Skip to main content
Log in

The global propagation of the US–China trade war

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines upstream propagations of the US–China tariff war in 2018–2019 through the lens of exports from 32 countries to China. Building an industry-country specific measure of input–output linkages with China, we obtain new empirical evidence that the US tariffs on Chinese imports had a significant adverse effect on third countries by dampening Chinese demand for foreign inputs. A one standard deviation rise in this upstream shock leads to a decline in the growth rate of exports to China by 2.6 percentage points. A quantification exercise shows that the upstream propagation of US tariffs has incurred an average GDP loss of 0.05 percent for these countries. Taiwan and Korea, key suppliers to China, were most severely hurt by this vertical effect. Firm-level analysis using a panel of Korean manufacturers lends further support to the importance of this vertical linkage channel.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To name a few, see Amiti et al. (2019), Amiti et al. (2020) and Fajgelbaum et al. (2019) for US consumers and welfare and Amiti et al. (2020) and Handley et al. (2020) for investment and exports of US firms.

  2. These countries were selected based on the availability of monthly product-level export data in the UN Comtrade database and the cross-country input-output matrices in the World Input-Output Database (WIOD). We add a few more countries from alternative sources as well. See Sect. 3 for a detail.

  3. In 2016, the US was the single largest export market for China, accounting for 18.4% of its total exports.

  4. Using the episode of US import restrictions in the 1990s, these papers show two channels through which a trade policy distorts the targeted country’s trade with third countries—“trade diversion” and “trade depression”.

  5. For a review of recent empirical work on production networks, see Carvalho and Tahbaz-Salehi (2019).

  6. Early work using the IO tables to study production networks includes Bems et al. (2011) and Acemoglu et al. (2016). Bems et al. (2011) highlight the importance of vertical linkages in the trade collapse during the Great Recession of 2008-2009 based on a global IO framework. Using the detailed US IO tables, Acemoglu et al. (2016) empirically test the theoretical upstream and downstream network effects of demand and productivity shocks on the US economy.

  7. Even before April 2018, both countries raised their tariffs on one another for specific products, such as solar panels, washing machines and aluminium. However, the breadth and trade volumes associated with these tariffs were relatively small. For a detailed timeline of US–China trade disputes, see Fajgelbaum et al. (2019) and Amiti et al. (2019).

  8. More formally, I run a regression for 12-month log difference in US imports from China (\(\Delta {\log imv}^{US}_{i,t}\)) against US tariff changes (\(\Delta \tau ^{US \rightarrow CN}_{i,t}\)) between January 2017 and September 2019, both of which are aggregated at the 87 Chinese SIC industry level (the level of aggregation in this paper):

    $$\begin{aligned} \Delta {\log imv}^{US}_{i,t} = \;&-1.179^{***} \Delta \tau ^{US \rightarrow CN}_{i,t} + \alpha _{i} + \eta _{t} + \epsilon _{i,t}\\& (0.345) \end{aligned}$$

    where \(\alpha _{i}\) and \(\eta _{t}\) are industry and time fixed effects, and the standard error in parenthesis is clustered at the industry level. The growth rate of US imports from China drops by 1.179 percentage points in response to a one percentage point rise in US tariffs on China. The size of the coefficient is in line with prior literature (e.g. -1.52 to -1.42 at the HS 10-digit level in Amiti et al. (2019) and Fajgelbaum et al. (2019)).

  9. Related to the fall in exports of capital goods, the trade war may have affected investment for Chinese firms through various channels. Higher tariffs on Chinese imports and a subsequent fall in US demand may have directly lowered expected returns to capital. Moreover, trade policy uncertainty could also stifle investments of Chinese firms (Handley and Limão 2015). As a related research, Amiti et al. (2020) show that US–China tariff actions through 2018 and 2019 significantly lowered the investment growth rate of listed US firms.

  10. The share of each category in the 2017 total exports to China is 67.3% for intermediates, 14.8% for capital goods, 6.6% for consumption goods and 11.3% for others that are classified into multiple categories or unclassified.

  11. See the Appendix Table 6 for the full list of the countries with the values of their exports to China for 2016.

  12. The remaining 46 industries in non-tradable sectors include energy production, construction and a wide range of private and public services industries that are not subject to tariffs. According to the 2012 imported input matrix for China available in the WIOD, 82.0% of imported intermediates into China are used by tradable industries, while the other 18.0% are used by non-tradable industries.

  13. The World IO table is constructed using both product-level trade flows across countries and national IO tables. For more details on WIOD, refer to Timmer et al. (2015).

  14. For matching between the CSIC 5-digit industries and the HS 6-digit products, we exploit the lookup table between the Korean SIC (KSIC) 5-digit industries and the HS 6-digit products provided by Statistics Korea as a bridge since the KSIC 5-digit industries and the CSIC 5-digit industries are very well aligned.

  15. These firms make up around 8% in total number of entities and account for only about 3% in aggregate sales, which implies that they are quite small firms. Adding these outlier firms yields qualitatively same results, with somewhat larger and equally significant estimates overall.

  16. Using a balanced panel of firms would alleviate any selection bias associated with entry or exit. A large number of firms are dropped due to the use of the balanced panel.

  17. For instance, the CSIC-industry “Glass and glass products (30055)” includes intermediates (HS 6-digit of 700100, “Cullet and other waste and scrap of glass; glass in the mass”), consumption goods (701322, “Stemware drinking glasses, other than of glass-ceramics: Of lead crystal”) and capital goods (701322, “Signalling glassware and optical elements of glass”).

  18. There are 93 CSIC industries in the tradable sectors: agriculture, mining and manufacturing. Among these, three industries do not export: “Support service to farming, forestry etc.” (05005), “Mining support activity etc.” (11011), “Slaughtering and processing of meat” (13016), and “Other electronic equipment (39090)”.

  19. This US vertical shock measure is conceptually linked to the “upstreamness measure” by Antràs and Chor (2018), and the “vertical specialization measure” by Hummels et al. (2001) as these all capture the forward linkages in productions across countries. The main difference is that our vertical shock measure attempts to identify a relatively short-run upstream effect of US tariffs that is specific to input suppliers to China, whereas Antràs and Chor (2018) capture the cross-country upstreamness in a general equilibrium setting.

  20. For empirical evidence, see Bernard et al. (2008) and Amiti et al. (2014).

  21. Processing trade was introduced by the Chinese government in the 1980s in an effort to boost their competitiveness in global markets (Yu 2014). Chinese firms import all or part of the raw materials and intermediate inputs, and then re-export the finished products after local processing or assembly. Despite their diminishing share, processing exports still accounted for 37.8% of China’s total exports in 2014 (Kang and Liao 2016).

  22. By the same token, we admit that using the US share of China’s total exports as in this paper would possibly overstate the US tariff effects on Chinese producers.

  23. Analogously, $30 (=100*15/(5+15+10+20)) and $20 (=100*10/(5+15+10+20)) of the imports are assigned to the motor-shipbuilding and battery-auto industry pairs, respectively.

  24. Both the vertical impact and trade depression due to US tariffs predict a negative impact on third country exports to China. But while trade depression could take place in any type of the end-use categories, the vertical propagation should occur in intermediates only.

  25. Chinese government cut its MFN tariffs on other trading partners when imposing retaliatory tariffs against the US in 2018 (Bown et al. 2019).

  26. Since some ISIC 2-digit sectors include only one CSIC-industry, we group these sectors with other similar sectors together. Specifically, we combine “Crop and animal production, hunting and related service activities (A01)”, “Forestry and logging (A02)” and “Fishing and aquaculture (A03”) as a single sector group. We further group “Manufacture of paper and paper products (C17)” and “Printing and reproduction of recorded media (C18)” as “C17-18”, “Manufacture of chemicals and chemical products (C21)” and “Manufacture of basic pharmaceutical products and pharmaceutical preparations (C22)” as “C21-22”, “Manufacture of basic metals (C24)” and “Manufacture of fabricated metal products, except machinery and equipment (C25)” as “C24-C25”, and “Manufacture of motor vehicles, trailers and semi-trailers (C29)” and “Manufacture of other transport equipment (C30)” as “C29-C30”. The results using the initial definition of sectors are largely similar, however. We also test the sector-specific second-degree time polynomials to account for potentially nonlinear aspects of the global business cycle. The results are very similar, with almost none of the coefficients for sectoral trends being significant.

  27. This is to account for the possibility of correlated residuals within sectors as our vertical shock measure exploits the IO elements in the WIOD. Alternative clustering—at the country-industry pair—does not make much difference, though.

  28. Note that Table 1 reports different numbers of observations in regressions for each end-use category. This is because certain end-use products are entirely missing for some country-industry pairs. For instance, there is no capital goods in the CSIC industry ‘Paper and paper products (22036)’ for most countries.

  29. This indicates that the fall in exports of capital goods to China could have been far more severe in the absence of the trade diversion.

  30. When the US vertical shock is scaled by non-intermediate share \((1-\omega ^{CN}_{i,c})\), the coefficient was -0.932 which is insignificant as expected, with the standard error of 0.962.

  31. The absence of market-switching could be due to various frictions on international transactions including upfront entry costs that are likely to be country-specific, as discussed extensively in trade literature.

  32. We confirm that dropping any individual country, sector or industry does not alter the size of the coefficient on the US vertical shock, nor its significance substantially.

  33. In other tariff controls (\(\widetilde{Z_{i}}*D_{t}\)), China’s MFN tariff changes (\(\Delta {Tariff}^{MFN}_{i,t}\)) were not transformed as these would affect third countries’ exports more immediately. Applying the same transformation to the MFN tariffs makes no difference in our results.

  34. One may wonder whether countries with a higher share of intermediates in their exports to China (\(\omega ^{CN}_{i,c}\)), regardless of their exposures to the US vertical shock, experienced a larger fall in their export growth. However, the correlation between the changes in their export growth and their intermediate shares was merely -0.09, and thus, the initial share of intermediate cannot explain much part of the changes in exports.

  35. Once US tariff revenues and other general equilibrium effects are accounted for, they suggest that the losses could have been reduced to 0.04 percent of GDP.

  36. The magnitude of this mechanism could be huge. Alessandria et al. (2010) suggest that inventory adjustments account for up to 20% of the drop in US imports during the trade collapse of 2008-2009. The impact could be largely heterogeneous across industries as well. In their case study on the US auto industry, imports fell by more than twice the sales of imported autos during the same period.

  37. Literature including Handley and Limão (2015) highlights the importance of trade policy uncertainty for trade and investment decisions.

  38. One related hypothesis could be the presence of a global component of fixed export cost. For instance, Mau (2017) argues that firms should pay not only the conventional destination-specific fixed cost but a global (product-specific) fixed cost of exporting which results in economies of scale in serving multiple destinations. This implies that a negative demand shock in one foreign market, particularly a large one (the US), could induce Chinese firms to exit not only from the affected market but also from other destinations due to the increased per destination global fixed cost, which would result in much larger fall in their input demand.

  39. As evidenced by the diagonal elements of most IO tables, a large fraction of inputs produced in each industry are purchased by its own industry. As a study using information other than the IO tables, Handley et al. (2020) exploit the firms’ imports of the same HS 4-digit categories as their export products in evaluating the supply chain effect of the US import tariffs on the US exporters.

  40. Note that these coefficients estimate the effects of a one standard deviation increase in each component of shocks. If we consider the actual changes in each shock component between pre- and post-2018.Q1 periods, the vertical effect from other sectors contributes less than a tenth to the total vertical effect.

  41. The correlation between the original and the inventory-augmented vertical shocks is 0.75 between 2018:Q2-2019:Q3—the period when massive tariff changes occurred.

  42. Defever et al. (2020) show that wholesalers—the key agent holding inventories—play an important role of supplying foreign intermediate inputs and they cover around 21.4% of total intermediate imports for Chinese manufacturing sectors in 2002.

  43. Besides that, the merchandise exports account for over 30% of the Korea’s GDP. This may imply that a large fraction of Korean manufacturing firms engage in exporting—particularly to China as their largest foreign market—and should thus be exposed to the US–China trade war either directly or indirectly.

  44. This magnitude seems somewhat large given that the US vertical effect on Korea’s export growth to China was −3.1 percentage points in the previous section.

  45. Cigna et al. (2022) use monthly product-level US imports from 30 countries between 2016 and 2019 to examine whether US tariffs on China increased US imports from third countries. Similarly to our results, they do not find evidence of a significant trade diversion effect over the time horizon they considered.

  46. The Cobb–Douglas production assumes that country-input varieties are complements. The overall implications of the model remain valid for a more general form of production functions such as in Pakel et al. (2020) under some assumptions when country-input varieties are incomplete substitutes.

  47. For simplicity, we do not consider firm entry into exporting that would incur additional fixed costs.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Akcigit U, Kerr W (2016) Networks and the macroeconomy: an empirical exploration. NBER Macroecon An 30:276–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Alessandria G, Kaboski JP, Midrigan V (2010) Inventories, lumpy trade, and large devaluations. Am Econ Rev 100(5):2304–2339

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Itskhoki O, Konings J (2014) Importers, exporters, and exchange rate disconnect. Am Econ Rev 104(7):1942–1978

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Sang Hoon K, David W (2020) The effect of the U.S.–China trade war on U.S. investment. National bureau of economic research working paper 27114

  • Amiti M, Redding SJ, Weinstein David E (2020) Who’s paying for the US tariffs? A longer-term perspective. AEA Pap Proceed 110:541–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Stephen R, David W (2019) The impact of the 2018 tariffs on prices and welfare. J Econ Perspect 33

  • Antràs P, de Gortari A (2020) On the geography of global value Chains. Econometrica 84(4)

  • Antràs P, Chor D (2013) Organizing the global value Chain. Econometrica 81(6):2127–2204

  • Antràs P, Chor D (2018) On the measurement of upstreamness and downstreamness in global value Chains. National bureau of economic research working paper 24185

  • Bems R, Johnson RC, Yi K-M (2013) The great trade collapse. Ann Rev Econ 5(1):375–400

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bems R, Johnson R, Yi K-M (2011) Vertical linkages and the collapse of global trade. Am Econ Rev Pap Proceed 101(3):308–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard A, Bradford Jensen J, Peter S (2008) Importers, exporters, and a portrait of firms in the U.S. that trade goods. In: Producer dynamics: new evidence from micro data. 513–552. University of Chicago Press

  • Bown C, Euijin J, Eva Z (2019) Trump has gotten China to lower its tariffs. Just toward everyone else. PIIE trade and investment policy watch 12 June, Peterson Institute for International Economics

  • Bown CP, Crowley MA (2006) Policy externalities: how US antidumping affects Japanese exports to the EU. Eur J Polit Econ 22(1):696–714

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bown CP, Crowley MA (2007) Trade deflection and trade depression. J Int Econ 72(1):176–201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bown C, Paola C, Aksel E, Lorenzo T(2021) Trade protection along supply Chain. Center for economic policy research discussion paper 15648

  • Caliendo L, Parro F (2014) Estimates of the trade and welfare effects of NAFTA. Rev Econ Stud 82(1):1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carvalho VM, Tahbaz-Salehi A (2019) Production networks: a primer. Ann Rev Econ 11(1):635–663

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chor D, Li B (2021) Illuminating the effects of the US–China tariff war on China’s economy. National bureau of economic research working paper 29349

  • Cigna S, Meinen P, Schulte P, Steinhoff N (2022) The impact of US tariffs against China on US imports: evidence for trade diversion? Econ Inq 60(1):162–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crowley M (2019) Trade war: the clash of economic systems endangering global prosperity. Center for economic policy research press

  • Defever F, Imbruno M, Kneller R (2020) Trade liberalization, input intermediaries and firm productivity: evidence from China. J Int Econ 126:103329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fajgelbaum PD, Goldberg PK, Kennedy PJ, Khandelwal AK (2019) The return to protectionism. Quart J Econ 135(1):1–55

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flaaen A, Pierce J (2019) Disentangling the effects of the 2018–2019 tariffs on a globally connected U.S. manufacturing sector. FEDS working paper, board of governors of the federal reserve system

  • Handley K, Limão N (2015) Trade and investment under policy uncertainty: theory and firm evidence. Am Econ J Econ Policy 7(4):189–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Handley K, Fariha K, Ryan M (2020) Rising import tariffs, falling export growth: when modern supply chains meet old-style protectionism. National bureau of economic research working paper 26611

  • Huang Y, Chen L, Sibo L, Heiwei T (2019) Trade networks and firm value: evidence from the U.S.–China trade war. Center for economic policy research discussion paper 14173

  • Hummels D, Ishii J, Yi K-M (2001) The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. J Int Econ 54(1):75–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang JS, Liao W (2016) Chinese imports: What’s behind the slowdown? IMF working paper 16/106, international monetary fund

  • Levchenko Andrei A, Lewis Logan T, Tesar Linda L (2010) The collapse of international trade during the 2008–09 crisis. In: Search of the smoking gun. IMF Econ Rev 58(2):214–253

  • Mau K (2017) US policy spillover (?)—China’s accession to the WTO and rising exports to the EU. Eur Econ Rev 98:169–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pakel BD, Beata Smarzynska J, Michalski TK, Evren O (2020) Financial constraints and propagation of shocks in production networks. CESifo working paper 8607, center for economic studies and Ifo institute (CESifo)

  • Timmer M, Erik D, Bart L, Robert S, de Vries GJ (2015) An illustrated user guide to the world input–output database: the case of global automotive production. Rev Int Econ 23(3)

  • Yu M (2014) Processing trade, tariff reductions and firm productivity: evidence from Chinese firms. Econ J 125(June):943–988

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Minkyu Son.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I am grateful to Meredith Crowley, Michael Gasiorek, Christopher Rauh, Gabriella Santangelo, John Spray, Thomas Prayer and the participants in Empirical Micro workshops at the University of Cambridge for thoughtful comments and constructive suggestions. I also thank Yu-jeong Cho, Seung-whan Lee and Chang-hyun Park for fruitful feedback in an internal seminar at the Bank of Korea.

Appendices

More statistics and results

Table 6 Exports values and US vertical effect, by country
Fig. 6
figure 6

Dynamic specification for US–China tariffs on sales growth of Korean firms. Figure plots regressions with full time dummies interacted with each tariff shock on the growth rate of sales for Korean firms. Shaded areas indicate 95% confidence intervals

Theoretical framework for vertical effects

This appendix describes a simple theoretical framework to illustrate how US–China tariff changes are associated with China’s demand for third countries’ intermediate inputs. Then, we derive the empirical measures of each vertical shock. The main purpose is to show that the vertical effect due to US tariffs on Chinese imports, the focus of our research, is robust to inclusions of alternative vertical channels related to Chinese tariffs on the US. The framework is in a partial equilibrium setting and focuses on the short-run impacts of the US–China tariffs. For simplicity, we assume one representative firm in each industry-country pair.

1.1 Technology

Consider a representative Chinese firm in tradable industry i that uses labour and multiple imported intermediate inputs to produce a single differentiated product in the following Cobb–Douglas production function:Footnote 46

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{i} = A_{i} L_{i}^{\alpha _{i}} \bigg (\prod _{j=1}^{N} \prod _{c=1}^{N_{c}} {X_{i,j(c)}}^{\gamma _{i,j(c)}} \bigg ) \end{aligned}$$
(B1)

where \(A_{i}\) denotes firm productivity which is exogenously given, \(L_{i}\) is labour and \(X_{i,j(c)}\) indicate foreign imported input varieties j from origin country c that firm i uses, respectively. N and \(N_{c}\) denote the numbers of industries and origin countries, respectively. Constant returns to scale implies \(\alpha _{i} + \sum _{c}^{N_{c}} \sum _{j}^{N} \gamma _{i,j(c)} = 1\). Total production cost isFootnote 47:

$$\begin{aligned} TC_{i} = w L_{i} + \textstyle \sum _{j} \textstyle \sum _{c} \tau _{j(c)} v_{j(c)} X_{i,j(c)} \end{aligned}$$
(B2)

where w is nominal wage and \(v_{j(c)}\) is the unit producer price of foreign intermediate input j(c) in the importer’s currency and \(\tau _{j(c)}\) is the Chinese ad valorem tariff imposed on input j from origin country c. Cost minimization yields marginal cost as:

$$\begin{aligned} c_{i} = \frac{w^{\alpha _{i}}}{A_{i} \text{\O}mega _{i}} {\bigg [\prod _{j=1}^{N} \prod _{c=1}^{N_{c}} \big ( \tau _{j(c)} {v_{j(c)}} \big )^{\gamma _{i,j(c)}} \bigg ]} \end{aligned}$$
(B3)

where \(\text{\O}mega _{i} = \alpha _{i}^{\alpha _{i}} \prod _{j=1}^{N} \prod _{c=1}^{N_{c}} ({\gamma _{i,j(c)}}^{\gamma _{i,j(c)}})\) is a collection of technology parameters.

1.2 Profit maximization

The Chinese firm sells its product to home and foreign markets. We assume that each firm faces monopolistic competition in each market and consumers have a CES preference over differentiated products with elasticity of substitution between products common across destinations (\(\sigma \)). Then, the residual demand faced by a firm i in home and foreign market d is, respectively:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_{i}^{H} = \bigg (\frac{p_{i}}{P} \bigg )^{-\sigma } E Q^{d}_{i} = \bigg (\frac{\tau _{i}^{d} p_{i}^{d}}{{P_{d}}} \bigg )^{-\sigma } E_{d} \end{aligned}$$
(B4)

where E and \(E_{d}\) are demand shifters and P and \(P_{d}\) are price indices for home and foreign market d. \(p_{i}\) and \(p_{i}^{d}\) are the prices set by Chinese firm i for home (H) and foreign market d. \(\tau _{i}^{d}\) is the tariff imposed on Chinese firm i’s exports by importing country d. Profit maximization in each market yields the common optimal price:

$$\begin{aligned} p_{i} = p_{i}^{d} = \frac{\sigma }{\sigma -1} c_{i} \end{aligned}$$
(B5)

Market clearing for firm i’s output yields:

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{i} = Q^{H}_{i} + \textstyle \sum _{d}^{} Q^{d}_{i} \end{aligned}$$
(B6)

1.3 Foreign input demand

Let us turn to Chinese demand for non-US imported inputs. Combining Eqs. (B3)-(B6) together with the first-order condition for \( X_{i,j(c)}\) in the cost minimization problem yields

$$\begin{aligned} \ln X_{i,j(c)} = \ln \gamma _{i,j(c)} - \ln v_{j(c)} + \ln c_{i} + \ln \bigg [Q^{H}_{i} + \textstyle \sum _{d}^{} Q^{d}_{i} \bigg ] \end{aligned}$$
(B7)

To focus on the short-run impact of tariffs, we assume that the terms related to firm technology (\(A_{i}, \alpha _{i}, \gamma _{i,j(c)}\) and \(\text{\O}mega _{i}\)) and macroeconomic factors (w, E, \(E_{d}\), P, \(P_{d}\), \(\forall d\)) are not affected by the changes in tariffs between the US and China. We further assume that the unit producer prices of foreign inputs (\(v_{j(c)}\)) also remain unchanged. Total differentiation of Eq. (B7) with respect to US tariffs on China \(\tau _{i}^{US}\) and China’s retaliatory tariffs on US inputs \(\tau _{j(US)}^{CN}\) leads to:

$$\begin{aligned} d\ln X_{i,j(c)} = \underbrace{-\sigma \psi _{i}^{US} d\ln \tau _{i}^{US}}_{\text {Vertical effect due to US tariff}} + \underbrace{(1-\sigma ) {\textstyle \sum }_{j} \gamma _{i,j(US)} d\ln \tau _{j(US)}}_{\text {Vertical effect due to China tariff}} \end{aligned}$$
(B8)

where \(\psi _{i}^{US}=\frac{Q^{US}_{i}}{Q^{H}_{i} + \sum _{d}^{} Q^{d}_{i}}\) denotes the fraction of Chinese firm i’s total output exported to US markets and \(\gamma _{i,j(US)}\) is the cost share of input j sourcing from the US.

For non-US foreign input supplier j(c) (\(\forall c \ne US\)), the total demand change from across all Chinese tradable industries, with \(X_{j(c)} = \sum _{i} X_{i,j(c)}\), can be expressed as:

$$\begin{aligned} d\ln X_{j(c)}&= \textstyle \sum _{i} \theta _{i,j(c)}^{F} d\ln X_{i,j(c)} \nonumber \\&= \textstyle \sum _{i} \theta _{i,j(c)}^{F} \Bigg [-\sigma \psi _{i}^{US} d\ln \tau _{i}^{US} + (1-\sigma ) \textstyle \sum _{j} \gamma _{i,j(US)} d\ln \tau _{j(US)} \Bigg ] \end{aligned}$$
(B9)

where \(\theta _{i,j(c)}^{F}=\frac{X_{i,j(c)}^{F}}{\sum _{i} X_{i,j(c)}^{F}}\). Equation (B9) shows that the vertical linkage effect associated with US tariffs (\(d\ln \tau _{i}^{US}\)) is definitely negative as a demand-side effect. The sign of the vertical effect related to Chinese tariffs (\(d\ln \tau _{j(US)}^{CN}\), \(\forall j\)) is determined by \((1-\sigma )\) which is negative as long as \(\sigma >1\). To interpret, there are two different channels through which Chinese tariffs on US inputs could affect its demand for other foreign inputs. First is a “substitution effect”. The higher US input prices due to Chinese tariffs will result in substitution of the US imports into the other countries’ inputs. This is conceptually identical to the trade diversion effect mentioned in the text, except that the substitution effect in this section holds for intermediate inputs only. Second is that, due to complementarity between different inputs, higher US input prices driven by Chinese tariffs increase the production cost of Chinese firms. The resulting demand fall and profit loss of Chinese producers would eventually lead to a fall in China’s demand for every input, not only US inputs. This negative “production cost effect” is more pronounced if consumers are more price-elastic (higher \(\sigma \)).

So far, we assumed that the price index in Chinese market (P) remains unchanged. We may go one step further by relaxing this assumption and allow Chinese retaliatory tariffs on US imports of final goods in industry i (\(\tau _{i(US)}\)) to shift Chinese price index (\(P = \big [p_{i}^{1-\sigma } + \textstyle \sum _{c} (\tau _{i(c)} p_{i(c)})^{1-\sigma }\big ]^{\frac{1}{1-\sigma }}\)) upward, thereby strengthening the price competitiveness of Chinese producers in their home market. And this will lead to an increase in foreign input demand by Chinese producers. Incorporating this additional effect yields:

$$\begin{aligned} d\ln X_{j(c)} =&\textstyle \sum _{i} \theta _{i,j(c)}^{F} \Bigg [-\sigma \psi _{i}^{US} d\ln \tau _{i}^{US} + \sigma \psi _{i}^{H} \eta _{i(US)} d\ln \tau _{i(US)} \nonumber \\&+ (1-\sigma ) \textstyle \sum _{j} \gamma _{i,j(US)} d\ln \tau _{j(US)} \Bigg ] \end{aligned}$$
(B10)

where \(\psi _{i}^{H}=\frac{Q^{H}_{i}}{Q^{H}_{i} + \sum _{d}^{} Q^{d}_{i}}\) is the fraction of Chinese industry i’s total output sold in Chinese home market and \(\eta _{i(US)}\) is the US market share in Chinese markets of that industry i. The additional term (\(\sigma \psi _{i}^{H} \eta _{i(US)} d\ln \tau _{i(US)}\)) captures the potential gains in home market for Chinese producers due to Chinese tariffs on US final goods.

1.4 Linking theory to data

To build the empirical counterparts of each vertical shock from US–China tariffs that are consistent with Eq. (B10), we exploit the industry-level IO tables described in the text. The underlying assumption is that individual firms do not deviate systematically from the aggregate input-output structure of the industries to which they belong.

Two \(\mathbf {N x N}\) matrices are constructed. First is \(\theta ^{\mathbf{F}}_{\mathbf{c}}\), which is obtained by dividing China’s intermediate imports from each origin country c for each input-output industry pair by China’s total intermediate import of a given input industry from the origin country. \(\gamma _{\mathbf{US}}\) is a matrix for the cost share of each US input in each Chinese industry’s total output. Both \(\theta ^{\mathbf{F}}_{\mathbf{c}}\) and \(\gamma _{\mathbf{US}}\) build on the origin country-specific import matrix that is constructed by disaggregating the sector-level World IO table proportionally to the industry-level Chinese detailed IO table.

$$\begin{aligned} \theta ^{\mathbf{F}}_{\mathbf{c}} = \begin{bmatrix} \theta _{1,1(c)}^{F} &{} \theta _{1,2(c)}^{F} &{} \cdots &{} \theta _{1,N(c)}^{F} \\ \theta _{2,1(c)}^{F} &{} \theta _{2,2(c)}^{F} &{} \cdots &{} \theta _{2,N(c)}^{F} \\ \vdots &{} \vdots &{} \ddots &{} \vdots \\ \theta _{N,1(c)}^{F} &{} \theta _{N,2(c)}^{F} &{} \cdots &{} \theta _{N,N(c)}^{F} \end{bmatrix} \quad \gamma _{\mathbf{US}} = \begin{bmatrix} \gamma _{1,1(US)} &{} \gamma _{1,2(US)} &{} \cdots &{} \gamma _{1,N(US)} \\ \gamma _{2,1(US)} &{} \gamma _{2,2(US)} &{} \cdots &{} \gamma _{2,N(US)} \\ \vdots &{} \vdots &{} \ddots &{} \vdots \\ \gamma _{N,1(US)} &{} \gamma _{N,2(US)} &{} \cdots &{} \gamma _{N,N(US)} \end{bmatrix} \end{aligned}$$
Table 7 Testing for alternative vertical shocks

We use \(\psi ^{\mathbf{US}}\), \(\psi ^{{\mathbf {H}}}\) and \(\eta ^{\mathbf {US}}\) to denote \(\mathbf {N x 1}\) vectors for \(\psi _{i}^{US}\), \(\psi _{i}^{H}\) and \(\eta _{i}^{US}\), constructed using Chinese detailed IO for 2012 and trade share between the US and China for 2016. Likewise, \(\tau _{\mathbf {CN,t}}^{\mathbf {US}}\), \(\tau _{\mathbf {J(US),t}}^{\mathbf {CN}}\) and \(\tau _{\mathbf {US,t}}^{\mathbf {CN}}\) are vectors of US tariffs on China at time t, Chinese tariffs on US intermediates and on US non-intermediates within each CSIC industry, respectively. Then, based on Eq. (B10), we build three distinct \(\mathbf {N x 1}\) vectors of vertical shocks as follows:

$$\begin{aligned}&{\textit{Vertical Shock from US tariffs}} = \theta ^{{\mathbf {F}}}_{{\mathbf {c}}}*(\psi ^{\mathbf {US}} \circ \varvec{\Delta } \tau _{\mathbf {CN,t}}^{\mathbf {US}}) \end{aligned}$$
(B11)
$$\begin{aligned}&{\textit{Vertical Shock from CN tariffs on US inputs}} = \theta ^{{\mathbf {F}}}_{{\mathbf {c}}}*(\gamma _{\mathbf {US}} \circ \varvec{\Delta } \tau _{\mathbf {J(US),t}}^{\mathbf {CN}}) \end{aligned}$$
(B12)
$$\begin{aligned}&{\textit{Vertical Shock from CN tariffs on US final goods}} = \theta ^{{\mathbf {F}}}_{{\mathbf {c}}}*(\psi ^{{\mathbf {H}}} \circ \eta ^{\mathbf {US}} \circ \varvec{\Delta } \tau _{\mathbf {US,t}}^{\mathbf {CN}}) \end{aligned}$$
(B13)

where \(\circ \) denotes element-wise multiplication. The formula (B11) is a vector expression of the benchmark measure 1 of the US vertical shock in the text except that we use the US share in the China’s total export of industry i as \(\psi _{i}^{US}\) (not the US share in China’s total output of that industry) based on the discussion in Sect. 4.1 of the main text. (B12) and (B13) express the newly constructed measures of vertical shocks related to Chinese tariffs on US imports of intermediates and final goods, respectively.

Table 7 shows the results including two additional vertical channels of (B12) and (B13), along with the US vertical effect (B11). These two alternative shocks related to Chinese retaliatory tariffs were not statistically significant. The US vertical effect, on the other hand, remains highly significant with little changes in magnitude across different specifications. These confirm that the US vertical shock is the major channel in propagations of the US–China tariff shocks to third countries at the current level of aggregation and the time horizon.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Son, M. The global propagation of the US–China trade war. Empir Econ 63, 3121–3157 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-022-02231-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-022-02231-7

Keywords

JEL classification:

Navigation