Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Innovation spillover and merger decisions

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The merger–innovation nexus has been well studied in the theoretical literature, but empirical evidence, particularly on the spillover impacts of innovation, is limited. Merger decisions are influenced by a series of macroeconomic and behavioural factors; however, internalizing innovation spillovers and keeping a competitive edge may also explain merger activities. In this paper, we investigate the impact of innovation spillovers on the likelihood of firms to merge, using a combined panel data set of mergers among publicly traded US manufacturing firms from 1980 to 2003. Innovation is measured using R&D investments and citation-weighted patents, and innovation spillover is proxied using the technological proximity of firms and rivals’ innovation. We include a series of control variables affecting merger decisions and address the potential endogeneity problem using previous R&D activities of firms. We find that innovative firms are on average more likely to merge. The results also show that within-industry inward spillovers increase the likelihood of mergers, but between-industry inward spillovers do not influence merger decisions significantly. Our main results are robust to alternative measures of innovation and spillovers as well as to different estimation methods such as propensity score matching.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. As an example, Jost and Velden (2008) point to the development of a new drug in the pharmaceutical industry, which requires large R&D investments and takes several years. The requirement for large investments in R&D has led to mergers between large companies in this industry, including GlaxoWellcome and SmithKlinee Beecham in 2001 and Hoechsr and Rhone Poulenc in 1998 among many others.

  2. The private rate of return of innovation is the benefit earned by the firm participating in the innovative activities. The social rate of return includes benefits to consumers and other firms (Jaffe 1998).

  3. There are other cooperative strategies to capture spillovers, such as research joint ventures or RJVs (Gugler and Siebert 2007; Kamien et al. 1992). Both mergers and RJVs may result in efficiency gains and market power; however, they are different in terms of their production decisions. Firms make their production decisions cooperatively in mergers, but they act independently in RJVs. RJVs also do not reduce the number of firms in the market in the same way as mergers and thus the likelihood of gaining higher market power in the case of RJVs is less acute than mergers. Gugler and Siebert (2007) show that efficiency effect dominates market power effect for both mergers and RJVs in the semiconductor industry, but mergers achieve efficiencies sooner than RJVs. Our study is focused on mergers, as we do not have information on RJVs in our data and, therefore, cannot compare the impacts of mergers and RJVs on innovation spillovers.

  4. Bena and Li (2014) also include non-merging firms in their control group and construct a technological proximity measure close to ours. However, their specification of non-merging firms and technological proxies differs from ours. They include as non-merging firms those that have participated in the merger process but whose bids were not successful during the 3-year intervals before the announcement and after the withdrawal. Thus, some firms in their control group may have experienced mergers outside of this 6-year time span. Our non-merging firms are those that did not experience a merger in the entire span of our sample; our observations of these firms are not limited to the suggested 6 years in Bena and Li (2014). For technological proximity, Bena and Li use patenting information across technological classes of PATSTAT data on target and acquirers in failed or completed mergers during the 6-year intervals. Our technological proximity measure uses the distribution of patent citations of all firms (completed mergers and non-merging firms in the entire sample) across technological classes of the USPTO for all years of the sample. Compared with the patent count, the patent citations variable is a better proxy for innovation as it reflects the quality of the patents and the benefits that a firm receives from the research activity of other firms in the same technology field (Noel and Schankerman 2013; Entezarkheir 2017).

  5. As in Noel and Schankerman (2013), the initial sample values of R&D variable is used as the initial stock of R&D. Hall and Mairesse (1995) use 15% for the depreciation rate and show that the R&D stock measure is not sensitive to changes in this parameter.

  6. The proximity measure is symmetric to the ordering of firms (\(\rho _{ij}\) = \(\rho _{ji}\)).

  7. We will also specify technological proximity based on industries rather than technology classes in Sect. 4.2.

  8. Chemicals includes chemical products; Computers includes computers and computing equipment; Drugs includes optical and medical instruments and pharmaceuticals; Electricals includes electrical machinery and electrical instrument and communication equipment; Mechanicals includes primary metal products, fabricated metal products, machinery and engines, transportation equipment, motor vehicles, and auto parts. The number of firms and the number of mergers in each industry in the sample are: Chemicals, 174/21 (12%); Computers, 337/28 (5.3%); Drugs, 1089/87 (8%); Electricals, 1250/99 (8%); Mechanicals, 866/91 (10%).

  9. Harford (2005) and Komlenovic et al. (2011) use the first principal component of \(AssetTurnover_{it}\), \(EmployGrowth_{it}\), SaleGrowth it, \(Profitability_{it}\), \(ROA_{it}\), and \(CapitalExp_{it}\) to measure industry shocks. They justify this by the high level of multicollinearity among these variables in the industry level. However, we do not find this problem at the firm-level data, and therefore we use the six variables above directly in Eq. (1). As a robustness check and for the sake of comparison, we also report our estimates of Eq. (1) with the first principal component of these variables in Sect. 4.

  10. According to Harford (2005), the regulation changes took place in 1981, 1982, 1984, 1987, 1989, and 1991–96. We also estimated Eq. (1) controlling for these regulation changes but our estimated coefficients of \( logR \& DStock_{it-1}\) and \( logSpillR \& D_{it-1}\) present a similar result.

  11. Inflation adjustments are based on the CPI urban US  index for 1992 (Source: http://www.bls.gov).

  12. Our measure of business cycle also controls for time fixed effects. We also control for time fixed effects with indicator variables for each year instead of business cycles in Sect. 4.

  13. For a detailed explanation of the series used in building the CFNAI index, see Komlenovic et al. (2011) and www.chicagofed.org/publications/cfnai/index.

  14. Another measure of business cycles previously used in the literature is the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) business cycles index. The reported status of the economy by the NBER dates, however, has considerable lags, which devalues the information provided for company managements in their decision-making. For example, NBER announced the trough in the business cycle of June 2009 on 20 September 2010. However, the CFNAI index is built upon economic data present at the estimation time. This information on NBER dates is available at: http://www.nber.org/cycles.html.

  15. This method of calculating market share follows Blundell et al. (1999), who employ sales in the primary SIC3, Giroud and Mueller (2010), who use sales in the primary SIC2 and SIC4; and Duso et al. (2014), who utilize sales in the primary SIC4. We would have liked to build the market share variable at a more disaggregate level, but our data only provide information at the SIC4 level. As Duso et al. (2014) note, using SIC4-level information to define market share might generate lower bound estimates, as the relevant anti-trust market might be smaller than the product markets defined by SIC4.

  16. Bronwyn Hall prepared the updated NBER patent and citation files, available at http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~bhhall/. The original files are explained in Hall et al. (2001) and their time range is from 1963 to 1999.

  17. The publicly traded firms are those traded on the New York, American, and regional stock exchanges, as well as over-the-counter in NASDAQ.

  18. The company identifier file is available at http://elsa.berkeley.edu/~bhhall.

  19. According to the USPTO’s website, withdrawn patents are those that are not issued (http://www.uspto.gov/patents/process/search/withdrawn.jsp). Note that the citation data are not limited to public firms.

  20. To correct for the truncation in patent and citation counts, we follow Hall et al. (2000) by defining a weight factor as follows:

    $$\begin{aligned} PC_{t}^*= & {} \frac{PC_{t}}{\sum _{J=0}^{2003-t} W_J} \nonumber \\ 2000\le & {} t\le 2003, \end{aligned}$$
    (6)

    where \(PC_{t}\) is the number of patents granted at time t to all firms and \(W_J\) is an index built based on the average citations in each lag for the patents granted. Lags are the differences between the last year of the sample (2003) and the ending years of the sample (2000–2003). We multiply the inverse of the weight factor (\(1/PC_{t}^*\)) by the patent counts in ending years of the sample to correct for the truncation. We apply this to years 2000–2003, because the last years of the sample (2004–2006) are subject to “edge effect”: large variances and therefore unstable. We also correct for truncation in citations data using the citations distribution between the granting year of the citing patent and the granting year of the cited patent in the patent document of the citing patent. We then forecast the number of citations that might be received for each citing patent outside the range of the sample up to 40 years after the granting date of the citation counts. For more details, see Entezarkheir and Moshiri (2018).

  21. Note that some of the acquiring firms experience several mergers during the sample period, and we keep them all in the sample.

  22. The number of replications for bootstrapped standard errors is 400.

  23. This interpretation of the results may not be robust if there is a large number of competing firms in each industry, as the acquiring firm can only internalize a very tiny portion of the knowledge spilling over to many firms. However, the median industry in our data has 14 public firms and one merger (29 firms and two mergers on average) with the HHI index of 0.28, implying that each merger may still provide access to a considerable part of the spillover pool.

  24. We also estimated the model with the second and third lags of innovation spillover variables but the results remain robust. In the case of second lag, the estimated coefficients of \( logR \& DStock_{it-2}\) and \( logSpillR \& D_{it-2}\) are 0.283 (Std.Error \(=\) 0.131) and 0.651 (Std. Error \(=\) 0.228), and in the case of third lag, the estimated coefficients of \( logR \& DStock_{it-3}\) and \( logSpillR \& D_{it-3}\) are 0.223 (Std.Error \(=\) 0.086) and 0.678 (Std. Error \(=\) 0.192), respectively. As suggested by a referee, we isolated the impact of technological proximity on the merger likelihood by removing it from the spillover measure. The estimated coefficient of spillover without technological proximity is 0.441 (Std.Error \(=\) 0.195), which is less than the original estimated values, implying that technological proximity would increase the impact of innovation spillover on mergers.

  25. One possible concern that may be raised here is that the positive correlation we find is only capturing scale effects. In other words, larger firms tend to merge more. Nevertheless, in our estimations, we control for size of firms by the variable \(EmployGrowth_{it}\) in Eq. (1). Moreover, in Sect. 4.2, we show that when we use the logarithm of R&D expenditure (\( logR \& D_{it}\)) or the logarithm of R&D intensity (\( log(R \& D/L)_{it}\)) instead of stock of R&D for measuring innovation, we still find a positive and statistically significant impact from innovation on merger likelihood.

  26. The effect of \(BC_{t}\) is also positive and significant but smaller than the \(BC_{t-1}\) effect. As a robustness check, we control for time-fixed effects instead of business cycles. The impacts of \( logR \& DStock_{it-1}\) (0.373, Std. Error=0.153) and \( logSpillR \& D_{it-1}\) (1.900, Std. Error=0.741) stay positive and statistically significant.

  27. The negative estimated coefficient of \(logHHI_{ht}\) in Column (3) indicates that higher concentration in the industry of the acquiring firms lowers the likelihood of merger. This finding conforms to anti-trust regulations that a proposed merger in a highly concentrated industry is more likely to be rejected ceteris paribus. Nevertheless, the impact is also not statistically significant.

  28. Since variables on target characteristics may be highly correlated, we also consider the first principal component of these three variables as in Harford (2005). The estimated results with the PC variable included do not change. The estimated coefficients of \( logR \& DStock_{it-1}\) and \( logSpillR \& D_{it-1}\) are 1.239 (Std.Error \(=\) 0.437) and 2.207 (Std. Error \(=\) 0.643), respectively.

  29. The number of replications for bootstrapped standard errors is 400.

  30. As a robustness check, we further estimate the model in Column (3) of Table 6 with the linear probability method. The positive impacts of spillover variables remain the same, smaller in value though. The estimated coefficients of \( logR \& DStock_{it-1}\) and \( logSpillR \& D_{it-1}\) are 0.009 (Std.Error \(=\) 0.003) and 0.019 (Std.Error \(=\) 0.004), respectively.

  31. For a list of studies on competition and innovation, see Entezarkheir and Moshiri (2018).

  32. The Wooldridge (2010) test result also confirms the endogeneity of \( logR \& DStock_{it-1}\).

  33. We apply the method outlined in Wooldridge (2010) for the test of overidentifying restrictions. We first estimate Eq. (1) and obtain predicted residuals. We then calculate \(J=MF\) from a regression of estimated residuals on instruments. The estimated test statistic is equal to 21, leading us almost not to reject the hypothesis of exogeneity of the instruments.

  34. Possible caveats to using the citation-weighted patent stock as a measure for innovation are that some firms may patent defensively, which means that they are only marginal innovations (Hall and Ziedonis 2001; Ziedonis 2004; Noel and Schankerman 2013), and not all innovations are patented. Nevertheless, our findings are robust to this measure of innovation.

  35. The bias is defined as the difference in the mean values of the treatment group and the control group, divided by the square root of the average sample variance in the treatment group and the not matched control group (Rosenbaum and Robin 1985). Our results are robust to other matching techniques, such as Kernel matching.

  36. To check for the common support condition, we compare the min and max values of the propensity score in both the target and control groups. For details on this method, see Caliendo and Kopeinig (2008).

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1988) Growth and cycles through creative destruction. University of Western Ontario Working Paper

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60(1): 323–351

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1998) Endogenous growth theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Aghion P, Bloom N, Blundell R, Griffith R, Howitt P (2005) Competition and innovation: an inverted-U relationship. Q J Econ 120(2):701–728

    Google Scholar 

  • Alcacer J, Chung W (2007) Location strategies and knowledge spillovers. Manag Sci 53(5):760–776

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alcacer J, Zhao M (2012) Local R&D strategies and multilocation firms: the role of internal linkages. Manag Sci 58(4):734–753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrade G, Stafford E (2004) Investigating the economic role of mergers. J Corp Finance 10(1):1–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andrade G, Mitchell M, Stafford E (2001) New evidence and perspectives on mergers. J Econ Perspect 15(2):103–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ang J, Cheng Y (2006) Direct evidence on the market-driven acquisitions theory. J Financ Res 29(2):199–216

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arrow K (1962) Economic welfare and allocation of resources to invention. In: Nelson R (ed) The rate and direction of inventive activity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, pp 609–626

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Bandick R, Gorg H, Karpaty P (2014) Foreign acquisitions, domestic multinationals, and R&D. Scand J Econ 116(4):1091–1115

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baptista R (2000) Do innovations diffuse faster within geographic clusters? Int J Ind Organ 18(3):515–535

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becketti S (1986) Corporate mergers and the business cycles. Econ Rev 71(5):13–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Belleflamme P, Peitz M (2010) Industrial organization: markets and strategies. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bena J, Li K (2014) Corporate innovations and mergers and acquisitions. J Finance 69(5):1923–1960

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein J, Nadiri I (1989) Research and development and intra-industry spillovers: an empirical application of dynamic duality. Rev Econ Stud 56(2):249–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloom N, Schankerman M, Van Reenen J (2013) Identifying technology spillovers and product market rivalry. Econometrica 81(4):1347–1393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Griffith R, VanReenen J (1999) Market share, market value and innovation in a panel of British manufacturing firms. Rev Econ Stud 66(3):529–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boone A, Mulherin H (2000) Comparing acquisitions and divestitures. J Corp Finance 6(2):117–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brealey R, Myers S, Marcus A, Maynes E, Mitra D (2012) Fundamentas of corporate finance. McGrawHill, Toronto

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral L (2000) Introduction to industrial organization. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Caliendo M, Kopeinig S (2008) Some practical guidance for the implementation of property score matching. J Econ Surv 22(1):31–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron C, Trivedi P (2006) Microeconometrics: methods and applications. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron C, Trivedi P (2010) Microeconometrics using stata. College Stations, STATA Press, United States

  • Chirgui Z (2009) Dynamics of R&D networked relationships and mergers and acquisitions in the smart card feld. Res Policy 38(1):1453–1467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunningham C, Ederer F, Ma S (2019) Killer acquisitions. Available at SSRN 3241707

  • Danzon P, Epstein A, Nicholson S (2007) Mergers and acquisitions in the pharmaceutical and biotech industries. Manag Decis Econ 28(4):307–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deman AP, Duysters G (2005) Collaboration and innovation: a review of the effects of mergers. Acquisitions and alliances on innovation. Technovation 25(1):1377–1387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dong M, Hirshleifer D, Richardson S, Teoh SH (2006) Does investor misvaluation drive the takeover market? J Finance 61(2):725–761

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driffield N (2001) The impact on domestic productivity of inward investment in the UK. Manch Sch 69(1):103–119

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Driffield N, Love J, Menghinello S (2010) The multinational enterprise as a source of international knowledge flows: direct evidence from Italy. J Int Bus Stud 41(2):350–359

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duso T, Roller LH, Seldeslachts J (2014) Collusion through joint R&D: an empirical assessment. Rev Econ Stat 96(2):349–370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entezarkheir M (2017) Patent thickets, defensive patenting, and induced R&D: an empirical analysis of the costs and potential benefits of fragmentation in patent ownership. Empir Econ 52(2):599–634

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entezarkheir M, Moshiri S (2018) Mergers and innovation: evidence from a panel of U.S. firms. Econ Innov New Technol 27(2):132–153

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entezarkheir M, Moshiri S (2019) Is innovation a factor in merger decisions? Evidence from a panel of U.S. firms. Empir Econ

  • Gallini N (2002) The economics of patents: lessons from recent U.S. patent reform. J Econ Perspect 16(2):131–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert R, Newbery D (1982) Preemptive patenting and the persistence of monopoly. Am Econ Rev 72(1):514–526

    Google Scholar 

  • Giroud X, Mueller H (2010) Does corporate governance matter in comeptitive industries? J Financ Econ 95(1):312–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gort M (1969) An economic disturbance theory of mergers. Q J Econ 83(1):624–642

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Griliches Z (1992) The search for R&D spillovers. Scand J Econ 94:29–47

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gugler K, Siebert R (2007) Market power versus efficiency effects of mergers and research joint ventures: evidence from the semiconductor industry. Rev Econ Stat 89(4):645–659

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall B (1987) The effect of takeover activity on corporate research and development. In: Auerbach A (ed) Corporate takeovers: causes and consequencs. University of Chicago Press for NBER, Chicago, US

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall B, Mairesse J (1995) Exploring the relationship between R&D and productivity in French manufacturing firms. J Econom 65(1):263–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall B, Vopel K (1997) Innovation, market share, and market value. http://elsa.berkeley.edu/\(\sim \)bhhall/papers/HallVopel97.pdfd

  • Hall B, Ziedonis R (2001) The patent paradox revisited: an empirical study of patenting in the semiconductor industry, 1979–1995. RAND J Econ 32(1):101–128

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall B, Adam J, Manuel T (2000) Market value and patent citations: a first look. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 7741

  • Hall B, Adam J, Manuel T (2001) The NBER patent citations data file: lessons, insights and methodological tools. National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 8498

  • Hall B, Jaffe A, Trajtenberg M (2005) Market value and patent citations. RAND J Econ 36(1):16–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Harford J (2005) What drives merger waves? J Financ Econ 77(1):529–560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hasbrouck J (1985) The characteristics of takeover targets, Q and other measures. J Bank Finance 9(3):351–362

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson R (2000) Drug industry mergers won’t necessariy benefit R&D. Res Technol Manag 43(4):10–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Higgins M, Rodrigues D (2006) The outsourcing of R&D through acquisitions in the pharmaceutical industry. J Financ Econ 80(1):351–383

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huck S, Konrad K, Muller W (2000) Merger in contests. CESifo Working Paper No. 241

  • Igami M, Kosuke U (2019) Mergers, innovation, and entry-exit dynamics: consolidation of the hard disk drive industry 1996–2016. Revi Econ Stud 87(6):2672–2702

  • Jaffe A (1986) Technological opportunity and spillovers of R&D: evidence from firms’ patents, profits, and market value. Am Econ Rev 76(5):984–1001

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A (1989) Real effects of academic research. Am Econ Rev 79(5):957–970

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A (1998) The importance of spillovers in the policy mission of the advanced technology program. J Technol Transf 23(2):11–19

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffe A, Lerner J (2007) Innovation and its discontents: how our broken patent system is endangering innovation and progress, and what to do about it. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Jost P, Velden C (2008) Organizational design of R&D after mergers and the role of budget responsibility. J Econ Bus 60(1):469–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B, Rousseau P (2002) The Q-theory of mergers. Technol Change 92(2):198–204

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien M, Muller E, Zang I (1992) Research joint ventures and R&D cartels. Am Econ Rev 82(5):1293–1306

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz M, Shelanski H (2005) Merger policy and innovation: must enforcement change to account for technological change? In: Jaffe A, Lerner J, Stern S (eds) Innovation policy and the economy. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 109–165

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz M, Shelanski H (2007) Mergers and innovation. Antitrust Law J 1(1):70–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Komlenovic S, Mamun A, Mishra D (2011) Business cycle and aggregate industry mergers. J Econ Finance 35(1):239–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Loughran T, Vijh A (1997) Do long-term shareholders benefit from corporate acquisitions? J Finance 52(5):1765–1790

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maksimovic V, Phillips G (2001) The market for corporate assets: who engages in mergers and assets sales and are there efficiency gains? J Finance 56(1):2019–65

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McQueen G, Roley V (1993) Stock prices, news, and business conditions. Rev Financ Stud 6(3):683–707

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melichner R, Ledolter J, D’Antonio L (1983) A time series analysis of aggregate merger activity. Rev Econ Stat 65(3):423–430

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell M, Mulherin H (1996) The impact of industry shocks on takeover and restructuring activity. J Financ Econ 41(1):193–229

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moeller S, Schlingeman F, Stulz R (2004) Firm size and the gains from acquisitions. J Financ Econ 73(1):201–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moshiri S, Simpson W (2011) Information technology and the changing workplace in Canada: firm-level evidence. Ind Corp Change 20(6):1601–1636

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson R (1966) Business cycle factors in the choice between internal and external growth, the corporate merger. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Noel M, Schankerman M (2013) Strategic patenting and software innovation. J Ind Econ 61(3):481–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norman G, Pepall L (2004) Knowledge spillovers, mergers and public policy in economics clusters. Rev Ind Organ 25(1):155–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oulton N (1997) Total factor productivity growth and the role of externalities. Natl Inst Econ Rev 162(1):99–111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum J (1983) Uncertain innovation and the persistence of monopoly. Am Econ Rev 73(4):741–748

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum J (1984) Practical implications of game theoretic models of R&D. Am Econ Rev Papers Proc 74(1):61–66

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinganum J (1985) Innovation and industry evolution. Q J Econ 100(1):81–100

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes-Kropf M, Viswanathan S (2004) Market valuation and merger waves. J Finance 59(1):2685–2718

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes-Kropf M, Robinson D, Viswanathan S (2005) Valuation waves and merger activity: the empirical evidence. J Financ Econ 77(1):561–603

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenbaum P, Robin D (1985) Constructing a control group using multivariate matched sampling methods that incorporate the propensity score. Am Stat 39(1):33–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1942) Capitalism, socialism and democracy. Harper & Brothers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro C (2001) Navigating the patent thicket: cross licenses, patent pools, and standard-setting. In: Jaffe A, Lerner J, Stern S (eds) Innovation policy and the economy. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Shleifer A, Vishny R (1992) Liquidation values and debt capacity. J Finance 47(4):1343–1366

  • Shleifer A, Vishny R (2003) Stock market driven acquisitions. J Financ Econ 70(1):295–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stahl J (2010) Mergers and sequential innovation: evidence from patent citations. Working Paper in Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

  • Szucs F (2014) M&A and R&D: asymmetric effects on acquirers and targets? Res Policy 43(1):1264–1273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole J (1988) The theory of industrial organization. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Trajtenberg M (1990) A penny for your quotes: patent citations and the value of innovations. Rand J Econ 21(1):172–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weston J (1961) The role of mergers in the growth of large firms. University of California Press, Berkeley

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge J (2010) Econometric analysis of cross section and panel data. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao X (2009) Technological innovation and acquisitions. Manag Sci 55(7):1170–1183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ziedonis R (2004) Don’t fence me in: fragmented markets for technology and the patent acquisition strategies of firms. Manag Sci 50(6):804–820

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mahdiyeh Entezarkheir.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

We are grateful for comments by Mario Samano, and by participants at the 2018 IIOC and CEA conferences, and the seminars organized by the Department of Economics, the University of Western Ontario, and the Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of Saskatchewan. We would also like to thank the anonymous referee for valuable comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Entezarkheir, M., Moshiri, S. Innovation spillover and merger decisions. Empir Econ 61, 2419–2448 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01973-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01973-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation