Skip to main content
Log in

Forecast combination when outcomes are difficult to predict

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We show that when outcomes are difficult to forecast in the sense that forecast errors have a large common component that (a) optimal weights are not affected by this common component, and may well be far from equal to each other but (b) the relative mean square error loss from averaging over optimal combination can be small. Hence, researchers could well estimate combining weights that indicate that correlations could be exploited for better forecasts only to find that the difference in terms of loss is negligible. The results then provide an additional explanation for the commonly encountered practical situation of the averaging of forecasts being difficult to improve upon.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a book length exposition of these methods as well as the basic forecast combination problem, see Elliott and Timmermann (2016).

  2. Alternatively, we could consider that forecasters do in fact observe the relevant information but have forecasts that differ from each other as they add in an additional random error. This would leave the following mathematical results unchanged, although it is perhaps a less defendable story for the differences amongst forecasts.

  3. This was verified visually. Because forecast errors from this method display large forecast errors before this period, these errors are very influential observations in the regressions used to construct the weights.

  4. Whilst not formally justified here, it is expected that this approximation is likely to be reasonable. First, so long as the optimal weights are not the average weights, the two combined forecast models will not have a degenerate spectral density at frequency zero (so issues of nested models do not arise). Second, we have used the same loss function (squared loss) in the forecast combination as the evaluation.

References

  • Alquist R, Kilian L (2010) What do we learn from the price of crude oil futures. J Appl Econom 25:539–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bates JM, Granger CWJ (1969) The combination of forecasts. Oper Res Q 20:451–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemen RT (1989) Combining forecasts: a review and annotated bibliography. Int J Forecast 5:559–581

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements MP, Hendry DF (2004) Pooling of forecasts. Econom J 7:1–31

  • Dana J, Dawes RM (2004) The superiority of alternatives to regression for social science predictions. J Educ Behav Stat 29(3):317–331

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies A, Lahiri K (1995) A new framework for analyzing survey forecasts using three-dimensional panel data. J Econom 68(1):205–227

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diebold FX, Mariano RS (1995) Comparing predictive accuracy. J Bus Econ Stat 20(1):134–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elliott G (2010) Averaging and the optimal combination of forecasts (unpublished manuscript)

  • Elliott G, Timmermann A (2016) Economic forecasting. Princeton Unversity Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Faust J, Wright JH (2013) Forecasting inflation. Handb Econ Forecast 2(Part A):3–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger CWJ, Ramanathan R (1984) Improved methods of combining forecasts. J Forecast 3:197–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ito T (1990) Foreign exchange rate expectations: micro survey data. Am Econ Rev 80:434–439

    Google Scholar 

  • Lahiri K, Yang L (2015) A non-linear forecast combination procedure for binary outcomes, CESinfo Working paper No 5175

  • Lahiri K, Peng H, Zhao Y (2013) Machine learning and forecast combination in incomplete panels. Unpublished Manuscript, University of Albany, SUNY

  • Lahiri K, Peng H, Zhao Y (2015) Testing the value of probability forecasts for calibrated combining. Int J Forecast 31:113–129

  • Palm FC, Zellner A (1992) To combine or not to combine? Issues of combining forecasts. J Forecast 11(8):687–701

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Patton AJ, Timmermann A (2012) Forecast rationality tests based on multi-horizon bounds. J Bus Econ Stat 30(1):1–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith J, Wallis KF (2009) A simple explanation of the forecast combination puzzle. Oxf Bull Econ Stat 71(3):331–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson M (2001) A comparison of linear and nonlinear univariate models for forecasting macroeconomic time series. In: Engle RF, White H (eds) Festschrift in honour of Clive Granger. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 1–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Timmermann A (2006) Forecast combinations. In: Elliott Graham, Granger Clive WJ, Timmermann Allan (eds) Handbook of economic forecasting. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 135–196

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Trueman B (1994) Analyst forecasting and herding behavior. Rev Financ Stud 7:97–124

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Graham Elliott.

Appendix

Appendix

Proof

(Proposition 1) We generalize slightly from the proposition, where above \( b=1.\) From matrix inverse laws

$$\begin{aligned} \Sigma ^{-1}= & {} \left( a\iota \iota ^{\prime }+b\tilde{\Sigma }\right) ^{-1}\\= & {} b^{-1}\left( \tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}-\frac{ab^{-1}}{1+ab^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime } \tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )}\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota \iota ^{\prime }\tilde{ \Sigma }^{-1}\right) . \end{aligned}$$

By direct calculation, we have

$$\begin{aligned} \iota ^{\prime }\Sigma ^{-1}\iota =b^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )\left( \frac{1}{1+ab^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )}\right) \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \Sigma ^{-1}\iota =b^{-1}(\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )\left( \frac{1}{ 1+ab^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )}\right) \end{aligned}$$

so

$$\begin{aligned} \omega ^{opt}= & {} (\iota ^{\prime }\Sigma ^{-1}\iota )^{-1}\Sigma ^{-1}\iota \\= & {} \frac{b^{-1}(\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )\left( \frac{1}{1+ab^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )}\right) }{b^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{ \Sigma }^{-1}\iota )\left( \frac{1}{1+ab^{-1}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma } ^{-1}\iota )}\right) } \\= & {} (\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota )^{-1}\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota \end{aligned}$$

yielding the result. \(\square \)

Proof

(Proposition 2). When the optimal weights are equivalent to the averaging weights, i.e. \((\iota ^{\prime }\Sigma \iota )^{-1}\iota ^{\prime }\Sigma =m^{-1}\iota ^{\prime }\), then \(rl=0\) and is independent of \(\sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}.\) If not, we have by taking derivatives with respect to \( \sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}\) that

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial rl}{\partial \sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}}= & {} \frac{1}{\sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}+\left( \iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota \right) ^{-1}}-\frac{\sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}+m^{-2}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma } \iota )}{\left[ \sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}+\left( \iota ^{\prime }\tilde{ \Sigma }^{-1}\iota \right) ^{-1}\right] ^{2}} \\= & {} \frac{\left( \iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota \right) ^{-1}-m^{-2}(\iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }\iota )}{\left[ \sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}+\left( \iota ^{\prime }\tilde{\Sigma }^{-1}\iota \right) ^{-1}\right] ^{2}} \\\le & {} 0 \end{aligned}$$

and the equality sign only holds in the case we are in the situation of (a). \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Elliott, G. Forecast combination when outcomes are difficult to predict. Empir Econ 53, 7–20 (2017). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1253-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-017-1253-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation