Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Consumption and credit constraints: a model and evidence from Ireland

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

After the onset of the financial crisis, consumption fell in many economies. This paper presents a small-scale DSGE model with occasionally binding credit constraints. Indebted households start facing credit constraints when the value of their main asset, housing, declines. As a response, they stop smoothing consumption and start deleveraging. Even households that only expect to face a credit constraint in the future deleverage. Using the Irish Household Budget Survey, we show that most Irish households continued to smooth consumption during the crisis. However, for highly indebted consumption smoothing is disrupted during the crisis. Households with leverage close to but below the standard loan-to-value ratio of 85% also seem to smooth consumption less than normal households. This is rational if they expect a further house price decline and therefore anticipate the need to deleverage in the near future. We interpret these results as evidence of credit constraints that arise from falling property prices.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This number is derived from real personal consumption expenditure from the FRED database and from average population growth in the 1930 s from the 1940 US Census.

  2. In a column on VoxEu, Gerlach-Kristen et al. (2013) present results on consumption decisions based on both micro- and aggregate data.

  3. The Household Finance and Consumption Network conducts a harmonised household survey across the euro area that is also compatible with the US Federal Reserve’s Survey of Consumer Finances. For a detailed description of data and results, see Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network (2009, 2013). Irish data were collected only in the second wave 2013. For analyses of these data, see Lawless et al. (2015) and Staunton (2015).

  4. See O’Connell et al. (2013) for a comparison of real per capita consumption before and during the financial crisis in the Eurozone. Studies on Irish household consumption include Hogan and O’Sullivan (2007), Lydon and O’Hanlon (2012) and Gerlach-Kristen (2013, 2014).

  5. For an empirical analysis on Irish data over the period 1960–1991, see Roche (1995).

  6. Mankiw and Shapiro (1985) criticise the validity of some of these procedures for testing the PIH. For instance, they show that, if income has a unit root, the analysis in Flavin (1981) is biased towards rejection. Nelson (1987) finds evidence supporting the PIH.

  7. Barakova et al. (2014) use data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth to assess the impact of borrowing constraints and house price dynamics on the probability of homeownership during the US housing market boom between 2003 and 2007.

  8. In the earlier literature, some authors (Campbell and Mankiw 1990; Roche 1995) also assume that there are two types of consumers: a constant proportion of households is forward-looking optimising households and consumes their permanent income, while the remaining population consumes their current disposable income. Alternatively, Flavin (1985) proposes a specification of the consumption function that includes the unemployment rate, which is assumed to be a proxy for the proportion of liquidity-constrained households.

  9. This approach is also chosen by Mayer and Gareis (2013), who present a DSGE model for Ireland.

  10. Justiniano et al. (2015) model an occasionally binding borrowing constraint so as to reproduce the asymmetry of mortgage contract and the downward stickiness of mortgage debt observed in 2006–2007 US data. Benigno et al. (2009) analyse optimal monetary policy rules for “crisis” periods when the borrowing constraints bind and for “normal” periods when the borrowing constraint is slack. They conclude that optimal policy is nonlinear. For more details on methodological aspects and a comparison of alternative parameterised expectation algorithms, we refer the reader to Christiano and Fisher (2000).

  11. To solve the model, we employ a piecewise linear solution technique developed by Guerrieri and Iacoviello (2015a) and available online (https://www2.bc.edu/matteo-iacoviello).

  12. The dynamics in our model hold under more general conditions than in Mendoza (2010), where the amplification channel and asymmetric response are driven by an external finance risk premium and the debt deflation effect.

  13. In models assuming an ever-binding constraint, Eq. (3) holds with equality and Eq. (3a) is never invoked. We present an impulse response based on a model with an ever-binding constraint in Fig. 4.

  14. Normally, in the literature β is set equal to 0.9925, implying a steady-state real interest rate of 3% on an annual basis. We set the discount factor equal to 0.965, which means that households are more impatient. This value has a limited effect on the model dynamics, but guarantees an impatience motive large enough that the impatient agents are arbitrarily close to the borrowing limit. For the US economy, Iacoviello and Neri (2010) set this value for impatient households equal to 0.97, hence very close to our calibration.

  15. We acknowledge that, ideally, our model would assume that the borrowing constraint is not binding in the steady state, since it would be more intuitive to assume that households are not constrained in “normal” times. However, this is a shortcoming common to the literature on occasionally binding constraints. Besides Guerrieri and Iacoviello (2015b), see also Brzoza-Brzezina et al. (2015) and Benigno et al. (2009).

  16. The introduction of habit in consumption to modern DSGE models was initially proposed by Christiano et al. (2005). It causes that model is able to generate hump-shaped response of consumption to various shocks, as observed in the data.

  17. We have calibrated χ so that it matches the coefficient on the proxy for the lagged dependent variable—the 5-year-lagged consumption—that we estimate in Sect. 5. Clancy and Merola (2017) develop a DSGE model for Ireland, and they set χ = 0.8, close to the upper value of the interval [0.5, 0.9]. Our results are robust and results remain valid for alternative values of consumption persistence.

  18. In Ireland in 2013 the average mortgage debt service to income ratio was 15.8. Concerning credit constraints, the share of constrained households was 18.4%. However, aggregate data may not accurately assess the risk exposure and the vulnerability of households. When we look at micro-data and individual characteristics, the situation may be different. The share of constrained households rises up to 31% for young households under 35 and up to 42.1% for single-parent families (Staunton 2015).

  19. All simulations are run in Dynare 4.3.3 (Adjemian et al. 2011), using the OccBin Toolkit developed by Guerrieri and Iacoviello (2015a).

  20. A recent and growing literature investigates the implications of using loan-to-value ratios to contain boom-bust cycles in credit and housing prices (e.g. Christensen and Meh 2011; Angelini et al. 2011; Lambertini et al. 2013).

  21. Using a county-level dataset, Mian and Sufi (2010b) and Mian et al. (2013) find that in those US counties that experienced a large increase in household leverage during the boom (2002–2005), consumption dropped more dramatically during the first phase of the recession (2007:Q3–2008:Q4) than in other counties.

  22. For Italy, this result might be explained by some peculiarities of the Italian credit market. Due to the existence of strong imperfections, households prefer to save in a precautionary manner or to rely on "informal networks" (i.e. help from parents or friends), rather than rely on credit markets.

  23. See Engelhardt (1996) for the USA and Berben et al. (2007) for the Netherlands. Kim and Chung (2016) find that house price decreases have a larger impact on movements in US macro-indicators (and consequently on US business cycle) than house price increases.

  24. Similarly, in a small open-economy DSGE model with occasionally binding collateral constraints, Benigno et al. (2012) find that government should intervene aggressively by subsidising the consumption of non-tradable goods in periods of stress, when the borrowing constraint is binding. In “normal” times, it is not optimal to intervene before the constraint actually binds.

  25. Income and consumption are reported for the household as a whole, not broken down by individual.

  26. The HBS reports expenditure, not consumption. This means that a household’s consumption jumps up if for instance a new car is bought. The consumption utility derived from the services of the car is not recorded in the data.

  27. For the economy as a whole, the savings rate computed from gross national disposable income and personal savings before stock appreciation is 4.2% in 1995, − 0.5% in 2000, 2.9% in 2005 and 3.8% in 2010..

  28. J-tests for the exogeneity of these instruments with respect to consumption do not reject by a wide margin.

  29. Kennedy and McIndoe-Calder (2012) report a somewhat lower average loan-to-value ratio between 50 and 80% for the years before the crisis.

  30. For the regressions in Sect. 5, we have run robustness tests by varying the leverage at origination from 75 to 100%. None of the main results changed. Results are available upon request.

  31. Kennedy and McIndoe-Calder (2012) report that most Irish mortgages are flexible-rate contracts. Nevertheless, since the speed of amortisation primarily depends on maturity, our measure of outstanding debt at the time of the HBS interview should be roughly accurate.

  32. We also tried including mortgage payments. This additional variable was significant only at the 5% level and did not change the main results. We also performed robustness checks that include housing expenditure in consumption, and the results are robust to this change in definition. Excluding all non-mortgage households does not change the main findings, either. Results are available upon request.

  33. The referee pointed out that high-consumption households might tend to have high leverage at origination. We hope to account for general consumption habits with the household-specific demographic and employment data. If there is spurious reverse causality left in our estimation set-up, this would bias the coefficients on leverage upwards. This in turn would imply that we underestimate the negative impact of credit constraints on consumption.

  34. Using leverage in logs and excluding non-mortgage households does not change the main findings. Results are available upon request.

  35. The referee has pointed out that we might underestimate leverage because of top-up loans. If so, \( \hat{\beta }^{L} \) is biased upwards, and in truth, the PIH would be rejected even more strongly.

  36. It is interesting to note that a Wald test for the equality of the income elasticities of households with medium and high leverage does not reject the null hypothesis (p value of 0.66). Precautionary deleveraging thus seems to have been as strong as that caused by actual credit constraints. This probably is one factor explaining why Irish consumption declined so sharply in the crisis.

  37. This time series starts in 1999. We therefore drop those mortgage households that moved to their current residence before that data. This means that of sample shrinks by 10%.

References

  • Adjemian S, Bastani H, Karamé F, Juillard M, Maih J, Mihoubi F, Perendia G, Pfeifer J, Ratto M, Villemot S (2011) Dynare: reference manual version 4. Dynare working papers 1, CEPREMAP

  • Agarwal S, Liu C, Souleles N (2007) The reaction of consumer spending and debt to tax rebates-evidence from consumer credit data. J Polit Econ 115(6):986–1019

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alessie R, Devereux M, Weber G (1997) International consumption, durables and liquidity constraints: a cohort analysis. Eur Econ Rev 41:37–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Almeida H, Campello M, Liu C (2006) The financial accelerator: evidence from international housing markets. Rev Finance 10:321–352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelini P, Neri S, Panetta F (2011) Monetary and macroprudential policies. Temi di discussione (Economic working papers) 801, Bank of Italy, Economic Research and International Relations Area

  • Arellano C, Mendoza E (2002) Credit frictions and ‘sudden stops’ in small open economies: an equilibrium business cycle framework for emerging markets crises. NBER working paper 8880

  • Attanasio O, Pavoni N (2011) Risk sharing in private information models with asset accumulation: explaining the excess smoothness of consumption. Econometrica 79:1027–1068

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bank of International Settlements (2001) 71st annual report, June 2001, Basel

  • Barakova I, Calem P, Wachter S (2014) Borrowing constraints during the housing bubble. J Hous Econ 24(c):4–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaudry P, Portier F (2006) Stock prices, news, and economic fluctuations. Am Econ Rev 96(4):1293–1307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaudry P, Portier F (2014) News-driven business cycles: insights and challenges. J Econ Lit 52(4):993–1074

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benigno G, Chen H, Otrok C, Rebucci A, Young E (2012) Optimal policy with occasionally binding constraints. CEP discussion paper 1172

  • Berben RP, Bernoth K, Mastrogiacomo M (2007) Households’ response to wealth changes: do gains or losses make a difference? In: Bank for International Settlements (ed), Proceedings of the IFC conference on “measuring the financial position of the household sector”, Basel, 30–31 Aug 2006

  • Beznoska M, Ochmann R (2012) Liquidity constraints and the permanent income hypothesis. DIW discussion paper 1231

  • Beznoska M, Ochmann R (2013) The interest elasticity of household savings: a structural approach with German micro data. Empir Econ 45(1):371–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Preston I (2008) Consumption inequality and partial insurance. Am Econ Rev 98(5):1887–1921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Saporta-Eksten I (2016) Consumption inequality and family labour supply. Am Econ Rev 106(2):387–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brzoza-Brzezina M, Kolasa M, Krzysztof M (2015) A penalty function approach to occasionally binding credit constraints. Econ Model 51(c):317–327

    Google Scholar 

  • Callan T, Nolan B, Keane C, Savage M, Walsh JR (2014) Crisis, response and distributional impact: the case of Ireland. IZA J Eur Labor Stud 3(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J, Deaton A (1989) Why is consumption so smooth? Rev Econ Stud 56(3):357–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J, Mankiw G (1990) Permanent income, current income, and consumption. J Bus Econ Stat 8(3):265–279

    Google Scholar 

  • Carroll CD (1992) The buffer-stock theory of saving: some macroeconomic evidence. Brook Pap Econ Act 2:61–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll CD, Kimball MS (2001) Liquidity constraints and precautionary saving. NBER working paper 8496

  • Carroll CD, Toche P (2009) A tractable model of buffer stock saving. NBER working paper 15265

  • Casado GarcÍa JM (2011) From income to consumption: measuring households partial insurance. Empir Econ 40(2):471–495

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Central Statistics Office (2013) Quarterly National Household Survey: effect on households of the economic downturn

  • Christensen I, Meh C (2011) Countercyclical loan-to-value-ratios and monetary policy. Bank of Canada Mimeo, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Christiano LJ, Fisher JDM (2000) Algorithms for solving dynamic models with occasionally binding constrain. J Econ Dyn Control 24(8):1179–1232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano LJ, Eichenbaum M, Evans C (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. J Polit Econ 113:1–45

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clancy D, Merola R (2017) Countercyclical capital rules for small open economies. J Macroecon 54:332–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cogan JF, Cwik T, Taylor JB, Wieland V (2010) New Keynesian versus old Keynesian government spending multipliers. J Econ Dyn Control 34(3):281–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1991) Saving and liquidity constraints. Econometrica 59(5):1221–1248

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deidda M (2014) Precautionary saving under liquidity constraints: evidence from Italy. Empir Econ 46(1):329–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffy D, O’Hanlon N (2013) Negative equity in the Irish housing market: estimates using loan level data. ESRI working paper 463

  • Engelhardt GV (1996) House prices and home owner saving behavior. Reg Sci Urban Econ 26(3/4):313–336

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erceg C, Guerrieri L, Gust C (2006) SIGMA: a new open economy model for policy analysis. Int J Cent Bank 2(1):1–50

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2009) Housing wealth and private consumption in the euro area. Monthly Bulletin, Jan 2009

  • Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network (2009) Survey data on household finance and consumption: research summary and policy use. European central bank occasional paper series no. 100

  • Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network (2013) The eurosystem household finance and consumption survey: the results from the first wave. European Central Bank statistic paper series no. 2

  • Flavin M (1981) The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income. J Polit Econ 89(5):974–1009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flavin M (1985) Excess sensitivity of consumption to current income: liquidity constraints or myopia? Can J Econ 18(1):117–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1957) A theory of the consumption function. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gerlach-Kristen P (2013) The effect of unemployment, arrears and negative equity on consumption: Ireland in 2009/10. ESRI working paper 457

  • Gerlach-Kristen P (2014) Testing the permanent income hypothesis for Irish households, 1994 to 2005. Econ Soc Rev 45(4):511–535

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerlach-Kristen P, Merola R, O’Toole C (2013) Consumption and credit constraint during financial crises. VoxEu, 1 Dec 2013

  • Gomes S, Jacquinot P, Pisani M (2012) The EAGLE. A model for policy analysis of macroeconomic interdependence in the euro area. Econ Model 29(5):1686–1714

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodhart C, Hofmann B (2007) House prices and the macroeconomy: implications for banking and price stability. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri L, Iacoviello M (2015a) OccBin: a toolkit for solving dynamic models with occasionally binding constraints easily. Journal of Monetary Economics 70(C):22–38

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guerrieri L, Iacoviello M (2015b) Collateral constraints and macroeconomic asymmetries. National Bank of Poland working papers 202

  • Guerrieri V, Lorenzoni G (2011) Credit crises, precautionary savings and the liquidity trap. NBER working paper 17583

  • Hall RE (1978) Stochastic implications of the life cycle-permanent income hypothesis: theory and evidence. J Polit Econ 86:971–987

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi F (1982) The permanent income hypothesis: estimation and testing by instrumental variables. J Polit Econ 90:895–916

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hogan V, O’Sullivan P (2007) Consumption and house prices in Ireland. ESRI Quarterly Economic Commentary, Sept

  • Honohan P (2009) Resolving Ireland’s banking crises. Paper prepared for the UCD-Dublin economic workshop conference: “responding to the crisis”, Dublin, 12 Jan 2009

  • Iacoviello M (2005) House prices, borrowing constraints, and monetary policy in the business cycle. Am Econ Rev 95(3):739–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iacoviello M, Neri S (2010) Housing market spillovers: evidence from an estimated DSGE model. Am Econ J Macroecon 2(2):125–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2000) World Economic Outlook, May 2000, Washington D.C

  • Jaimovich N, Rebelo S (2009) Can news about the future drive the business cycle? Am Econ Rev 99(4):1097–1118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jappelli T (1990) Who is credit constrained in the U.S. economy? Q J Econ 105(1):219–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jappelli T, Pistaferri L (2010) The consumption response to income changes. Ann Rev Econ 2(1):479–506

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jappelli T, Pistaferri L (2014) Fiscal policy and MPC heterogeneity. Am Econ J Macroecon 6(4):107–136

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson D, Parker J, Souleles N (2006) Household expenditure and the income tax rebates of 2001. Am Econ Rev 96(5):1589–1610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordà O, Schularick M, Taylor AM (2013) When credit bites back. J Money Credit Bank 45(S2):3–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jordà O, Schularick M, Taylor AM (2015) Leveraged bubbles. J Monet Econ 76(S):S1–S20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Justiniano A, Primiceri G, Tambalotti A (2015) Household leveraging and deleveraging. Rev Econ Dyn 18(1):3–20

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy G, McIndoe-Calder T (2012) The Irish mortgage market: stylised facts, negative equity and arrears. Quarterly Bulletin 01, Central Bank of Ireland

  • Kim JR, Chung K (2016) The role of house price in the US business cycle. Empir Econ 51(1):71–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger D, Perri F (2011) How do households respond to income shocks? 2009 Meeting paper 14, society for economic dynamics

  • Krueger D, Perri F, Pistaferri L, Violante G (2010) Cross sectional facts for macroeconomists. Rev Econ Dyn 13(1):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumhof M, Laxton D, Muir D, Mursula S (2010) The global integrated monetary and fiscal model: theoretical structure. IMF working paper WP/10/34

  • Lalonde R, Muir D (2007) The Bank of Canada’s version of the global economy model (BoC-GEM). Bank of Canada technical report no. 98

  • Lambertini L, Mendicino C, Punzi MT (2013) Leaning against boom-bust cycles in credit and housing prices. J Econ Dyn Control 37(8):1500–1522

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawless M, Lydon R, McIndoe-Calder T (2015) The financial position of Irish households. Quarterly Bulletin 01, Central Bank of Ireland

  • Leland HE (1968) Saving and uncertainty: the precautionary demand for saving. Q J Econ 82(3):465–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lorenzoni G (2009) A theory of demand shocks. Am Econ Rev 99(5):2050–2084

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lydon R, O’Hanlon N (2012) Housing equity withdrawal, property bubbles and consumption. Central Bank of Ireland research technical paper 05/RT/12

  • Mankiw NG, Shapiro MD (1985) Trends, random walks and tests of the permanent income hypothesis. J Monet Econ 16:165–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer E, Gareis J (2013) What drives Ireland’s housing market? A Bayesian DSGE approach. Open Econ Rev 24:919–961

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCarthy Y, McQuinn K (2013) Price expectations, distressed mortgage markets and the housing wealth effect. Central Bank of Ireland research technical papers 06/RT/13

  • Mendoza EG (2010) Sudden stops, financial crises, and leverage. Am Econ Rev 100(5):1941–1966

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG, Smith K (2006) Quantitative implications of a debt-deflation theory of Sudden Stops and asset prices. J Int Econ 70(1):82–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian A, Sufi A (2010a) The Great Recession: lessons from microeconomic data. Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 100:51–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian A, Sufi A (2010b) Household leverage and the recession of 2007–09. IMF Econ Rev 58:74–117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mian A, Sufi A (2014) House of debt: how they (and you) caused the Great Recession and how we can prevent it from happening again. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mian A, Rao K, Sufi A (2013) Household balance sheets, consumption and the economic slump. Q J Econ 128(4):1687–1726

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miles D, Pillonca V (2008) Financial innovation and European housing and mortgage markets. Oxford Rev Econ Policy 24(1):145–175

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson CR (1987) A reappraisal of recent tests of the permanent income hypothesis. J Polit Econ 95:641–646

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connell B, O’Toole C, Znuderl N (2013) Trends in consumption since the crisis. ESRI Quarterly Economic Commentary, Jan

  • Ratto M, Roeger W, In ‘t Velt J (2009) QUEST III: an estimated open-economy DSGE model of the euro area with fiscal and monetary policy. Econ Model 26(1):222–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roche MJ (1995) Testing the permanent income hypothesis: the Irish evidence. Econ Soc Rev 26(3):283–305

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitt-Grohe S, Uribe M (2012) What’s news in business cycles. Econometrica 80:2733–2764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Souleles N (2002) Consumer response to the Reagan tax cuts. J Public Econ 85:99–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staunton C (2015) The distribution of wealth in Ireland, TASC

  • Tobin J, Dolde W (1971) Wealth, liquidity, consumption. In: Consumer spending and monetary policy: the linkages. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rossana Merola.

Additional information

The work was conducted when both the authors were staff members at the ESRI and the Trinity College in Dublin. The authors thank the Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network (HFCN), Alan Barrett, Tim Callan, David Duffy, Stefan Gerlach, Matteo Iacoviello, Conor O’Toole, Margarita Rubio and seminar participants at the Deutsche Bundesbank, the Dutch National Bank, the ESRI, the National University of Ireland Maynooth, the Nottingham University and the UECE Conference in Lisbon for useful comments and suggestions. The authors are also indebted to Claire Burke and Brian O’Connell for help with the data and to Robert Kunst, an anonymous reviewer and an associate editor for their careful reading of the manuscript and their many insightful comments and suggestions. The authors, however, are responsible for any remaining errors. This paper is based on data from the Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network, and the responsibility for all conclusions drawn from the data lies entirely with the authors. The views presented in this paper are the authors’ and do not necessarily represent those of the Swiss National Bank, the International Labour Organization and the Eurosystem Household Finance and Consumption Network.

Appendices

Appendix A: computation of permanent income and lagged consumption

Table 4 shows proxies for permanent real income by household tenancy, education and age. We compute this measure as the average over time (i.e. over HBS waves) of the average income within each population group. Mortgage owners, more educated households and middle-aged households tend to have the highest permanent incomes.

Table 4 Proxies for permanent income by age, tenancy and education level

Table 5 presents proxies for lagged consumption by household tenancy, education and age. These are used as a proxy for the lagged dependent variable in Eqs. (12) and (13). It can be seen that consumption in 2004/2005, at the height of the boom, was much above the permanent income proxy.

Table 5 Proxies for lagged consumption by age, tenancy and education level

Appendix B: computation of household leverage ratios

Here, we discuss how we compute the proxy for the leverage ratio of mortgage households. There are four main assumptions underlying this measure.

First, we assume a loan-to-value ratio of 85% at origination, so that the mortgage corresponds to 85% of the value of the property the household purchases. Thus, dorigination = LTVp horigination . We assume for simplicity that after the down-payment for the mortgage, the household does not have any assets but the house.

Second, we assume that the house value moves in unison with the general house price index presented in Fig. 6 in the main text.Footnote 37 We use the house price index in the quarter in which the interview was conducted and we denote it by p h t . For each household, we know how many years ago it last moved, though there is no information on quarters. We therefore assume that the move was exactly the number of years ago the household indicates, with no additional quarters. The general house price index at that point in time gives us the value at origination p horigination .

Third, we assume a fixed-rate mortgage contract with a maturity T of 28 years. The monthly payments made are constant over time and combine the interest payment, which declines as the remaining principal decreases, and an amortisation payment, which correspondingly rises over time. As there are no data available on mortgage rates at origination, we use the average mortgage rate in the quarter of the house purchase and denote it by mrate. We calculate the monthly payment as

$$ {\text{Monthly payment}} = \frac{{d_{\text{origination}} }}{{1 - {{\left[ {\frac{1}{{\left( {1 + mrate} \right)^{12T} }}} \right]} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left[ {\frac{1}{{\left( {1 + m{\text{rate}}} \right)^{12T} }}} \right]} {m{\text{rate}}}}} \right. \kern-0pt} {mrate}}}}. $$

Fourth, we assume that each household only has one mortgage, so that the number of real-estate properties per household is \( h_{t} = 1 \).

Based on these assumptions, we compute the leverage ratio in the quarter of the HBS interview as

$$ \frac{{d_{t} }}{{p_{t}^{h} }} = {\text{lev}}_{t} {=} \frac{{d_{\text{origination}} - \sum {\text{monthly payment}}}}{{p_{t}^{h} }} = \frac{{{\text{LTV}}p_{\text{origination}}^{h} - \sum {\text{monthly payment}}}}{{p_{t}^{h} }}, $$

where we denote as \( \sum {\text{monthly payment}} \) the sum of the payments made since the origination of the mortgage.

To illustrate the calculation of the leverage ratio, let us consider the following example. A household bought its residence in 1999 at a price of 100, using a mortgage of 85. It is interviewed in the third quarter of 2009. Due to mortgage payments, its debt has by that time fallen to 66. At the same time, the general house price index has increased by 67%, so that the house price has moved from 100 to 167. Correspondingly, the leverage ratio is calculated as 66/167 = 39%. This is the number in the bottom-left cell in Table 6. If this household is interviewed a quarter later, in 2009Q4, its leverage ratio increases to 44% because of the rapidly falling house prices and in spite of the additional mortgage payments made.

Table 6 Proxies for leverage ratios used in Sect. 5

The size of these numbers appears plausible. Lawless et al. (2015) report loan-to-value ratios by age group using Irish data from the second wave of the European Household Finance and Consumption network. These data refer to 2013 and show that households in their thirties typically had a leverage ratio above 100%. This number is smaller for older households, who bought at lower prices and had more time to amortise their debt. For households in their forties leverage was around 60%.

Table 7 shows which households were particularly likely to be highly leveraged. It can be seen that the younger the mortgage household, the more likely it is to be highly leveraged. There is also weak evidence that more highly educated households, small households, those with few children, those in rural areas and those unemployed are more indebted.

Table 7 Determinants of a high leverage ratio

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Gerlach-Kristen, P., Merola, R. Consumption and credit constraints: a model and evidence from Ireland. Empir Econ 57, 475–503 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1461-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-018-1461-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation