1 Introduction

Peer effects—that is, the effects of peers’ behavior on actors’ own behavior through social networks—have been recognized in the theoretical and empirical economics literature (Blume et al. 2011; Jackson and Zenou 2015). Although many studies have examined peer effects on economic activity, such as student performance (Sacerdote 2001; Zimmerman 2003; Angrist and Lang 2004; Calvó-Armengol et al. 2009), one strand of this literature focuses on peer effects on the decision to participate in social programs. For example, Duflo and Saez (2003) analyzed the role of social interactions in employees' decision to enroll in a retirement plan. They conducted an experiment in which they provided randomly selected employees with monetary incentives to participate in information fairs, and they found a positive peer effect on participation.

Peer effects may affect participation in social and business programs, particularly in programs focused on information dissemination, for four reasons. First, actors may be more likely to participate in a program if their peers also participate because actors may obtain the benefits of face-to-face interactions, which include having an enjoyable time with peers and lowering psychological barriers to participation. Second, peers' participation encourages actors to participate if they expect to be able to discuss the information provided in a program with these peers and thus to enhance their understanding of the information. This channel is related to Centola's (2010) findings from a social experiment showing that people are more likely to adopt new health behaviors when a group’s online social network is dense, i.e., when most of a group’s members know one another. Centola (2010) interpreted this finding to indicate that the reinforcement of the same knowledge by multiple peers results in a deeper understanding of the knowledge and thus promotes its adoption. We refer to this channel as information confirmation. Third, peers’ participation discourages actors’ participation in programs because actors may be able to obtain the information that their peers receive in the program at no personal cost. We refer to this channel as information free riding. Fourth, those who participated in a program may encourage or discourage their peers from participating in the same program on the following days depending on its content and quality. We refer to this channel as word-of-mouth. In short, the benefits of face-to-face interactions and information confirmation result in positive peer effects, whereas free riding results in negative peer effects. However, whether word-of-mouth results in positive peer effects or negative effects depends on the seminar content and quality.

Whether peer effects are positive or negative largely affects the participation rate in a seminar. On the one hand, if positive peer effects dominate because of the benefits of face-to-face interactions and information confirmation, actors' gain from participation depends on whether their peers participate. If actors believe that their peers will not participate, they will not participate either. In this situation, few will participate. However, if they believe that their peers will participate, most of them will also participate. On the other hand, if negative peer effects dominate because of free riding, only a few actors participate, whereas others free ride and thus obtain the information provided in the seminar. In either case, peer effects may result in a low participation rate in programs for information dissemination. In practice, the take-up rate of social and business programs, particularly those in developing countries, is often quite low (Bertrand et al. 2004; Currie 2006; Bruhn and Zia 2013; McKenzie and Woodruff 2014).

Therefore, the empirical question of how peer effects work in such programs is relevant to both program organizers and policy makers. However, it is difficult to empirically identify peer effects both because of the reflection problem articulated by (Manski 1993). The reflection problem arises because average group behaviors are a mirror image of individual behaviors. Thus, it is difficult to identify causality from the correlations between behaviors.

To accurately identify peer effects, recent studies have utilized natural and randomized experiments on peer formation and participant selection (Duflo and Saez 2003; Zimmerman 2003; Falk and Ichino 2006; De Giorgi et al. 2010; Aral and Walker 2011; Banerjee et al. 2013; Dahl et al. 2014; Sacerdote 2014; Cai and Szeidl 2018; Fafchamps and Quinn 2018). This study follows this literature on identifying peer effects based on randomized experiments. In particular, we conducted a randomized controlled trial (RCT) in which we invited randomly selected firm representatives from a population of registered small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) in 11 traditional garment and textile clusters in Vietnamese villages to seminars on export promotion. Before the RCT, we conducted a survey among all of these SMEs to capture the complete information exchange network of the firms within each cluster. The network peers were the information exchange partners solicited. In this setting, the number of firms’ peers that are invited to the seminar can be considered as random given the number of peers. Thus, we identify peer effects by estimating the impact of the number of invited peers on managers’ participation after controlling the number of peers. Since only invited firms can participate in the seminars, the effect of the number of peers that are invited to the seminar can be viewed as a good proxy for the effect of peers’ participation on their own participation.

Furthermore, we identify two of the four types of peer effects mentioned earlier, i.e., those arising from benefits of face-to-face interactions and word-of-mouth, and test if the remaining two, i.e., information confirmation and information free riding, are jointly significant. In our experiment, we invited each participant to one of three one-day seminars held over three consecutive days. The invited firms were allocated to the three seminars randomly, and they were not allowed to change their participation date. Given this unique structure of our experiment, we can separately examine the effect of peers who are invited to the seminars before the seminar to which a firm is invited, of those who are invited to the seminar to which the firm is invited, and of those who are invited to the seminars after the seminar to which the firm is invited. The three types of peers would generate some of the four types of peer effects differently. Specifically, peers who were invited to the earlier seminars could affect the firm's decision maker through three channels, namely, word-of-mouth, information confirmation, and information free riding. Peers who were invited to the seminar on the same day could influence the decision maker through three channels, i.e., the benefits of face-to-face interactions, information confirmation, and information free riding. However, peers who were invited to the later seminars could affect the decision maker only in terms of information confirmation and information free riding. Therefore, the difference between the effect of peers invited to the earlier seminars and of those invited to the later seminars should constitute peer effects arising from word-of-mouth. Furthermore, the difference between the effect of those invited to the same seminar and of those invited to the later seminars should constitute peer effects attributable to the benefits of face-to-face interactions.

To preview our results, we find a positive, statistically significant, and quantitatively large effect of the number of peers who were invited to the seminar on the same day on firm managers’ decision to participate in the seminar. However, neither the effect of the number of peers who were invited to the earlier seminars nor the effect of the number of peers who were invited to the later seminars is statistically significant. In addition, we reject the null hypothesis that the difference in the effect of the number of peers who were invited to the seminar on the same day and the effect of peers who were invited in the later seminars is zero. That is, the benefits of face-to-face interactions led to positive peer effects on participation in the seminar. However, the null hypothesis that the effect of the number of peers who were invited to the earlier seminars and the effect of peers who were invited to the later seminars are the same cannot be rejected. Thus, peer effects arising from word-of-mouth are found to be absent. Moreover, the sum of the positive effect due to information confirmation and the negative effect due to information free riding is not statistically significant, although we cannot further distinguish between the two.

Our results supporting positive peer effects, particularly those due to benefits of face-to-face communication, imply that the rate of firms' participation in the seminars may vary across villages, depending on the village characteristics that determine firms' beliefs about their peers' participation. We find evidence that supports this argument: there was a low participation rate (less than 40 percent) among 8 of the 11 villages in our sample, while the take-up rate was quite high (more than 50 percent) in others. This argument is also consistent with the literature finding that peer effects may lead to herd behaviors (Durlauf 2006; Blume et al. 2011; Bursztyn et al. 2014).

This study contributes to the literature on the identification of peer effects in the following four ways. First, although several papers, such as Cai and Szeidl (2018) and Fafchamps and Quinn (2018), examine peer effects on firms' performance and practices, this study is the first attempt to identify peer effects on firm managers’ decisions to participate in business programs.

Second, we define peers according to firms' actual links to the exchange of business information. Most studies have defined peers according to group membership (Sacerdote 2001; Duflo and Saez 2003; Zimmerman 2003; De Giorgi et al. 2010). However, not all members of a particular group are necessarily closely connected for information or utility exchange, and it is therefore difficult to interpret the estimates from these studies (Carrell et al. 2011). Accordingly, some recent studies have defined peers more precisely, using data for social networks (Falk and Ichino 2006; Calvó-Armengol et al. 2009; Aral and Walker 2011; Banerjee et al. 2013; Card and Giuliano 2013). The current study follows this strand of the literature and identifies all peer firms within the cluster with which firms exchange business information by asking firm representatives directly.

Third, we separately estimate several types of peer effects, particularly finding positive effects arising from the benefits of face-to-face interactions. A decomposition of peer effects into those from social learning and those from social utility is provided by Bursztyn et al. (2014), who examined how individuals’ decisions to purchase a financial asset affect their peers’ decisions. Our findings provide new light in the literature on the decomposition of peer effects.

In addition to making an academic contribution, this study can contribute to policy making. The take-up ratio of business and social programs is often low despite these programs’ potential benefits. This study implies that program organizers can spatially focus their interventions and invite dense cliques of firms to increase the participation rate.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data and RCT. Section 3 presents the empirical methodology and the results, and Sect. 4 provides a discussion of the results and conclusions.

2 Data and randomized experiment

2.1 Sampling and survey

In this study, we focus on SMEs in village-based apparel and textile industry clusters in the Red River Delta surrounding Hanoi, the capital city of Vietnam. Village industry clusters are traditionally developed agglomerations of SMEs, including microenterprises in a particular industry such as apparel, wood furniture, or ceramics, within the village boundary. We focus on village industry clusters because it allows us to observe all networks within the village through which firms exchange business information. We have a substantial interest in export promotion through information seminars, and therefore, we target SMEs in the apparel and textile industry. Since the ratification of the US-Vietnam Bilateral Trade Agreement in 2001 and resulting reductions in tariffs, including those on apparel and textiles, exports of these products from Vietnam to the US have drastically increased. However, SMEs in traditional village clusters lag behind. In our sample explained later in detail, only approximately 10 percent of SMEs exported their products. This is possibly because of the lack of information about the procedures of exporting and foreign markets. Using the same experiment and data as used in this study, Kim et al. (2018) find that the exporting promotion seminar encourages relatively large firms among the targeted SMEs to export, implying that the seminar successfully provides important information for targeted SMEs to start exporting. Therefore, these institutional backgrounds are suitable for the objectives of this study.

We identified the village clusters using data from the Vietnam Enterprise Survey (VES), which was conducted by the General Statistical Office of Vietnam (GSO) in 2010. We chose villages or communes, which are the smallest administrative units, with more than five registered firms in the textile and apparel industries (industry codes 13 and 14 in the Vietnamese system of industry classifications) in the 10 provinces in the Red River Delta. Because not all of the firms are formally registered and because smaller firms in the VES are randomly selected,Footnote 1 villages with more than five registered firms in the apparel and textile industry in the VES data are most likely to be industry clusters of a specific industry. Through this process, we initially identified 19 villages in six provinces. We visited the selected villages and found that two villages among the 19 are not apparel and textile clusters, as most manufacturing firms in the villages do not necessarily engage in apparel or textile production. We also omitted one village from our sample both because it had already received business management training through another RCT and because it had been surveyed several times for impact evaluation (Higuchi et al. 2015). We assumed that firms in this village were already systematically different from firms in other villages.

Our study targeted registered firms in the remaining 16 apparel and textile village clusters. For each of the 16 villages, we obtained the full updated list of registered firms from the municipal governments. The total number of all registered firms in the target villages was 354. In December 2014 and January 2015, we requested face-to-face interviews with the owners, managing directors, and top-level managers of the 354 firms and obtained responses from 296, for a response rate of 84 percent. The questionnaire comprised questions on standard firm characteristics such as sales, the number of workers, main products, and ownership. In addition, to identify firm networks within a cluster, we presented to a representative of each firm the full list of registered firms in the village and asked him or her to list the firms with which the firm regularly exchanged business information.Footnote 2 Because we surveyed most of the registered firms within a village, we identified a nearly complete network of registered firms within each village.

2.2 Seminars on export promotion

We conducted an RCT in which we randomly selected approximately half of the 286 firms that were surveyed and invited each of them to one of three one-day seminars on export promotion held from March 14 to March 16, 2015. The seminars consisted of four common classes on the following topics: introduction to the development of the global economy (delivered by a business school professor); basic exporting procedures (delivered by an official from the Vietnam Export Promotion Agency); advice for exporting to Japan (delivered by officials from the Hanoi office of the Japan External Trade Organization, JETRO); and finally, learning about the experiences of current exporters. The content of the seminars was slightly different across the three days: there was an additional class on e-customs on the second and third days, and there was a reception dinner after the seminar on the third day (Kim et al. 2018). However, we can disregard these differences when we estimate peer effects because the invitees were not informed about such differences upon invitation, and therefore, their decision to participate could not have been affected by the differences among the seminars.

The venue of the seminars was a three-star hotel located at the center of Hanoi. We chose a three-star hotel to attract participants. Traveling from the sample villages to the hotel took a minimum of 30 min by motorbike to a maximum of 2 h by bus. For several villages located far from the hotel, we chartered buses for the participants' transportation. We provided reimbursement for the cost of travel to participants who used their own means of transportation, such as public buses or motorbikes. Except for transportation cost reimbursement, no compensation was provided for participation except for meals at the hotel. We did not collect any participation fees from the participants.

2.3 Selection and participation of firms

We randomly selected 50 firms for the first day, 50 firms for the second day, and 51 firms for the third day (151 firms in total) using a stratified sampling strategy at the village level. Then, we sent an enumerator of the firm-level survey to personally invite each firm to the seminars and to deliver a formal letter that explained the details of the seminar. In the letter, we noted that only the owner, the managing director, or a top-level manager could participate in the seminars, although the seminar participants and respondents to our surveys may have differed. A few days before the seminars, we made phone calls to the firms to invite them again. If the firms were not willing to participate at the time of the first phone call, we made another phone call a day before the seminar. No firms were allowed to participate in the seminars unless they were invited, so there were no participants who had not been invited.

A small number of the invited firms participated in our seminars. Only 9 out of 50 firms participated on the first day, 15 out of 50 firms participated on the second day, and 14 out of 51 firms participated on the last day. In total, of the 151 invited firms, 38 firms participated; thus, the participation rate was 25.2 percent. This low participation rate is comparable to that of the business and financial literacy program conducted by Bruhn and Zia (2013) in Bosnia and Herzegovina.

2.4 Construction of variables

The dependent variable is a dummy variable that takes a value of one if firm i participated in one of the three seminars and zero otherwise. The key independent variables are \(INV\_EARL{Y}_{i}\), \(INV\_SAM{E}_{i}\), and \(INV\_LATE{R}_{i}\), i.e., the number of firm i’s peers invited to the earlier seminars, the number of its peers invited to the seminar on same days, and the number of its peers invited to the later seminars, respectively. Firm i's peers are defined as the firms that were reported by the survey respondent of firm i as information-sharing partners or those that reported firm i as an information-sharing partner. In network terms, this study utilizes undirected network data. Although our estimations are based on 131 invited firms with complete information, the number of peers is defined based on the information exchange partners of all of the registered firms within each village, including those that did not respond, those that were not invited, and those that were dropped due to missing information.

The control variables include firm attributes that contain the log of the total number of workers, the share of exports in total sales, the log of firm age, and the attributes of the top-level manager of each firm—such as the president or the owner—including the log of his or her age, the log of his or her years of education, and a dummy that indicates whether the respondent was female. The number of a firm’s peers invited to the earlier seminars, \(INV\_EARL{Y}_{i}\), is not observed for firms invited to the seminar on the first day. Similarly, the number of a firm’s peers invited to the later seminars, \(INV\_LATE{R}_{i}\), is not observed for firms invited to the seminar on the third day. We assign zero to these variables when these variables are not observed. To control for the effect of this procedure in the analysis, we include dummy variables that represent which seminar a firm was invited to in the estimated equations.

2.5 Descriptive statistics

When we construct the sample for our estimations, we dropped 6 firms in five villages in which the number of respondent firms was less than 3 so that the number of invited peers was mostly zero. We were forced to drop 14 firms that failed to report the survey information that was necessary for the estimations. Consequently, our baseline sample consists of 131 invited firms from 11 villages. Although the invited firms were not allowed to participate in a seminar that was different from the seminar to which they were invited, five invited firms attended a seminar to which they were not invited. For ethical reasons, we ultimately had to allow them to participate. In the analysis, we kept these five firms in the sample since the number of invited peers remains exogenous given the number of peers.

Table 1 analyzes whether we succeeded in randomizing the invitations we sent to the firms by conducting t tests for systematic differences between the invited and noninvited firms in terms of the control variables for the firm and manager attributes used in the estimation. None of the variables showed a statistically significant difference between the two groups.

Table 1 Differences between invited and noninvited firms

Table 2 shows the descriptive statistics of the variables that are used in later estimations for the sample of 131 firms. The average number of peers is 4.02, of which approximately half, i.e., 1.98, were invited to one of the three seminars. Figure 1 shows the distribution of the number of peers and the number of invited peers, indicating their large variation. The average number of peers participating in any of the seminars is 0.62. Because the target firms are in traditional garment and textile clusters, the average number of workers, 25.99, is relatively small. On average, the share of exports in total sales is 19.0 percent, the firm age is 6.57 years, the age of managers is 42.9 years, and they have 13.8 years of education. Additionally, 19.8 percent of the managers are female. In the sample, 31.3, 35.1, and 33.6 percent of firms were invited to the seminar on the first, second, and third day, respectively.

Table 2 Descriptive statistics
Fig. 1
figure 1

Distribution of the number of peers

3 Estimation methods and results

3.1 Total peer effects

When we estimate peer effects on firm managers’ participation decisions in seminars, there are several challenges to identifying peer effects. First, the largest challenge is that it is difficult to identify peer effects because of the reflection problem (Manski 1993). That is, because firms' participation decisions would affect each other, the decisions of a particular firm's peers, which is a determinant of the firm's decision, are a function of the firm’s decision. Therefore, the regression of the firm’s participation on its peers’ participation would create a mechanical endogeneity because peers’ participation would capture the firm’s own participation, which would bias the estimated coefficients.

To address the biases caused by reflection, we employ the number of peers who were randomly invited to the seminars as the key independent variable in ordinary least squares (OLS) estimations. Because the number of each firm's peers invited to the seminars is randomly determined once the total number of its peers is controlled for, we can avoid the endogeneity arising from the reflection problem in regressions where the number of invited peers and the total number of peers are simultaneously used as independent variables. A more intuitively plausible way is to use the number of invited peers as an instrumental variable (IV) for the number of participating peers in IV estimations. Then, the coefficient of the number of participating peers can be easily interpreted as the effect of peer behaviors on one’s own behavior. However, given the small sample in this study, IV estimates may be quite biased. Therefore, we employ the OLS approach using the number of invited peers rather than IV using the number of participating peers. Although the number of invited peers does not directly represent peers' behaviors, its effect on the firm's participation can be viewed as a good proxy for the effect of peers' behaviors on own behavior because only invited firms can participate in the seminars and our OLS approach is a reduced form of the IV approach in which the number of participating peers directly represents peers' behaviors. It should be noted that the effect of the number of invited peers should be smaller than the effect of the number of participating peers because the former is diluted by invited but nonparticipating peers.

The second source of bias in the estimation of peer effects is the correlated effects of Manski (1993) or the correlation between unobservable attributes shared by an actor and its peers, such as common knowledge, willingness to learn, aspiration to export, culture, and their behaviors. Such unobservable attributes arise mostly because of endogenous formation of peers. If the unobservable common attributes or common shocks to a group are not controlled for, they are included in the error term and thus lead to another type of endogeneity in peer participation (Bramoullé et al. 2009, 2020).

To address the issue of correlated effects, we control for village fixed effects in the estimated equations. Since the village fixed effects pick up common unobservable characteristics shared by all firms in the village, village fixed effects control for correlated effects to some extent. However, if firms connected to each other have a similar propensity to participate in the seminar due to correlated unobserved characteristics shared by peer firms, the estimation of peer effects is still biased due to correlated effects even if we control for village fixed effects. To check whether correlated effects bias the estimation of peer effects using village fixed effects, our alternative specification drops firms that have no peer from the sample and uses network cluster fixed effects, i.e., fixed effects for firms connected directly or indirectly with each other within the village, instead of village fixed effects.

Finally, the estimation of peer effects can be biased by the exogenous effect of Manski (1993) or the direct effect of peers' attributes on the firm's behavior. In particular, in the settings of this study, we presume that firm managers may decide whether or not they participate in the seminars, partly depending on the attributes of other invited firms and firm managers. For example, if invited peer firms of a firm are large in size or their managers are male, the firm may be more willing to participate in the seminars. To control for the exogenous effect, we include the average attributes of invited peers of the focal firm in the set of independent variables. Based on these arguments, we consider the following linear probability model:

$$\begin{aligned} PAR_{il} &= \alpha_{l} + \beta INV_{il} + \delta n_{il} + \gamma X_{il} + \zeta Day_{i} \\ & \quad + \lambda \mathop \sum \limits_{{j \in P_{il} }} X_{jl} /n_{il} + \varepsilon_{il} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

where \(PAR_{il}\) is a dummy variable for the participation of firm \(i\) in village \(l\) in the invited seminar and \(P_{il}\) represents the set of firm i's invited peers in village \(l\). The first term on the right-hand side, \(\alpha_{l}\), is the village fixed effect. The second term, \(INV_{il}\), is the number of firm i’s peers in village \(l\) invited. Thus, \(\beta\) represents the effect of peers who were invited to the seminars on the firm manager’s participation decision. We refer to this effect as total peer effects. The third term,\(n_{il}\) is the number of peers of firm \(i\). The number of invited peers of firm \(i\), \(INV_{il} ,\) can be seen as good as random after controlling the number of peers, while the number of peers of firm \(i\) is endogenously determined. The fifth term, \(Day_{i} ,\) is dummies that indicate on which day firm \(i\) is invited to the seminar. The sixth term, \(\mathop \sum \limits_{{j \in P_{i} }} X_{jl} /n_{il} ,\) is a vector of the average attribute of invited firm\(i\)’s peers. Thus, \(\uplambda\) represents the exogenous effect, as argued by Manski (1993). The seventh term,\({\varepsilon }_{il}\), is the error term.

The result from the OLS estimation of Eq. (1) is shown in column (1) in Table 3. The estimated coefficient on the number of invited peers is positive but not statistically significant. Next, we dropped 22 firms that have no peer from the sample and use network cluster fixed effects instead of village fixed effects in Eq. (1). The results in column (2) of Table 3 indicate that the estimated coefficient on the number of invited peers is still positive but statistically insignificant. In the benchmark estimations, we use the number of invited peers as our key independent variable, assuming that peer effects are larger when the number of peers is larger. We alternatively use the dummy variable that takes a value of one if the firm has any invited peer and zero otherwise, highlighting the difference between firms with no invited peers and those with any positive number of peers. Column (3) of Table 3 indicates that the estimated coefficient on the dummy is positive but statistically insignificant, a result that is consistent with the benchmark result. Because the number of invited peers varies more than the dummy for invited peers, we will hereafter use the number of invited peers rather than the dummy.

Table 3 Estimation results for aggregate peer effects

3.2 Decomposing peer effects

Subsequently, we decompose peer effects. That is, we estimate the effect of peers who were invited to the earlier seminars, peers who were invited to the seminar on the same day, and peers who were invited to the later seminars. We consider the following linear probability model:

$$\begin{aligned} PAR_{{il}} & = \alpha _{l} + \beta _{1} INV_{{EARLY_{i} }} + \beta _{2} INV_{{SAME_{i} }} + \beta _{3} INV_{{LATE_{i} }} \\ &\quad + \delta n_{{il}} + \gamma X_{{il}} + \zeta Day_{i} ~ + \lambda \mathop \sum \limits_{{j \in P_{{il}} }} X_{{jl}} /n_{{il}} + u_{{il}} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

where \(INV\_EARLY_{i}\) is the number of firm i’s peers that are invited to the earlier seminars, \(INV\_SAME_{i}\) is the number of firm i’s peers that are invited to the seminar to which firm i is invited, \(INV\_LATE_{i}\) represents the number of firm i’s peers that are invited to the later seminars, and \(u_{il}\) is the error term. The effect of peers who were invited to the earlier seminars, \({\beta }_{1}\), represents the sum of their effects through word-of-mouth, a positive effect due to information confirmation, and a negative effect due to information free riding. The effect of peers invited to the same seminar, \({\beta }_{2}\), constitutes the sum of positive peer effects due to the benefits of face-to-face interactions, a positive effect due to information confirmation, and a negative effect due to information free riding. The effect of peers invited to the later seminars, \({\beta }_{3}\), represents the sum of the effects due to information confirmation and free riding. Therefore, \({\beta }_{1}-{\beta }_{3}\) signifies the peer effect arising from word-of-mouth, and \({\beta }_{2}-{\beta }_{3}\) constitutes the peer effect due to the benefits of face-to-face interactions.

The result is shown in column (1) in Table 4. The results demonstrate a positive and statistically significant effect of the number of peers invited to the same seminar but no significant effect of the number of peers invited to the earlier or the later seminars. To address correlated effects more accurately as we did in Sect. 3.1, we estimate an alternative specification, replacing the village fixed effects with network cluster fixed effects in Eq. (2). The result is shown in column (2) in Table 4. The estimated coefficients for the number of peers invited to the seminar on the same day, the number of peers invited to the earlier seminars, and the number of peers invited to the later seminars are very similar to those in column (1) in Table 4.Footnote 3 Therefore, using village fixed effects or network cluster fixed effects, i.e., whether controlling for correlated effects less or more accurately, does not affect the estimation results of peer effects in our analysis. As a robustness check, we test whether the results above remain valid if we control for the effect of no peers or the effect of peers not on the list of registered firms. The results are shown in columns (3)–(5) in Table 4. The results remain largely unchanged when controlling for these effects. In addition, because the dependent variable is a dummy variable, we estimated Eq. (2) by applying logit and probit models. The estimated coefficients and average marginal effects are shown in Table 5. The results are very similar to those in column (1) in Table 4.

Table 4 Estimation results of the decomposition of peer effects
Table 5 Estimation results of the decomposition of peer effects by logit model and probit model

As a further robustness check, we test whether the results above remain valid if we incorporate other standard measures of centrality in a network, such as the eigenvector, betweenness, and closeness centrality (Jackson 2010), into the set of control variables used in Eq. (2). The results are shown in Table 6. The estimated coefficients of the number of peers invited to the seminar on the same day and of the number of peers invited to the earlier seminars and of the number of peers invited to the later seminars are mostly similar to those in Table 4 even when we incorporate other centrality measures into the analysis. However, the estimated coefficients on all of these centrality measures are not statistically significant. These results imply that after we control for the simplest centrality measure, the degree to which other centrality measures do not necessarily affect firms’ participation decisions and therefore may not be incorporated into the estimations.

Table 6 Estimation results of the decomposition of peer effects incorporating network centrality

Based on the above argument, we separate peer effects into those arising from the benefits of face-to-face interactions, those arising from word-of-mouth, and the sum of the other two effects (a positive effect due to information confirmation and a negative effect due to information free riding). We conduct Wald tests to examine the null hypothesis that the peer effect arising from word-of-mouth is zero (\({\beta }_{1}-{\beta }_{3}=0\)) and the null hypothesis that the peer effect due to the benefits of face-to-face interactions is zero (\({\beta }_{2}-{\beta }_{3}=0\)). The two rows in the lower part of Tables 4 and 6 show p values associated with these Wald tests.Footnote 4 The null hypothesis on peer effects arising from word-of-mouth is not rejected statistically in all specifications in Tables 4 and 6. Therefore, we find no evidence that word-of-mouth from peers did not promote participation in the seminars. A possible reason for the lack of a word-of-mouth effect is that participants had no time to spread information about the seminars because the seminars were held on three consecutive days and ended at 4:00 p.m. or 4:30 p.m. each day. In contrast, the null hypothesis on the peer effect due to benefits of face-to-face interactions is rejected at the 5-percent level in all specifications in Tables 4 and 6. These results suggest that firm managers are more willing to participate in the seminars to enjoy face-to-face communication with their peers there. Moreover, the insignificant effect of the number of peers invited to the seminar on the later days in Tables 4, 5, and 6 implies that the sum of the positive effect due to information confirmation and the negative effect due to information free riding is zero, although we cannot further distinguish between the two.

As discussed in Sect. 2.3, five invited firms participated in a "wrong" seminar to which they were not invited. We checked whether the results from the estimations and Wald tests hold if we drop these five firms from the sample. To save space, we do not show the full estimation results here, but they are mostly similar to the results in Tables 4, 5, and 6 except that the estimated coefficients of the number of peers who invited to the seminar on the same day are smaller (but still statistically significant) than those in Tables 4, 5, and 6. The results of the Wald test using the smaller sample are essentially the same as those in Tables 4 and 6.

3.3 Heterogeneity

We further investigate the possibility that peer effects are heterogeneous depending on firm attributes, particularly focusing on managers’ gender and exporting activities. We incorporate the interaction term between the number of invited peers and each of these firm attributes to Eq. (1) and show the results in columns (3)–(5) in Table 3. The estimated coefficient for the interaction terms between the number of invited peers and share of exporting is negative and statistically significant, while the estimated coefficient for the interaction terms with the female dummy is not significant. Thus, total peer effects on participation in the seminar are negative for exporting firms.

Similarly, we investigate heterogeneity in decomposed peer effects by incorporating interaction terms between the number of peers invited to the earlier, the same, and the later seminars and firm attributes (i.e., the manager's gender and the share of exports) into Eq. (2). The results are shown in columns (1)–(3) in Table 7. The estimated coefficient of the interaction term between the number of peers invited to the seminar on the same day and the share of exports is negative and statistically significant, whereas other interaction terms are not statistically significant. Therefore, the peer effect arising from the benefits of face-to-face interactions for exporting firms is weaker than that for nonexporting firms.

Table 7 Heterogeneity in decomposition of peer effects

4 Discussion and conclusion

By utilizing an RCT in traditional clusters of apparel and textile SMEs in Vietnam, we investigate peer effects on firms’ participation in seminars focused on export promotion. We use the number of randomly invited peers to identify such peer effects. We further decompose the invited peers into peers invited to a seminar on the earlier day, peers invited to seminars on the same day, and peers invited to seminars on the later days. In this way, we can isolate peer effects caused by the benefits of face-to-face interactions and peer effects arising from word-of-mouth from the sum of the positive effect of information confirmation and the negative effect of information free riding on peers’ information.

The results in Tables 3, 4, 5, 6 and 7 can be summarized as follows. First, the identified peer effect caused by the benefits of face-to-face interactions is large: an additional peer invited to the seminar on the same day increases a firm’s probability of participation in the seminar by 12.2 percentage points (column (1) in Table 4), whereas the average participation rate is only 25.2 percent (Table 2). However, the peer effect caused by the benefits of face-to-face interactions is weakened for exporting firms’ managers. Second, we do not find evidence that word-of-mouth from peers led to peer effects in our case. Third, theoretically, there may be two other types of peer effects: a positive effect due to information confirmation among peers and a negative effect due to information free riding on peers' information. Our empirical results suggest that the two opposing effects may cancel each other out or may both be negligible.

The positive peer effects found in this study imply the possibility of multiple equilibria across the group, as argued in Card and Giuliano (2013): Firms are better off participating in a seminar if many peers participate, but they are worse off if only a few peers participate. In our experiment, we indeed found some villages in which most of the invited firms did not participate in any seminar and other villages in which most of the invited firms participated in some seminars (see Fig. 2).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Interfirm social network and participation in the seminars. Notes: Red, green, and yellow circles indicate firms that participated in a seminar, those that were invited but did not participate in any seminar, and those that were not invited to any seminar, respectively. (Color figure online)

The actual situation in this study is more complicated, however, as we find positive effects of peers invited to a seminar on the same day but no effect of peers invited to the earlier seminars and of peers invited to the later seminars. In the latter cases, depending on how many firms in the village were invited to the seminar on each of the three days, the participation rate within the village varied. Suppose, for example, that three firms that are linked to each other in a village were invited to the seminar on the first day but that only one firm in the same village was invited on each of the other two days. Then, depending on their beliefs about their peers' behaviors, all or none of the former three firms would participate. However, the last two might not participate, which would lead to a participation rate of either 75 percent or 0 percent.

Based on this conjecture, we expect that the take-up rate among invited firms varies substantially across villages, although it may skew toward zero. Panel a of Fig. 3 shows the distribution of the take-up rate among the invited firms in each village. The dominant take-up rate is approximately 10–20 percent, but there are a few villages with rates of 50–70 percent. Panel b shows the take-up rate among invited firms with invited peers in the ego network of each invited firm, i.e., the invited firm and its invited peers. However, the distribution of the other firms is dispersed widely, from 10 to 100 percent, while the dominant take-up rate is 0 percent. Some firm networks have a high take-up rate of over 80 percent. These dispersed distributions are consistent with the argument that multiple equilibria exist as a result of peer effects.

Fig. 3
figure 3

Distribution of the take-up rate. Notes: This figure shows the distribution of the take-up rate among the invited firms in the ego network of each of the 131 invited firms studied in the regressions, i.e., an invited firm and its invited peers. Firms that have no peers are excluded from Fig. 3b

Our results provide an important policy implication. The evidence of positive peer effects mostly due to the benefits of face-to-face interactions provides an explanation for the fact that the take-up rate of social and business seminars is often low (Bruhn and Zia 2013; McKenzie and Woodruff 2014). The take-up ratio of any program involving a collective face-to-face component can be low when invitees expect that their peers will not participate. Therefore, to increase the take-up ratio, the organizer needs to fully utilize peer effects arising from the benefits of face-to-face interactions and invite many firms in a particular social or business group rather than a few firms from each of many groups. Social network studies often argue that a strategy to effectively utilize social networks for information diffusion is to invite social program opinion leaders or people in visibly influential positions, hoping that their message will spread to others (Valente 2017). Our study shows another strategy to effectively raise the take-up ratios of social and business programs, although it does not necessarily reject the role of opinion leaders in information diffusion.

Finally, we note an important caveat. Although the existence of information free riding is an important academic and policy issue, we cannot distinguish between the effect of information free riding and the effect of information confirmation in this study. One way to decompose the peer effect of information free riding is to utilize variation in the difficulty of seminar subjects. If a seminar provides information that is difficult to understand (for example, procedures for exporting activities), the negative peer effect of information free riding may be minimal because it is difficult to obtain this information from others without participating in the seminar. In contrast, information free riding is prominent if the subject of the seminar is important but easy to understand (for example, procedures for applying for subsidies). By comparing peer effects across these situations, we may decompose the peer effect of information free riding. We leave this issue to future research.