Skip to main content
Log in

Market prices, spatial distribution of consumers and firms’ optimal locations in a linear city

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We study a game of spatial competition in prices. In particular, we focus on the linear-city duopoly model to see what we can learn about the distribution of consumers, which is not required to be uniform—as in the original Hotelling model. Using variation in firms’ prices and costs, we identify points of the distribution of consumers. Based on these points, we estimate the spatial distribution of consumers along the linear city. We apply our methodology to a dataset of prices of two gas stations on a straight highway. By estimating the distribution of consumers, we are able to find the optimal location of an entrant gas station. Using our estimated distribution of consumers and the entrant’s optimal point, we simulate welfare gains under counterfactual locations of an entrant.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. To make our strategy more realistic, as Bajari and Benkard (2005) do in their seminal paper, we assume that firms choose the “right” (equilibrium) prices each period with some (zero-mean) measurement error.

  2. As we explain later, the estimated distribution of consumers along the highway does not reflect a static distribution of consumers’ residence locations or addresses. It reveals rather the pattern of traffic distribution in different sections of the highway. That is, the peak of the distribution reflects the section of the highway which is usually congested. We carefully selected a straight section of a highway with entries and exits. Entries and exits along a highway generate different traffic flows and congestion zones in different sections of the highway.

  3. The fact that gasoline is a homogeneous good is challenged by Lewis (2008). However, his argument relies on the price differences that arise between “high-brand” and “low-brand” retailers in highly dense urban areas considering the number and type of the surrounding competitors.

  4. We acknowledge that the relatively simple and well-defined structure of the linear-city model (which allows us to develop our empirical strategy) comes at the cost of imposing some of these “simple” assumptions to the empirical applications that we may have in mind (e.g., constant transportation cost across all consumers, unit-demand, etc.). As we discuss below, some of these “simple” assumptions that are present in the theoretical model can also be challenged in the particular empirical application that we propose in this paper (see Sect. 4).

  5. Similar requisites are required in many other countries, such as Australia (see the technical note on the “Investigation of Service Station Sites,” that describes industry best practice in the assessment of service station sites in NSW) and Italy (Decreto legislativo 11 febbraio 1998, n. 32).

  6. This is a valid assumption in the context of our empirical application: wholesale gasoline prices (typically formed in supranational markets, such as the Mediterranean market or the North-Western Europe market; see Sect. 4 for further details) impact gasoline retail prices, but not the other way around. That is, the retail gasoline prices of a pair of (vertically integrated) gas stations at t are not likely to impact supranational wholesale gasoline prices at \(t+1\) (unless some kind of sophisticated collusive agreement at the international level is in play).

  7. This is also a valid assumption in the context of our empirical application, since retail gasoline prices change every day and they are posted electronically (the cost of changing them is virtually zero).

  8. For the sake of simplicity, we normalize it to [0, 1] in the upcoming sections. However, we keep the general form throughout this section.

  9. See Caplin and Nalebuff (1991) for a more in-depth discussion on this Theorem.

  10. In our empirical application, \(\theta \) is the (common) fuel wholesale price and \(\epsilon \) captures gas station-specific marginal costs (labor efficiency, management issues, etc.)—see Thomadsen (2005).

  11. As discussed above, there are no “dynamics” from one period to the next one in the model that justify the use of more sophisticated (time-dependent) solution concepts.

  12. For such a baseline case, we assume a symmetric beta distribution, with shape parameters \(\alpha =\beta =2\), firms’ symmetric locations—in particular \(x_1=\frac{1}{3}\) and \(x_2=\frac{2}{3}\)—and transportation cost \(\tau =25\).

  13. A different question concerns what the observable and the nonobservable variables are. We deal with this issue in the following section.

  14. Shuai (2017) explains that, under perfect inelastic demand (which is the case in the linear-city model), “maximizing welfare is equivalent to minimizing consumers transportation cost.”

  15. If we think in our empirical application, the goal of the social planner (the General Direction of Highways) is to authorize the construction of a new gas station in such a way that the total probability of vehicles running out of gas is minimized.

  16. In this case, if \(f(\cdot )\) is strictly positive in all its support, the optimal location of the entrant is at \(x^*=0\).

  17. In this case, if \(f(\cdot )\) is strictly positive in all its support, the optimal location of the entrant is at \(x^*=1\).

  18. Formally, tie-breaking rules are as follows:

    1. (d)

      (Tie-breaking rule #1) If \(T_1= T_{\text {mid}} > T_2\), the optimal location of the entrant is determined by the following rule: \(x^*={{\,\mathrm{\mathrm{arg\,min}}\,}}_{x\in [\underline{x},\overline{x}]} f(x)\) such that \(f(x^*)>0\) with probability \(\frac{1}{2}\) and \(x^*=\hat{x}\) with probability \(\frac{1}{2}\).

    2. (e)

      (Tie-breaking rule #2) If \(T_{\text {mid}} = T_2 > T_1\), the optimal location of the entrant is determined by the following rule: \(x^*=\hat{x}\) with probability \(\frac{1}{2}\) and \(x^*={{\,\mathrm{\mathrm{arg\,max}}\,}}_{x\in [\underline{x},\overline{x}]} f(x)\) such that \(f(x^*)>0\) with probability \(\frac{1}{2}\).

    3. (f)

      (Tie-breaking rule #3) If \(T_2 = T_1>T_{\text {mid}}\), the optimal location of the entrant is determined by the following rule: \(x^*={{\,\mathrm{\mathrm{arg\,max}}\,}}_{x\in [\underline{x},\overline{x}]} f(x)\) such that \(f(x^*)>0\) with probability \(\frac{1}{2}\) and \(x^*={{\,\mathrm{\mathrm{arg\,max}}\,}}f(x)\) such that \(f(x)>0\) with probability \(\frac{1}{2}\).

  19. More realistic is to assume that entry and exit exist in the market instead, but we leave this issue aside. Estimation of entry and exit decisions in a (general) oligopolistic market is by Bajari et al. (2007).

  20. Some authors have previously analyzed Hotelling’s linear-city model assuming a more general class of distribution of consumers. See Neven (1986), Tabuchi and Thisse (1995), Anderson et al. (1997), Torrisi (2011), Shuai (2017).

  21. In principle, if \(\tau \) is identical for all consumers (as the theoretical model assumes), one could argue that it should be easily calculated (and, therefore, observable). For this reason, we develop the empirical strategy for the case in which the transportation cost is known in Sect. 3.1. However, one could also argue that the calculation of \(\tau \) is not entirely obvious (even for the case of identical consumers). That is why we extend our empirical strategy for the case in which the transportation cost is unknown in Sect. 3.2.

  22. As we have detailed extensively above, in our empirical application we cannot assume that individual gas stations’ posted prices have an impact on wholesale prices and Brent crude oil prices: no gas station has enough power to determine the evolution of the price of fuel commodities. However, this assumption may not be realistic if there we study dominant-market firms (which may influence wholesale prices).

  23. These measurement errors could arise due to modeling error, random idiosyncratic facts and/or firm optimization error.

  24. Previous authors have proposed different methodologies to estimate transportation cost parameters—see, for instance, Englin and Shonkwiler (1995). However, we need to think that \(\tau \) (the transportation cost) acts as an “equilibrium parameter” that helps us to fit the model equilibrium into the observed data.

  25. This happens when both shape parameters, \(\alpha \) and \(\beta \), are equal to 1.

  26. If \(\tau \) is the true transportation cost parameter, then \(x^t=\lambda ^t(\tau )\).

  27. In particular, using the conditions above, the set is bounded below by \(\max \left\{ \min \left\{ 0, \frac{p_{1}^{t,*}-p_{2}^{t,*}}{(x_2-x_1)^2}\right\} , \min \left\{ 0, \frac{p_{2}^{t,*}-p_{1}^{t,*}}{(x_2-x_1)(2-x_2-x_1)}\right\} \right\} \) and the set can be bounded above (if necessary) considering that the sum of the (unique) \(\nu ^t\)’s must be less than or equal to 1—which is a requirement of the distribution itself–, i.e., \(\tau \le \frac{\sum _t p_{1}^{t,*}-c(\cdot )+p_{2}^{t,*}-c(\cdot )}{2(x_2-x_1)}\) for every unique pair of equilibrium prices and costs.

  28. For further details on diesel cars versus gasoline cars, see Verboven (2002).

  29. Hybrid cars, electric cars and cars powered with alternative fuels are still residuals in Spain. According to the European Automobile Manufacturers’ Association, just 2% among new passenger cars in 2015 were hybrid or electric, and less than 2.2% of the cars among the passenger car fleet in Spain in 2014 were powered by alternative fuels.

  30. The data are available at http://geoportalgasolineras.es/#/Inicio [last access: 2020/05/08 14:05:29].

  31. Data are not available for October 12, 2014, which is the Spanish National day.

  32. Marion and Muehlegger (2011) show that gasoline taxes are indeed fully passed onto consumers and are incorporated fully into the tax-inclusive price, under typical supply and demand conditions.

  33. Cepsa, the owner of the gas stations considered in this study, is a partner of this organization.

  34. This formula is used by the Spanish Association of Operators of Oil Products (AOP) to calculate the wholesale cost faced by gas stations in Spain. The formula is included in the annual AOP reports—see, for instance, Asociación Española de Operadores de Productos Petrolíferos (2015). Likewise, the Spanish National Competition Commission (CNC) uses the same formula to calculate gas stations’ markups. See, for instance, the 2015 special report on the Spanish retail petroleum products market—Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia (2015). A similar weighted average of the relative importance of Genoa and Rotterdam prices (66.1% the former, 33.9% the latter) was employed by Rodrigues (2009) to study asymmetries in the adjustment of pump prices for the Spanish case.

  35. In Appendix C, we include a sensitivity analysis of our main estimations for different distribution cost parameters.

  36. Additional congestion maps are included in Appendix D. See Dirección General de Carreteras (2015) for further information and maps.

  37. We call a point between gas station #1 and gas station #2 a midpoint location.

  38. We have considered the following as “locations based on geographical distances” for an entrant firm: first, the geographical midpoint between town A and gas station #1; second, the geographical midpoint between gas station #1 and gas station #2; and third, the geographical midpoint between gas station #2 and town B.

  39. The results included in this table are preliminary.

  40. It seems also reasonable to consider professional truck drivers as a group of consumers that have a substantially different transportation cost in comparison with “regular” (nonprofessional) drivers. However, gas stations usually have alternative (lower) prices for professional truck drivers (typically settled through bilateral agreements between gas stations and freight companies). Unfortunately, these (lower) prices that gas stations charge to truck drivers are not observable for the econometrician. Therefore, it is not possible for us to perform a separate estimation for this well-differentiated segment of the market.

  41. For instance, following Bjornerstedt and Verboven (2016), one possible extension could be to consider a constant expenditures demand specification. Obviously, this alternative specification is also potentially subject to a similar critique (as they assume that the fraction of the budget spent is constant across all consumers), and it would also require the econometrician to observe individual consumers’ income data.

References

  • An Y, Baye MR, Hu Y, Morgan J, Shum M (2017) Identification and estimation of online price competition with an unknown number of firms. J Appl Econom 32(1):80–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, Goeree JK, Ramer R (1997) Location, location, location. J Econ Theory 77(1):102–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asociación Española de Operadores de Productos Petrolíferos (2015) Memoria 2014. Technical report, AOP

  • Bajari P, Benkard CL (2005) Demand estimation with heterogeneous consumers and unobserved product characteristics: a hedonic approach. J Political Econ 113(6):1239–1276

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bajari P, Benkard CL, Levin J (2007) Estimating dynamic models of imperfect competition. Econometrica 75(5):1331–1370

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bello A, Contín-Pilart I (2012) Taxes, cost and demand shifters as determinants in the regional gasoline price formation process: evidence from Spain. Energy Policy 48:439–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bjornerstedt J, Verboven F (2016) Does merger simulation work? Evidence from the Swedish analgesics market. Am Econ J Appl Econ 8(3):125–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borenstein S, Shepard A (1996) Dynamic pricing in retail gasoline markets. RAND J Econ 27(3):429–451

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caplin A, Nalebuff B (1991) Aggregation and imperfect competition: on the existence of equilibrium. Econometrica 59(1):25–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chandra A, Tappata M (2011) Consumer search and dynamic price dispersion: an application to gasoline markets. RAND J Econ 42(4):681–704

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colwell PF, Dehring CA, Turnbull GK (2002) Recreation demand and residential location. J Urban Econ 51(3):418–428

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Comisión Nacional de los Mercados y la Competencia (2015) Estudio sobre el mercado mayorista de carburantes de automoción en España. Technical Report E/CNMC/002/15, CNMC

  • Contín-Pilart I, Correljé AF, Palacios MB (2009) Competition, regulation, and pricing behaviour in the Spanish retail gasoline market. Energy Policy 37(1):219–228

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont C, Gabszewicz JJ, Thisse J-F (1979) On Hotelling’s “stability in competition”. Econometrica 47(5):1145–1150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • General Dirección, de Carreteras (2015) Mapa de Tráfico, (2015) Technical Report NIPO 161–15-052-3. Centro de Publicaciones, Ministerio de Fomento (España)

  • Doganoglu T (2003) Dynamic price competition with consumption externalities. Netnomics 5(1):43–69

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Egli A (2007) Hotelling’s Beach with linear and quadratic transportation costs: existence of pure strategy equilibria. Aust Econ Papers 46(1):39–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Englin J, Shonkwiler JS (1995) Modeling recreation demand in the presence of unobservable travel costs: toward a travel price model. J Environ Econ Manag 29(3):368–377

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fackler PL, Miranda MJ (2004) Applied computational economics and finance. MIT press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Fan J, Gijbels I (1995) Adaptive order polynomial fitting: bandwidth robustification and bias reduction. J Comput Gr Stat 4:213–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Hong H, Shum M (2006) Using price distributions to estimate search costs. RAND J Econ 37(2):257–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39(153):41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen M, Pichler P, Weidenholzer S (2011) Oligopolistic markets with sequential search and production cost uncertainty. RAND J Econ 42(3):444–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laussel D, de Montmarin M, Van Long N (2004) Dynamic duopoly with congestion effects. Int J Ind Organ 22(5):655–677

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis M (2008) Price dispersion and competition with differentiated sellers. J Ind Econ 56(3):654–678

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manuszak MD, Moul CC (2009) How far for a buck? tax differences and the location of retail gasoline activity in southeast Chicagoland. Rev Econ Stat 91(4):744–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marion J, Muehlegger E (2011) Fuel tax incidence and supply conditions. J Public Econ 95(9):1202–1212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moul CC (2015) Estimating demand for spatially differentiated firms with unobserved quantities and limited price data. Econ Lett 131:50–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neven DJ (1986) On Hotelling’s competition with non-uniform customer distributions. Econ Lett 21(2):121–126

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodrigues J (2009) Asymmetries in the adjustment of motor diesel and gasoline pump prices in Europe. Technical report

  • Shuai J (2017) A comment on mixed oligopoly spatial model: the non-uniform consumer distribution. Econ Theory Bull 5(1):57–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stolper S (2016) Who bears the burden of energy taxes? The role of local pass-through. Discussion Paper 16–70, Harvard Kennedy School

  • Tabuchi T (1994) Two-stage two-dimensional spatial competition between two firms. Reg Sci Urban Econ 24(2):207–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tabuchi T, Thisse J-F (1995) Asymmetric equilibria in spatial competition. Int J Ind Organ 13(2):213–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tappata M (2009) Rockets and feathers: understanding asymmetric pricing. RAND J Econ 40(4):673–687

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomadsen R (2005) The effect of ownership structure on prices in geographically differentiated industries. RAND J Econ 36(4):908–929

    Google Scholar 

  • Torrisi G (2011) The model of the linear city under triangular distribution of consumers. Manag Res Pract 3(2):7–23

    Google Scholar 

  • Verboven F (2002) Quality-based price discrimination and tax incidence: evidence from gasoline and diesel cars. RAND J Econ 33(2):275–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang Z (2009) (Mixed) strategy in oligopoly pricing: evidence from gasoline price cycles before and under a timing regulation. J Political Econ 117(6):987–1030

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wildenbeest MR (2011) An empirical model of search with vertically differentiated products. RAND J Econ 42(4):729–757

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Raúl Bajo-Buenestado.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

I acknowledge helpful comments and suggestions by Marcus Berliant, Dodge Cahan, Gilles Duranton, Hülya Eraslan, Nicholas Frazier, Peter Hartley, Jeffrey Lin, Kenneth Medlock, Shaun McRae, Xun Tang, and two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at the X EGSC Conference at Washington University in St. Louis and at the XXX Spanish Economic Association meeting. Thanks also to María García, who kindly helped me with the data. I gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Social Sciences Research Institute at Rice University and Fundación Ramón Areces (Grant Number CISP16A4779). The remaining errors are solely mine. The dataset and the MATLAB and R codes are available upon request from the author.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 2420 KB)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bajo-Buenestado, R. Market prices, spatial distribution of consumers and firms’ optimal locations in a linear city. Empir Econ 61, 443–467 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01871-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-020-01871-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation