Skip to main content
Log in

Inflation targeting and exchange rate volatility in emerging markets

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper investigates the exchange rate on the reaction function of 24 emerging markets economies’ (EMEs) central banks from 2000Q1 to 2015Q2. This is done by first employing fixed-effects (FE) ordinary least squares and then system generalized methods of the moments techniques. Under FE, the exchange rate is important in the reaction function of EMEs. Allowing for the endogeneity of inflation, output gap, and the exchange rate, the exchange rate remains positive and statistically significant (but quantitatively less) across inflation targeting countries. When the sample is partitioned into targeting and non-targeting countries, the exchange rate remains relevant in the reaction function of non-targeters. The results remain robust to splitting the sample at the time of the financial crisis of 2007–2009 and suggest that, after the crisis, central banks of EMEs respond only to inflation movements in the interest rate reaction function.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Recent analysis by Ahmed et al. (2017), for example, finds evidence that differences in economic fundamentals played a role in explaining the heterogeneous EME financial market responses during the global financial crisis of 2008, and that the role of fundamentals appeared to progressively increase through the European crisis in 2011 and subsequently in the so-called taper-tantrum episode of 2013 triggered by the US monetary policy.

  2. Modifying the model to nominal interest rates and foreign exchange reserves, Calvo and Reinhart (2002) have values ranging from zero (there is a peg or a very high degree of commitment to IT) to one when “seignorage” has a high weight in the policymaker’s objective function.

  3. By the ex-ante uncovered interest parity (UIP) condition in international finance, higher-yielding currencies are expected to depreciate against the (foreign) lower paying counterpart. In practice, however, this condition is often violated. Flood and Rose (2002) investigate this for a period of turbulence in financial markets and conclude that UIP performs relatively better during the crisis of the 1990s than other times. Frankel and Poonawala (2010) confirm that the UIP condition is not observed (ex-post) in emerging markets, although the rejection is not as severe as in industrial countries.

  4. Exchange rates may lead to inflationary effects, which forms an empirical matter of its own. Nogueira and León-Ledesma (2009), for example, use monthly data from 1995M1 to 2007M12 for Brazil and estimate inflation as a function of its past, real output growth, changes in nominal exchange rates, and changes in the price of foreign imports. They find that, after the policy change and adoption of IT in 1999M1 long-run exchange rate pass-through declined dramatically. Under the peg, exchange rate changes are more fully transmitted to prices. Also, under a credible IT nominal shocks are expected to have only limited effects on inflation.

  5. In Aizenman et al. (2011), real GDP growth was relatively close across samples: 1.11 versus 1%. However, their figures were similar to ours on monetary policy: Inflation targeters show lower average inflation (5.40%) relative to the non-inflation targeters (9.60%) and the group of targeters present lower nominal interest rates (8.98%) than their counterparts (12.68%). Therefore, in addition to slower economic growth for ITers in our sample, the rate of change of exchange rates is much lower for ITers on average: 0.28 versus 0.73%.

  6. For a general comparison of monetary policy rules in emerging markets, please refer to Mehrotra and Sánchez-Fung (2011). Canuto and Cavallari (2013) discuss whether central banks should incorporate indicators of financial stability into the reaction function. While one may associate asset prices with home and equity markets, private sector credit could indicate as well the extent of bank lending to the private sector. We might also consider alternative factors to the exchange rate such as private credit, money growth and other financial conditions.

  7. In a previous version, we also reported “static SGMM”, which referred to as inflation and exchange rata variations as endogenous but without the lagged interest rate. We later considered output gap also as endogenous in the more general SGMM. In the current version, and to minimize confusion as implied by a comment from an anonymous referee, we include the lagged interest rate in all versions of SGMM. In both previous and current versions, all estimations of SGMM are performed under the xtabond2 command in STATA as in Roodman (2009b).

  8. For dynamic panel data models, second-order serial correlation test is most important together with testing of instrument validity. The standard reference on specification tests for dynamic panel data model is Arellano and Bond (1991), who develop three such tests: a direct test on the second-order residual serial correlation coefficient [originally named m2, commonly referred to as AB(2) more recently], a Sargan test of over-identifying restrictions and a Hausman specification test. Their conclusions were that “the robust m2 statistics perform satisfactorily as do the two-step Sargan and difference—Sargan test, but the two-step Hausman test must be considered suspect in samples of this size.” Arellano and Bond (1991, p. 293). The influential article by Roodman (2009a) on instrument count for SGMM reports AB(2), together with Hansen and difference Sargan tests for the validity of instruments, but no AB(1) tests. Recent applied research with SGMM tends to report AB(2) together with Hansen’s J, but some also report AB(1) tests with mixed results. For example, for real exchange rates and productivity growth Caglayan and Demir (2014) usually report p values of 0 for AB(1) but those changes with alternative variables in the model with p values close to 0.10 or even 0.20 in some specifications. Gopalan and Rajan (2016) compare their findings on foreign aid for water supply and find no serial correlation of orders 1 and 2 for SGMM estimators but do find some serial correlation of order 1 for DGMM estimators. Rather than focusing on AB(1), the key consideration for the correct model specification is its stability, such as the lagged dependent variable coefficient being less than 1 and statistically significant, as well as satisfactory serial correlation tests of order 2 and some instrument validity tests as originally proposed by Arellano and Bond (1991) and revisited by Roodman (2009a).

  9. The caveat for the subsample of ITers with only 9 countries in columns (4)–(6) of Table 4 is that some serial correlation shows up at around the 5% significance level.

References

  • Agénor P-R, da Silva LAP (2013) Rethinking inflation targeting: a perspective from the developing world. University of Manchester, Centre for Growth and Business Cycle Research, Economic Studies, Discussion Paper Series, Number 185, July 2013

  • Ahmed S, Coulibaly B, Zlate A (2017) International financial spillovers to emerging market economies: how important are economic fundamentals? J Int Money Finance 76:133–152

    Google Scholar 

  • Airaudo M, Buffie E, Zanna LF (2016) Inflation targeting and exchange rate management in less developed countries. IMF Working Paper WP/16/55

  • Aizenman J, Hutchison M, Noy I (2011) Inflation targeting and real exchange rates in emerging markets. World Dev 39(5):712–724

    Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis P, Chortareas G, Magkonis G, Moschos D (2014) Inflation targeting and inflation convergence: international evidence. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 31:285–295

    Google Scholar 

  • Baharumshah AZ, Slesman L, Wohar M (2016) Inflation, inflation uncertainty and economic growth in emerging and developing countries: panel data evidence. Econ Syst 40:638–657

    Google Scholar 

  • Ball L, Sheridan N (2005) Does inflation targeting matter? In: Debate TIT (ed) NBER studies in business cycles 32. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Batini N, Laxton D (2007) Under what conditions can inflation targeting be adopted? The experience of inflation targeting in emerging markets. In: Mishkin F, Schmidt-Hebbel K (eds) Monetary policy under inflation targeting. Central Bank of Chile, Santiago

    Google Scholar 

  • Berganza JC, Broto C (2012) Flexible inflation targets, Forex interventions and exchange rate volatility in emerging countries. J Int Money Finance 31:428–444

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke B (2003) A perspective on inflation targeting. The Federal Reserve Board, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Brito RD, Bystedt B (2010) Inflation targeting in emerging economies: panel evidence. J Dev Econ 91(2):198–210

    Google Scholar 

  • Cabral R (2010) Why dollarization didn’t succeed: comparing credibility and the impact of real shocks on small open economies. North Am J Econ Finance 21(3):297–313

    Google Scholar 

  • Caglayan M, Demir F (2014) Firm productivity, exchange rate movements, sources of finance, and export orientation. World Dev 54:204–219

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo G, Reinhart C (2002) Fear of floating. Q J Econ 117(2):379–408

    Google Scholar 

  • Canuto O, Cavallari M (2013) Monetary policy and macroprudential regulation: whither emerging markets. The World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper 6310

  • Civcir I, Akcaglayan A (2010) Inflation targeting and the exchange rate: does it matter in Turkey? J Policy Model 32:339–354

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarida R, Galí J, Gertler M (2001) Optimal monetary policy in open versus closed economies: an integrated approach. Am Econ Rev 91(2):248–252

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis SJ, Kahn JA (2008) Interpreting the great moderation: changes in the volatility of economic activity at the macro and micro levels. J Econ Perspect 22(4):155–180

    Google Scholar 

  • de Mendonça HF, Tibert BP (2017) Effect of credibility and exchange-rate pass-through on inflation: an assessment for developing countries. Int Rev Econ Finance 50:196–244

    Google Scholar 

  • Ding H, Kim J (2017) Inflation targeting and real interest rate parity: a bias corrected approach. Econ Model 60:132–137

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards S (2006) The relationship between exchange rates and inflation targeting revisited. NBER Working Paper No. 12163, April

  • Eichengreen B, Masson P, Savastano M, Sharma S (1999) Transition strategies and nominal anchors on the road to greater exchange-rate flexibility. In: Essays in international economics, N. 213. International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University, Princeton

  • Flood R, Rose A (2002) Uncovered interest parity in crisis. IMF Staff Pap 49(2):252–266

    Google Scholar 

  • Fouejieu A (2017) Inflation targeting and financial stability in emerging markets. Econ Model 60:51–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraga A, Goldfajn I, Minella A (2003) Inflation targeting in emerging market economies. NBER Working Paper No. 10019

    Google Scholar 

  • Frankel J, Poonawala J (2010) The forward market in emerging currencies: less biased than in major currencies. J Int Money Finance 29:585–598

    Google Scholar 

  • Garcia CJ, Restrepo JE, Roger S (2011) How much should inflation targeters care about the exchange rate? J Int Money Finance 30(7):1590–1617

    Google Scholar 

  • Gopalan S, Rajan R (2016) Has foreign aid been effective in the water supply and sanitation sector? Evidence from panel data. World Dev 85:84–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Gozgor G (2014) Determinants of domestic credit levels in emerging markets: the role of external factors. Emerg Mark Rev 18:1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Hove S, Tchana FT, Mama AT (2017) Do monetary, fiscal and financial institutions really matter for inflation targeting in emerging market economies? Res Int Bus Finance 39:128–149

    Google Scholar 

  • Ismailov S, Kakinaka M, Miyamoto H (2016) Choice of inflation targeting: some international evidence. N Am J Econ Finance 36:350–369

    Google Scholar 

  • Lane P, Milesi-Ferretti GM (2007) The external wealth of nations mark II: revised and extended estimates of foreign assets and liabilities. J Int Econ 73:223–250

    Google Scholar 

  • Laurens B, Eckhold K, King D, Maehle N, Naseer A, Durré A (2015) The journey to inflation targeting: easier said than done. The case for transitional arrangements along the road. IMF Working Paper WP/15/136, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

  • Leitemo K, Söderström U (2005) Simple monetary policy rules and exchange rate uncertainty. J Int Money Finance 24(3):481–507

    Google Scholar 

  • Loayza N, Soto R (2002) Inflation targeting: design, performance, challenges. Central Bank of Chile, Santiago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehrotra A, Sánchez-Fung JR (2011) Assessing McCallum and Taylor rules in a cross-section of emerging market economies. J Int Financ Mark Inst Money 21(2):207–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishkin F (2004) Can inflation targeting work in emerging market countries? NBER Working Paper 10646

  • Mishkin F, Schmidt-Hebbel K (2007a) Does inflation targeting make a difference? NBER Working Paper No. 12876

  • Mishkin F, Schmidt-Hebbel K (2007b) Monetary policy under inflation targeting. Central Bank of Chile, Santiago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mollick AV, René C, Carneiro FG (2008) Does inflation targeting matter for output growth? Evidence from industrial and emerging economies. World Bank Working Policy Paper (WP # 4791), December of 2008

  • Mollick AV, Cabral R, Carneiro FG (2011) Does inflation targeting matter for output growth? Evidence from industrial and emerging economies. J Policy Model 33:537–551

    Google Scholar 

  • Moura M, de Carvalho A (2010) What can Taylor rules say about monetary policy in Latin America? J Macroecon 32:392–404

    Google Scholar 

  • Nogueira R, León-Ledesma M (2009) Fear of floating in Brazil: did inflation targeting matter? N Am J Econ Finance 20:255–266

    Google Scholar 

  • Oudiz G, Sachs J (1984) Macroeconomic policy coordination among the industrial economies. Brook Pap Econ Act 1:1–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouyang A, Rajan R, Li J (2016) Exchange rate regimes and real exchange rate volatility: does inflation targeting help or hurt? Japan World Econ 39:62–72

    Google Scholar 

  • Pavasuthipaisit R (2010) Should inflation-targeting central banks respond to exchange rate movements? J Int Money Finance 29(3):460–485

    Google Scholar 

  • Poon WC, Lee YS (2014) Inflation Targeting in ASEAN-10. S Afr J Econ 82(1):141–157

    Google Scholar 

  • Roger S (2009) Inflation targeting at 20: achievements and challenges. IMF Working Paper No. 09/236

  • Roodman D (2009a) A note on the theme of too many instruments. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 71(1):135–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodman D (2009b) How to do xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata J 9(1):86–136

    Google Scholar 

  • Rossi B (2013) Exchange rate predictability. J Econ Lit 51(4):1063–1119

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (1985) International coordination in the design of macroeconomic policy rules. Eur Econ Rev 28:53–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (2001) The role of the exchange rate in monetary policy rules. Am Econ Rev 91(2):263–267

    Google Scholar 

  • Taylor JB (2013) International monetary coordination and the great deviation. J Policy Model 35:463–472

    Google Scholar 

  • Wollmershäuser T (2006) Should central banks react to exchange rate movements? An analysis of the robustness of simple policy rules under exchange rate uncertainty. J Macroecon 28(3):493–519

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2014) Risk and opportunity: managing risk for development. World Development Report 2014, The World Bank, Washington, DC

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Francisco G. Carneiro.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

Francisco Carneiro, Rene Cabral, and Andre Mollick declare that they do not have any conflict of interest.

Ethical approval

This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cabral, R., Carneiro, F.G. & Mollick, A.V. Inflation targeting and exchange rate volatility in emerging markets. Empir Econ 58, 605–626 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1478-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1478-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation