Skip to main content
Log in

On the pernicious effects of oil price uncertainty on US real economic activities

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The last five decades have witnessed dramatic changes in crude oil price dynamics. We identify the influence of extreme oil shocks and changing oil price uncertainty dynamics associated with economic and political events. Neglecting these features of the data can lead to model misspecification that gives rise to: firstly, an explosive volatility process for oil price uncertainty, and secondly, erroneous output growth dynamic responses to oil shocks. Unlike past studies, our results show that the sharp increase in oil price uncertainty after mid-1985 has a pernicious effect on output growth. There is evidence that output growth responds symmetrically (asymmetrically) to positive and negative shocks in the period when oil price uncertainty is lower (higher) and more (less) persistent before (after) mid-1985. These results highlight the importance of accounting for outliers and volatility breaks in oil price and output growth and the need to better understand the response of economic activity to oil shocks in the presence of oil price uncertainty. Our results remain qualitatively unchanged with the use of real oil price.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Baumeister and Peersman (2013) use a time-varying-parameter VAR model to demonstrate that changes in the crude oil market have been gradual. While their model specification permit inference on the gradual dynamic of change in the price elasticity of oil supply and demand, we do not impose this structure to our model given that our basis of comparison is the model of Elder and Serletis (2009, 2010, 2011). Be that as it may, the application of the variance break test is able to detect whether there has been a change in the volatility process of oil price change partly explained by this gradual change in the price elasticity of oil supply and demand.

  2. The proxy for uncertainty which is measured by the conditional variance of oil prices is subject to certain caveats. This proxy measures the dispersion in the forecast error produced by the econometric model estimated using historical data, and it therefore may not capture other forward-looking components of uncertainty other than the one parameterised in the model. Nevertheless, the use of autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity-based measures of uncertainty is widespread in the empirical literature for modelling output growth uncertainty (Grier et al. 2004; Chua et al. 2011), inflation uncertainty (Engle 1982; Elder 2004), and oil price uncertainty (Elder and Serletis 2009, 2010).

  3. Recently, Rodrigues and Rubia (2011) have studied the size properties of Sansó et al.’s (2004) ICSS algorithm for detecting structural breaks in variance under the hypothesis of additive outliers. Their results indicate that neglected outliers tend to bias the ICSS test. They advise applying the modified ICSS algorithm on outlier-adjusted return series to identify sudden shifts in volatility.

  4. Elder and Serletis (2010) undertook a robustness analysis post-1986, but this was for the purpose of addressing the effect of the 1986 Tax Reform Act on investment. Specifically, following the sharp drop in oil prices in 1986 the decline in real GDP growth rate was primarily due to declines in private nonresidential investment expenditures. The fall in private nonresidential investment expenditures can be attributed to provisions in TRA86 such as the repeal of the investment tax credit and the elimination of some real estate tax shelters.

  5. Rahman and Serletis (2012) study the effects of oil price uncertainty on the Canadian economy using a multivariate conditional variance specification that does not impose this assumption.

  6. One damaging aspect of the tax reform is its application of the alternative minimum tax (AMT) to the main tax mechanisms for drilling cost and capital recovery, which comprise current year expensing of intangible drilling costs and the remnants of percentage depletion. In theory, producers can recover AMT tax payments through credits when and if they become so profitable that their regular income tax exceeds AMT tax. However, most producers are not that profitable. To the extent they cannot recover AMT payments, and lost opportunity costs associated with them, producers pay taxes on drilling capital.

  7. The test of Laurent et al. (2016) is similar to the non-parametric tests for jumps proposed by Lee and Mykland (2008) and Andersen et al. (2007) for low-frequency data.

  8. The critical values are defined by \(g_{T,\lambda }=-\log \left( -\log (1-\lambda )\right) b_{T}+c_{T}\), with \(b_{T}=1/\sqrt{2\log T}\), and \( c_{T}=(2\log T)^{1/2}-[\log \pi +\log (\log T)]/[2(2\log T)^{1/2}]\). Laurent et al. (2016) suggest setting \(\lambda =0.5\)

References

  • Andersen TG, Bollerslev T, Dobrev D (2007) No arbitrage semi-martingale restrictions for continous-time volatility models subject to leverage effects, jumps and i.i.d. noise: theory and testable distributional implications. J Econ 138:125–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Baffes J, Kose M, Ohnsorge F, Stocker M (2015) The great plunge in oil prices: causes, consequences, and policy responses. Policy Research Note No 15/01, World Bank Group

  • Barsky RB, Kilian L (2004) Oil and the macroeconomy since the 1970s. J Econ Perspect 18:115–134

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumeister C, Peersman G (2013) The role of time-varying price elasticities in accounting for volatility changes in the crude oil market. J Appl Econ 28:1087–1109

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke B (1983) Irreversibility, uncertainty and cyclical investment. Quart J Econ 98:85–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Gali J (2010) The macroeconomic effects of oil price shocks: why are the 2000s so different from the 1970s? In: Gal J, Gertler M (eds) International dimensions of monetary policy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 373–421

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudt K, Danielsson J, Laurent S (2013) Robust forecasting of dynamic conditional correlation GARCH Models. Int J Forecast 29:244–257

    Google Scholar 

  • Box G, Tiao G (1975) Intervention analysis with applications to economic and environmental problems. J Am Stat Assoc 70:70–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Bredin D, Elder J, Fountas S (2011) Oil volatility and the option value of waiting: An analysis of the G-7. J Futures Mark 31:679–702

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan M, Schwartz E (1985) Evaluating natural resource investment. J Bus 58:1135–1157

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan M (1990) Latent assets. J Finance 45:709–730

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrion-i-Silvestre JL, Kim D, Perron P (2009) GLS-based unit root tests with multiple structural breaks both under the null and the alternative hypotheses. Econ Theory 25:1754–1792

    Google Scholar 

  • Charles A, Darné O (2014) Volatility persistence in crude oil markets. Energy Policy 65:729–742

    Google Scholar 

  • Chua C, Kim D, Suardi S (2011) Are empirical measures of macroeconomic uncertainty alike? J Econ Surv 25:801–827

    Google Scholar 

  • Diebold F (1986) Modeling the persistence of conditional variances: a comment. Econ Rev 5:51–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Edelstein P, Kilian P (2009) How sensitive are consumer expenditures to retail energy prices? J Monet Econ 56:766–779

    Google Scholar 

  • Elder J (2003) An impulse-response function for a vector autoregression with multivariate GARCH-in-mean. Econ Lett 79:21–26

    Google Scholar 

  • Elder J (2004) Another perspective on the effects of inflation volatility. J Money Credit Bank 36:911–928

    Google Scholar 

  • Elder J, Serletis A (2009) Oil price uncertainty in Canada. Energy Econ 31:852–856

    Google Scholar 

  • Elder J, Serletis A (2010) Oil price uncertainty. J Money Credit Bank 42:1137–1159

    Google Scholar 

  • Elder J, Serletis A (2011) Volatility in oil prices and manufacturing activity: an investigation on real options. Macroecon Dyn 15:379–395

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliott G, Rothenberg TJ, Stock JH (1996) Efficient tests for an autoregressive unit root. Econometrica 64:813–836

    Google Scholar 

  • Engle RF (1982) Autoregressive conditional heteroscedasticity with estimates of the variance of United Kingdom inflation. Econom 50:987–1007

    Google Scholar 

  • Grier K, Henry O, Olekalns N, Shield K (2004) The asymmetric effects of uncertainty on inflation and output growth. J Appl Econ 19:551–565

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JD (1983) Oil and the macroeconomy since World-War-II. J Polit Econ 91:228–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton JD (2008) Macroeconomics and ARCH. Working Paper No. 14151. NBER

  • Hamilton JD (2013) Historical oil shocks. In: Parker RE, Whaples R (eds) Handbook of major events in economic history. Taylor and Francis Group, Routledge, pp 239–265

  • Hillebrand E (2005) Neglecting parameter changes in GARCH models. J Econom 129:121–138

    Google Scholar 

  • Inclan C, Tiao GC (1994) Use of cumulative sums of squares for retrospective detection of changes of variance. J Am Stat Assoc 89:913–923

    Google Scholar 

  • Kilian L (2009) Not all oil price shocks are alike: disentangling demand and supply shocks in the cude oil market. Am Econ Rev 99:1053–69

    Google Scholar 

  • Kilian L, Vigfusson RJ (2011) Are the responses of the US economy asymmetric in energy price increases and decreases? Quant Econ 2:419–453

    Google Scholar 

  • Koop G, Pesaran MH, Potter SM (1996) Impulse response analysis in nonlinear multivariate models. J Econ 74:119–147

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamoureux C, Lastrapes W (1990) Persistence in variance, structural change and the GARCH model. J Bus Econ Stat 8:225–234

    Google Scholar 

  • Laurent S, Lecourt C, Palm FC (2016) Testing for jumps in GARCH models, a robust approach. Comput Stat Data Anal 100:383–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee J, Strazicich MC (2001) Break point estimation and spurious rejections with endogenous unit root tests. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 63:535–558

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee SS, Mykland PA (2008) Jumps in financial markets: a new nonparametric test and jump dynamics. Rev Financ Stud 21:2535–2563

    Google Scholar 

  • Majd S, Pindyck R (1987) Time to build, option value and investment decisions. J Financ Econ 18:7–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Mikosch T, Starica C (2004) Nonstationarities in financial time series, the long-range dependence, and the IGARCH effect. Rev Econ Stat 86:378–390

    Google Scholar 

  • Muler N, Peña D, Yohai V (2009) Robust estimation for ARMA models. Ann Stat 37:816–840

    Google Scholar 

  • Muler N, Yohai V (2008) Robust estimates for GARCH models. J Stat Plan Inference 138:2918–2940

    Google Scholar 

  • Newey W, West K (1994) Automatic lag selection in covariance matrix estimation. Rev Econ Stud 61:631–653

    Google Scholar 

  • Ng S, Perron P (2001) Lag length selection and the construction of unit root tests with good size and power. Econometrica 69:1519–1554

    Google Scholar 

  • Perron P (1989) The great crash, the oil price shock and the unit root hypothesis. Econometrica 57:1361–1401

    Google Scholar 

  • Perron P, Qu Z (2007) A simple modification to improve the finite sample properties of Ng and Perron’s unit root tests. Econ Lett 94:12–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Pindyck R (1991) Irreversibility, uncertainty and investment. J Econ Lit 29:110–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Rahman S, Serletis A (2012) Oil price uncertainty and the Canadian economy: evidence from a VARMA, GARCH-in-Mean, asymmetric BEKK model. Energy Econ 34:603–610

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrigues P, Rubia A (2011) The effects of additive outliers and measurement errors when testing for structural breaks in variance. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 73:449–468

    Google Scholar 

  • Sansó A, Aragó V, Carrion-i-Silvestre J (2004) Testing for changes in the unconditional variance of financial time series. Revista de Economía Financiera 4:32–53

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock J, Watson M (2012) Disentagling the channels of the 2007–2009 Recession. Working Paper No. 18094, NBER

  • Zivot E, Andrews DWK (1992) Further evidence on the great crash, the oil price shock and the unit root hypothesis. J Bus Econ Stat 10:251–270

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors gratefully acknowledge the two referees, Associate Editor and the Editor for their constructive comments, which have improved the quality of the paper. Any remaining errors are our own. Amélie Charles and Olivier Darné gratefully acknowledge financial support from the Région des Pays de la Loire (France) through the Grant PANORisk.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Olivier Darné.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Impulse response function

To study the response of endogenous variables to the impact of a unit or standard deviation shock in the VAR system we use the impulse response function. Elder (2003) provides an analytical representation of the impulse responses in a VAR model with GARCH-in-Mean. The impulse response function captures the time profile of the effect of a shock on the \(m-\)th variable, \( m\in \{1,2\},\) at time t, being \(e_{mt}\), on the expected value of \( y_{v,t+n}\) where \(n\ge 0\). Note that in the case of our model, \(m=1\) denotes \(\mathrm{IPI}\) while \(m=2\) denotes \(\mathrm{Oil}\). Mathematically, we write the impulse response function of \(y_{v,t+n}\) at horizon n given information up to \(\mathcal {F}_{t-1}\) as:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E(y_{v,t+n}|e_{m,t},\mathcal {F}_{t-1})}{\partial e_{m,t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(5)

The impulse response for \(y_{v,t+n}\) stemming from a shock \(e_{m,t}\) takes the following analytical expression

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial E(y_{v,t+n}|e_{m,t},\mathcal {F}_{t-1})}{\partial e_{m,t}}= & {} \left( \Theta _{n}A^{-1}\right) _{\{v,m\}}+\sum _{i=0}^{n-1}\left( \Theta _{i}A^{-1}\Lambda \left( A_{2}+A_{3}\right) ^{n-i-1}A_{2}\right) _{\{v,:\}}\left( \Upsilon _{1}+\Upsilon _{0}\right) \nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(6)

where \(\Upsilon _{1}\) is an \(4\times 1\) vector such that its \(\left( 2(m-1)+m\right) \)th row contains \(2e_{mt}\) and zeros elsewhere, and \( \Upsilon _{0}\) is an \(4\times 1\) vector such that its \(\left( \left( j-1\right) 2+i\right) \)th row and its \(\left( 2\left( i-1\right) +1+(j-1\right) \)th row contain \(e_{jt}\) for \(i,j=1,2\) and \(i\ne j\). The subscripts \(\{v,m\}\) indicate elements in the vth row and mth column of a matrix and \(\{v,:\}\) indicates the vth row vector. Here, \(\Xi _{i}\) and \(\Theta _{i}\) are sub-matrices of \(\Omega _{i}^{*}\) where \(\Omega _{i}^{*}=\) \(\left[ \begin{array}{cc} \widetilde{\Xi }_{i} &{} \widetilde{\Theta }_{i} \\ \Xi _{i} &{} \Theta _{i} \end{array} \right] \) and is a product of \(\Omega _{1}\) and \(\Omega _{i-1}^{*}\) with \( \Omega _{0}^{*}=I_{3}\) and \(\Omega _{s}^{*}=0\) for \(s<0\). Note also that \(\Omega (L)=I-\left[ \begin{array}{cc} \Phi (L) &{} \Psi ^{*}(L) \\ 0 &{} A^{-1}\Gamma (L) \end{array} \right] \) where \(\Psi ^{*}\) is an null matrix. It is important to highlight that the coefficient estimates of the GARCH process \(h_{\mathrm{Oil},t}\) given by \(\hat{a}_{22}^{2}+\hat{a}_{22}^{3}\) need to be strictly less than unity to ensure that the effect of oil shock on output growth will dissipate over time. In this regard, it is important that any outliers and regime changes in the underlying oil price volatility are identified and accounted for appropriately to ensure that the GARCH parameter estimates are not biased towards an integrated or even an explosive GARCH process. An evaluation of the response of output growth to oil price shocks critically relies on unbiased parameter estimates of the model.

Appendix B: Detecting additive outliers

There are methods for detecting outliers in GARCH-type models based on interventional analysis approach which was first put forward by Box and Tiao (1975). We apply the semi-parametric procedure to detect additive outliers proposed by Laurent et al. (LLP) (2016).Footnote 7 They assume that the returns \(r_{t}\) are described by the ARMA(p,q)-GARCH(1,1) model, which is defined in Eqs. (7)–(9).

Consider the return series with an independent outlier component \(a_{t}I_{t}\) , defined as

$$\begin{aligned} r_{t}^{*}=r_{t}+a_{t}I_{t} \end{aligned}$$
(7)

where \(r_{t}^{*}\) denotes observed returns, \(I_{t}\) is a dummy variable taking the value 1 in the case of an additive outlier on day t and 0 otherwise while \(a_{t}\) is the outlier size. The model for \( r_{t}^{*}\) has the properties that an additive outlier \(a_{t}I_{t}\) will not affect \(\sigma _{t+1}^{2}\) (the conditional variance of \(r_{t+1}\)), and it allows for non-Gaussian fat-tailed conditional distributions of \( r_{t}^{*}\). LLP then use the bounded innovation propagation (BIP)-ARMA model proposed by Muler et al. (2009) and the BIP-GARCH(1,1) model proposed by Muler and Yohai (2008) to obtain robust estimations of \(\mu _{t}\) and \(\sigma _{t}^{2}\), respectively. These are shown in Eqs. (7)–(9) as \(\widetilde{\mu }_{t}\) and \( \widetilde{\sigma }_{t}\), respectively and that they are robust to potential presence of additive outliers \(a_{t}I_{t}\). In other words, the model is estimated based on \(r_{t}^{*}\) and not on \(r_{t}\). The BIP-ARMA and BIP-GARCH(1,1) are defined as

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{\mu }_{t}= & {} \mu +\sum _{i=1}^{\infty }\xi _{i}\widetilde{\sigma } _{t-i}\omega _{k_{\Delta }}^{MPY}(\widetilde{J}_{t-i}) \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{\sigma }_{t}^{2}= & {} \omega +\alpha _{1}\widetilde{\sigma } _{t-1}^{2}c_{\Delta }\omega _{k_{\Delta }}^{MPY}\left( \widetilde{J} _{t-1}\right) ^{2}+\beta _{1}\widetilde{\sigma }_{t-1}^{2}, \end{aligned}$$
(9)

respectively where \(\xi _{i}\) are the coefficients of the AR(p ) and MA(q) polynomials defined in Eq. (8), \(\omega _{k_{\Delta }}^{MPY}(.)\) is the weight function, and \(c_{\Delta }\) a factor which ensures that the conditional expectation of the weighted squared unexpected shocks is the conditional variance of \(r_{t}\) in the absence of outliers (Boudt et al. 2013).

Consider the standardised return on day t, which is given by

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{J}_{t}=\frac{r_{t}^{*}-\widetilde{\mu }_{t}}{\widetilde{ \sigma }_{t}}. \end{aligned}$$
(10)

To detect the presence of additive outliers they test the null hypothesis \(H_{0}:a_{t}I_{t}=0\) against the alternative \(\hbox {H} _{1}:a_{t}I_{t}\ne 0\). The null is rejected if

$$\begin{aligned} \max _{T}|\widetilde{J}_{t}|>g_{T,\lambda },\quad t=1,\ldots ,T \end{aligned}$$
(11)

where \(g_{T,\lambda }\) is the suitable critical value.Footnote 8 If \(H_{0}\) is rejected, a dummy variable is defined as follows

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{I}_{t}=I\left( |\widetilde{J}_{t}|>k\right) \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where I(.) is the indicator function, with \(\widetilde{I}_{t}=1\) when an additive outlier is detected at time t and 0 otherwise. LLP show that their test does not suffer from size distortions irrespective of the parameter values of the GARCH model from Monte Carlo simulations. The filtered returns or adjusted data are obtained as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \widetilde{r}_{t}=r_{t}^{*}-(r_{t}^{*}-\widetilde{\mu }_{t}) \widetilde{I}_{t}. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

Appendix C: Detecting variance changes

Having identified and adjusted the data for possible additive outliers, we apply the CUSUM-type test of Sansó et al. (2004) to the series \(\Delta \mathrm{IPI}_{t}\) and \(\Delta \mathrm{Oil}_{t}\). The test is based on the iterative cumulative sum of squares (ICSS) algorithm developed by Inclan and Tiao (1994). This algorithm makes it possible to detect multiple breakpoints in variance.

Define \(\tilde{y}_{t}\) as the mean-adjusted series for \(y_{t}\) so that it has a mean of zero for \(y_{t}=\{\Delta \mathrm{IPI}_{t},\Delta \mathrm{Oil}_{t}\}\). Further assume that \(\{\tilde{y}_{t}\}\) is a series of independent observations from a normal distribution with zero mean and unconditional variance \(\sigma _{t}^{2}\) for \(t=1,\ldots ,T\). We know from the data summary statistics that both \(\Delta \mathrm{IPI}_{t}\) and \(\Delta \mathrm{Oil}_{t}\) display serial dependence/correlation (see Sect. 3) and that the violation of the independence property of the series will cause serious size distortions to the ICSS test statistic (Sansó et al. 2004). Sansó et al. (2004), therefore, propose a test that explicitly takes into consideration the fourth moment properties of \(\tilde{y }_{t}\) and the conditional heteroskedasticity. The non-parametric adjustment to the test statistic allows for \(\tilde{y}_{t}\) to obey a wide class of dependent processes under the null hypothesis. This is discussed below.

Assume that the variance within each interval is denoted by \(\sigma _{j}^{2}\) for \(j=0,1,\ldots ,N_{T}\) where \(N_{T}\) is the total number of variance changes with \(1<\kappa _{1}<\kappa _{2}<\cdots<\kappa _{N_{T}}<T\) being the set of breakpoints. Accordingly, the variances over the \(N_{T}\) intervals are defined as:

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{t}^{2}=\left\{ \begin{array}{c} \sigma _{0}^{2}, \quad 1<t<\kappa _{1} \\ \sigma _{1}^{2}, \quad \kappa _{1}<t<\kappa _{2} \\ \cdots \\ \sigma _{N_{T}}^{2},\quad \kappa _{N_{T}}<t<T \end{array} \right. \end{aligned}$$
(14)

The cumulative sum of the squared observations, \(C_{k},\) is used to estimate the number of variance changes and to identify the point in time when the variance shifts such that \(C_{k}=\sum _{t=1}^{k}\) \(\tilde{y}_{t}^{2}\) for \(k=1,\ldots ,T\). Sansó et al. (2004) propose the adjusted test statistic – non-parametric adjustment based on the Bartlett kernel—given by:

$$\begin{aligned} AIT=\sup _{k}\left| (T/2)^{0.5}G_{k}\right| \end{aligned}$$
(15)

where \(G_{k}=\hat{\lambda }^{-0.5}\left[ C_{k}-\left( \frac{k}{T}\right) C_{T} \right] \) and \(\hat{\lambda }=\hat{\gamma }_{0}+2\sum _{l=1}^{m}\left[ 1-l(m+1)^{-1}\right] \hat{\gamma }_{l}\).

Here, \(\hat{\gamma }_{l}=T^{-1}\sum _{t=l+1}^{T}\left( \tilde{y}_{t}^{2}-\hat{\sigma }^{2}\right) \left( \tilde{y}_{t-l}^{2}-\hat{\sigma }^{2}\right) \) and \(\hat{\sigma }^{2}=T^{-1}C_{T}\), with \(C_{T}=\) \( \sum _{t=1}^{T}\) \(\tilde{y}_{t}^{2}\). The lag truncation parameter m is selected using the Newey and West (1994) procedure. Under general conditions, the asymptotic distribution of AIT is also given by \( \sup _{r}\left| W^{*}(r)\right| \) and the finite sample critical values are obtained from simulation.

Appendix D: The Carrion-Kim-Perron (CKP) test

Carrion-i-Silvestre et al. (2009) propose a testing procedure which allows for multiple structural breaks in the level and/or slope of the trend function under both the null and alternative hypotheses. The model is given by

$$\begin{aligned} y_{t}= & {} d_{t}+u_{t},\quad t=1,\ldots ,T, \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned} u_{t}= & {} \alpha u_{t-1}+v_{t},\quad t=2,\ldots ,T,\quad u_{1}=v_{1} \end{aligned}$$
(17)

with \(d_t\) denotes the deterministic component given by

$$\begin{aligned} d_t = z_t^{\prime }(T_0^{0})\psi _0 + z_t^{\prime }(T_1^{0})\psi _1 + \cdots + z_t^{\prime }(T_m^{0})\psi _m \equiv z_t^{\prime 0})\psi \end{aligned}$$
(18)

where \(z_t(T_0^{0})=(1,t)^{\prime }\), \(\psi _0=(\mu _0,\beta _0)^{ \prime })\), and \(z_t(T_j^{0})=\left( DU_t(T_j^{0}),DT_t(T_j^{0})\right) ^{\prime }\) for \(1\le j \le m\), with m is the number of breaks. \(DU_{t}(T_j^{0})=1\) and \(DT_t(T_j^{0})=(t-T_j^{0})\) for \(t>T_j^{0}\) and 0 elsewhere, with \(T_j^{0}=[T\lambda _j^0]\) is the jthe break date, with [.] the integer part and \(\lambda _j^0\equiv T_j^{0}/T \in (0,1)\) the break fraction parameter.

Carrion-i-Silvestre et al. (2009) consider extensions of the M class of unit root tests analysed in Ng and Perron (2001) and the feasible point optimal statistic of Elliott et al. (1996). The GLS-detrended unit root test statistics are based on using the quasi-differenced variable \(y_{t}{\bar{ \alpha }}=(1-\bar{\alpha }L)y_{t}\) and \(z_{t}{\bar{\alpha }}(\lambda ^{0})=(1- \bar{\alpha }L)z_{t}(\lambda ^{0})\) for \(t=2,\ldots ,T\), with \(\bar{\alpha }=1+ \bar{c}/T\) and \(\bar{c}=-13.2\) when \(z_{t}(T_{0}^{0})=(1,t)^{\prime }\). The feasible point optimal statistic is given by

$$\begin{aligned} P_{T}^{\mathrm{GLS}}(\lambda ^{0})=\left\{ S\left( \bar{\alpha },\lambda ^{0}\right) - \bar{\alpha }S\left( 1,\lambda ^{0}\right) \right\} /s^{2}(\lambda ^{0}) \end{aligned}$$

where \(S \left( \bar{\alpha },\lambda ^0\right) \) is the minimum of the following sum of squared residuals from the quasi-differenced regression \(S \left( \psi ,\bar{\alpha },\lambda ^0\right) =\sum _{t=1}^T \left( y_t{\bar{ \alpha }} - \psi ^{\prime }y_t{\bar{z}}(\lambda ^0) \right) ^2\), and \( s^2(\lambda ^0)\) is an estimate of the spectral density at frequency zero of \( v_t\) defined by

$$\begin{aligned} s^2(\lambda ^0) = s^2_{ek} / \left( 1-\sum _{j=1}^{k}\hat{b}_j \right) ^2 \end{aligned}$$
(19)

where \(s^2_{ek}=(T-k)^{-1}\sum _{t=k+1}^{T}\hat{e}_{t,k}^2\) and \(\{ \hat{b}_j,\hat{e}_{t,k}\}\) are obtained from the following OLS regression

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta \tilde{y}_t = b_0\tilde{y}_{t-1} + \sum _{j=1}^k b_j\tilde{y}_{t-j} + e_{t,k} \end{aligned}$$
(20)

with \(\tilde{y}_t=y_t \hat{\psi }'z_t(\lambda ^0)\), where \( \hat{\psi }\) minimises \(S \left( \psi ,\bar{\alpha },\lambda ^0\right) \). The lag order k is selected using the modified information criteria suggested by Ng and Perron (2001) with the modification proposed by Perron and Qu (2007).

The M-class of tests are defined by

$$\begin{aligned} MZ_{\alpha }^{\mathrm{GLS}}(\lambda ^{0})= & {} \left( T^{-1}\tilde{y}_{T}^{2}-s(\lambda ^{0})^{2}\right) \left( 2T^{-1}\sum _{t=1}^{T}\tilde{y}_{t-1}^{2}\right) ^{-1} \end{aligned}$$
(21)
$$\begin{aligned} MZ_{t}^{\mathrm{GLS}}(\lambda ^{0})= & {} \left( T^{-1}\tilde{y}_{T}^{2}-s(\lambda ^{0})^{2}\right) \left( 4s(\lambda ^{0})^{2}T^{-2}\sum _{t=1}^{T}\tilde{y} _{t-1}^{2}\right) ^{-1/2} \end{aligned}$$
(22)
$$\begin{aligned} MP_{T}^{\mathrm{GLS}}(\lambda ^{0})= & {} \left[ \bar{c}^{2}T^{-2}\sum _{t=1}^{T}\tilde{y} _{t-1}^{2}+(1-\bar{c}T^{-1}\tilde{y}_{T}^{2}\right] /s(\lambda ^{0})^{2} \end{aligned}$$
(23)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Charles, A., Chua, C.L., Darné, O. et al. On the pernicious effects of oil price uncertainty on US real economic activities. Empir Econ 59, 2689–2715 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01801-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-019-01801-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation