proposed to explain the slowdown in productivity growth in the USA and other developed countries. For example, “The mismeasurement hypothesis” (Griliches 1994; Byrne et al. 2018),Footnote 12 weak business dynamism (Decker et al. 2016; De Loecker and Eeckhout 2017; Bijnens and Konings 2018), and low interest rate (Gopinath et al. 2017; Liu et al. 2019). The latter two explanations point to the same end that it is the rise in industry concentration and higher markups that lead to lower productivity growth, as lower financial constraints and real interest rates make it more difficult for high-productivity firms to crowd out the least efficient ones. Financial development is closely related to credit constraints, capital abundance, and interest rate, and thus, financial development is likely to be a potential explanation for the productivity growth decline in developed economies since the 1980s.

  12. Brynjolfsson et al. (2018) acknowledges that it is difficult to completely rule out the possibility of mismeasurement issue, but it is not a major force that drags the productivity growth down over the past decade. Similar arguments can also be found in Sichel (1997) and Sichel (2019).

  13. All the values are converted to US dollar base.

References

  • Aghion L, Howitt P, Levine R (2018) Financial development and innovation-led growth. In: Handbook of finance and development. Edward Elgar Publishing

  • Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P (2005) Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Q J Econ 120(2):701–728

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Howitt P, Mayer-Foulkes D (2005) The effect of financial development on convergence: theory and evidence. Q J Econ 120(1):173–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Akcigit U, Ates ST (2019) What happened to us business dynamism? Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Arcand JL, Berkes E, Panizza U (2015) Too much finance? J Econ Growth 20(2):105–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano C, Bai Y, Zhang J (2012) Firm dynamics and financial development. J Monet Econ 59(6):533–549

    Google Scholar 

  • Autor D, Dorn D, Katz LF, Patterson C, Van Reenen J (2020) The fall of the labor share and the rise of superstar firms. Q J Econ 135(2):645–709

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck T, Demirgüç-Kunt A, Maksimovic V (2008) Financing patterns around the world: Are small firms different? J Financ Econ 89(3):467–487

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernini M, Montagnoli A (2017) Competition and financial constraints: a two-sided story. J Int Money Finance 70:88–109

    Google Scholar 

  • Bijnens G, Konings J (2018) Declining business dynamism. Technical report, CEPR Discussion Papers

  • Black BS, Gilson RJ (1998) Venture capital and the structure of capital markets: banks versus stock markets. J Financ Econ 47(3):243–277

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Griffith R, Van Reenen J (1999) Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. Rev Econ Stud 66(3):529–554

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradford A, Chilton AS, Megaw C, Sokol N (2019) Competition law gone global: introducing the comparative competition law and enforcement datasets. J Empir Leg Stud 16(2):411–443

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown JR, Martinsson G, Petersen BC (2013) Law, stock markets, and innovation. J Finance 68(4):1517–1549

    Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson E, Rock D, Syverson C (2018) Artificial intelligence and the modern productivity paradox: a clash of expectations and statistics. In: The economics of artificial intelligence: an agenda. University of Chicago Press

  • Brynjolfsson E, Benzell S, Rock D (2020) Understanding and addressing the modern productivity paradox

  • Byrne DM, Oliner SD, Sichel DE (2018) How fast are semiconductor prices falling? Rev Income Wealth 64(3):679–702

    Google Scholar 

  • Caner M, Hansen BE (2004) Instrumental variable estimation of a threshold model. Econom Theor 20(5):813–843

    Google Scholar 

  • Chava S, Oettl A, Subramanian A, Subramanian KV (2013) Banking deregulation and innovation. J Financ Econ 109(3):759–774

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherif R, Dhungana S, Fang X, Gonzalez-Garcia MJR, Yang Y, Yenice M, Yoon JE (2020) Competition, competitiveness and growth in Sub-Saharan Africa. International Monetary Fund

  • Comin D, Nanda R (2019) Financial development and technology diffusion. IMF Econ Rev 67(2):395–419

    Google Scholar 

  • De Loecker J, Eeckhout J (2017) The rise of market power and the macroeconomic implications. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • De Loecker J, Eeckhout J, Mongey S (2021) Quantifying market power and business dynamism in the macroeconomy. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Decker RA, Haltiwanger J, Jarmin RS, Miranda J (2016) Where has all the skewness gone? The decline in high-growth (young) firms in the us. Eur Econ Rev 86:4–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Diez F, Duval R, Chen W, Jones C, Villegas-Sanchez C (2019) The rise of corporate market power and its macroeconomic effects. IMF World Economic Outlook

  • Djankov S, La Porta R, Lopez-de Silanes F, Shleifer A (2002) The regulation of entry. Q J Econ 117(1):1–37

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, McLiesh C, Shleifer A (2007) Private credit in 129 countries. J Financ Econ 84(2):299–329

    Google Scholar 

  • Djankov S, La Porta R, Lopez-de Silanes F, Shleifer A (2008) The law and economics of self-dealing. J Financ Econ 88(3):430–465

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson GB, Robbins JA, Wold EG (2021) Kaldor and Piketty’s facts: the rise of monopoly power in the United States. J Monet Econ 124:S19–S38

    Google Scholar 

  • Gopinath G, Kalemli-Özcan Ş, Karabarbounis L, Villegas-Sanchez C (2017) Capital allocation and productivity in south Europe. Q J Econ 132(4):1915–1967

    Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1994) Productivity, r &d, and the data constraint. Am Econ Rev 84(1):1–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Guadalupe M (2007) Product market competition, returns to skill, and wage inequality. J Law Econ 25(3):439–474

    Google Scholar 

  • Haltiwanger J (2011) Firm dynamics and productivity growth. Eur Invest Bank Pap 16(1):116–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen BE (1999) Threshold effects in non-dynamic panels: estimation, testing, and inference. J Econom 93(2):345–368

    Google Scholar 

  • Holmes TJ, Levine DK, Schmitz JA (2012) Monopoly and the incentive to innovate when adoption involves switchover disruptions. Am Econ J Microecon 4(3):1–33

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsu P-H, Tian X, Xu Y (2014) Financial development and innovation: cross-country evidence. J Financ Econ 112(1):116–135

    Google Scholar 

  • Klapper L, Laeven L, Rajan R (2006) Entry regulation as a barrier to entrepreneurship. J Financ Econ 82(3):591–629

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremer S, Bick A, Nautz D (2013) Inflation and growth: new evidence from a dynamic panel threshold analysis. Empir Econ 44(2):861–878

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuttner KN, Shim I (2016) Can non-interest rate policies stabilize housing markets? Evidence from a panel of 57 economies. J Financ Stab 26:31–44

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta R, Lopez-de Silanes F, Shleifer A, Vishny RW (1997) Legal determinants of external finance. J Finance 52(3):1131–1150

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (1998) The legal environment, banks, and long-run economic growth. J Money Credit Bank 30:596–613

    Google Scholar 

  • Levine R, Loayza N, Beck T (2000) Financial intermediation and growth: causality and causes. J Monet Econ 46(1):31–77

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (2012) Using heteroscedasticity to identify and estimate mismeasured and endogenous regressor models. J Bus Econ Stat 30(1):67–80

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu E, Mian A, Sufi A (2019) Low interest rates, market power, and productivity growth. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Marquez R (2002) Competition, adverse selection, and information dispersion in the banking industry. Rev Financ Stud 15(3):901–926

    Google Scholar 

  • Michelacci C, Suarez J (2004) Business creation and the stock market. Rev Econ Stud 71(2):459–481

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell SJ (1996) Competition and corporate performance. J Political Econ 104(4):724–746

    Google Scholar 

  • Peress J (2010) Product market competition, insider trading, and stock market efficiency. J Finance 65(1):1–43

    Google Scholar 

  • Rajan RG, Zingales L (1998) Financial dependence and growth. Am Econ Rev 88(3):559–586

    Google Scholar 

  • Robb AM, Robinson DT (2014) The capital structure decisions of new firms. Rev Financ Stud 27(1):153–179

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitz JA Jr (2005) What determines productivity? Lessons from the dramatic recovery of the us and Canadian iron ore industries following their early 1980s crisis. J Political Econ 113(3):582–625

    Google Scholar 

  • Seo MH, Shin Y (2016) Dynamic panels with threshold effect and endogeneity. J Econom 195(2):169–186

    Google Scholar 

  • Sichel DE (1997) The productivity slowdown: Is a growing unmeasurable sector the culprit? Rev Econ Stat 79(3):367–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Sichel D E (2019). Productivity measurement: racing to keep up. Working Paper 25558, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Syverson C (2004) Product substitutability and productivity dispersion. Rev Econ Stat 86(2):534–550

    Google Scholar 

  • Syverson C (2011) What determines productivity? J Econ Lit 49(2):326–65

    Google Scholar 

  • Ye J, Zhang A, Dong Y (2019) Banking reform and industry structure: evidence from China. J Bank Finance 104:70–84

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiaoyang Zhu.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The author declares that he has no conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by the author.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix: Construction of external financial dependence index

Appendix: Construction of external financial dependence index

Existing literature typically follows the approach of Rajan and Zingales (1998) to construct the index of external financial dependence, i.e., using firms listed on major US stock exchanges retrieved from Compustat North America to calculate the industry-level value in the manufacturing sector. An important assumption is that the dependence of US firms on external finance serves as a good proxy for the demand for external finance in other countries. According to Rajan and Zingales (1998), there are two important reasons underlying this assumption. First, industries’ demand for external finance is assumed to be homogeneous across countries when they respond to technological shocks. Second, due to data limitation, the authors do not have access to data on flow of funds in other countries. Several studies show that the technology gap between poor and rich countries has been widening and it is mainly driven by differences in the development of financial markets in different countries (Aghion et al. 2005b; Comin and Nanda 2019). This means that countries respond differently to technology shocks due to the heterogeneity of the financial environment. Second, the Worldscope database provides Funds from operations (Worldscope item 4201), which helps remove the barriers to building the external financial dependence for each country individually. The cross-country EFD is constructed to account for the heterogeneity of financial dependence across countries. Following Rajan and Zingales (1998) and Hsu et al. (2014), the cash flow from operations is defined as funds from operations (item 4201) plus decreases in inventories (item 4826), decreases in receivables (item 4825), and increases in account payable (item 4827). Capital expenditure and R &D expense are item 4601 and item 1201, respectively. Each firm’s dependence on external finance is calculated as capital expenditures plus R &D expenditures minus cash flows from operations, all divided by the sum of capital expenditures and R &D expense. Within a country, the time series of each industry’s dependence on external finance is calculated as the median of all firms’ dependence on external finance in a year.Footnote 13 We then compute the invariant external dependence of each industry in each country as the time series median of the industry’s dependence on external finance over the period 1989–2018. An industry with higher external finance dependence uses more external financing to fund its tangible and intangible investment.

Table 6 shows the correlation matrix between the US and other countries in terms of the External Finance Dependence index. We can see that several developed economies, such as Australia, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Italy, Japan, South Korea, Sweden, and the UK, show a positive correlation with the USA in terms of External Financing Dependence. Therefore, it is legitimate to use the US EFD as a proxy for the external financing demand of industries in these countries. However, we can also observe that some developed economies, such as Germany, Greece, the Netherlands, and Singapore, have no or weak correlation with the USA. Regarding the emerging markets, countries such as Brazil, the Philippines, and Malaysia show a positive correlation with the USA, and many have no or negative correlation with the USA. For instance, Mexico and Thailand are negatively associated with the EFD of the USA. The facts presented in Table 6 clearly show that industries’ dependence on external financing varies across countries; therefore, using the US index may be valid if the study is limited to certain industrialized economies, but it may generate biased estimates if a larger number of emerging markets are included (Tables 7891011). This justifies our construction of a cross-country EFD dataset.

Table 6 Correlation of external financing dependence index between USA and other countries
Table 7 Threshold effect of financial development on market competition: subsample tests
Table 8 Threshold effect of financial development on market competition: longer sample period
Table 9 Threshold effect of financial development on market competition: including the second-order lagged dependent variable
Table 10 Threshold effect of financial development on market competition: multi-regime results
Table 11 Multifactor productivity growth rate in G7 group: 5 years average
Fig. 3
figure 3

Multifactor productivity growth rate in G7 Group: 1985–2017. Note Annual growth rate trends are obtained using HP filter. The smooth parameter is set as 6.25. Data source: OECD (2019), Multifactor productivity (indicator)

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Zhu, X. Financial development and declining market dynamics: Another dark side of “too much finance”?. Empir Econ 65, 275–309 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-022-02327-0

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-022-02327-0

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation