Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The long-run effect of foreign direct investment on total factor productivity in developing countries: a panel cointegration analysis

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper examines the long-run effect of the level of foreign direct investment (FDI) on the level of total factor productivity (TFP) for 49 developing countries for the period 1981–2011 using panel cointegration and causality techniques. It is found that (i) FDI has, on average, a negative long-run effect on TFP in developing countries, (ii) long-run causality runs in only one direction, from FDI to TFP, (iii) in the short run, TFP has a negative effect on FDI, and (iv) the long-run effect of FDI of TFP differs between selected groups of countries: While the estimated long-run FDI–TFP coefficients are always relatively large, negative, and significant for countries with lower levels of human capital, financial development, and trade openness, the estimated effects are relatively small, insignificant, or even significantly positive for subgroups of countries with higher levels of human capital, financial development, and trade openness.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Gourinchas and Jeanne (2006) show in a calibrated neoclassical model that the welfare gains from switching from complete financial autarky to perfect capital mobility are negligible compared to the welfare gains from productivity improvements in some countries.

  2. Barro (1999: 135) notes that “[r]ecent theories of endogenous growth allow for a sharper perspective on this residual [TFP]. Specifically, the residual can be clearly interpreted within settings that allow for increasing returns and spillovers or in models in which technological progress is generated by purposeful research. These interpretations provide guidance for explaining the residual in terms of R&D outlays, public policies, and other factors.”

  3. For example, the Monterrey Consensus of the International Conference on Financing for Development notes that “[FDI] is especially important for its potential to transfer knowledge and technology [...]” (UN 2002, p. 9). Similarly, the OECD (2002, p. 95) notes that “many countries view [FDI] as a primary means to acquire technology and knowledge [...].”

  4. The issue of parameter heterogeneity has also been addressed in other studies. Blomström et al. (1994), for example, find that lower-income developing countries do not enjoy substantial growth benefits from FDI, whereas higher-income developing countries do. Nair-Reichert and Weinhold (2001) find in sample of 24 developing countries that FDI has, on average, a positive causal effect on economic growth, but this growth effect is highly heterogeneous. The results by Blonigen and Wang (2005) suggest that FDI affects growth more strongly in less developed countries than in developed countries. Fillat and Wörz (2011) find that the growth effects of FDI are stronger in catching-up economies (such as Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, Spain, and Portugal) than in highly industrialized countries (such as Australia, Germany, Ireland, the UK, and the USA). Finally, the results by Mayer-Foulkes and Nunnenkamp (2009) suggest that FDI contributes to convergence in developed countries, but to divergence in underdeveloped countries.

  5. The literature typically distinguishes three types of FDI. Vertical or efficiency-seeking FDI is driven by international factor price differences. It takes place when a firm fragments its production process internationally, locating each stage of production in the country where it can be done at the lowest cost. Horizontal or market-seeking FDI, in contrast, is motivated by the desire to obtain market access and to avoid trade frictions, such as transport costs and import protection in the host country. The decision to engage in horizontal FDI is guided by the proximity-concentration trade-off in which proximity to the host market avoids trade costs but incurs the added fixed cost of building a second production facility. FDI of this type thus occurs when a firm decides to serve foreign markets through local production, rather than through exports, and hence to produce the same product or service in multiple countries. Finally, resource-seeking FDI occurs when firms identify specific host country locations as an attractive source of natural resources at the lowest cost (see, e.g., Herzer 2011).

  6. Dunning (2003, p. 285), for example, notes that “by far the greater part of FDI in developing countries, notably in the larger and faster growing economies, is directed toward accessing local natural resources and/or national or regional markets.”

  7. Herzer (2012, p. 396) argues that “FDI does not contribute to capital formation [...] if FDI takes the form of mergers and acquisitions, and if the proceeds of the sale of the assets are fully consumed.” However, a large fraction of FDI in developing countries is greenfield investment. Moreover, it is reasonable to assume that the proceeds from the sale of domestic firms are in part invested in the domestic market. UNCTAD (2000, p. 168) therefore argues that “over the longer term, there is no reason to expect any difference in the impacts on capital formation of the two modes of entry.”

  8. It is clear that the aggregate elasticity \(\beta \) in Eq. (4) masks differences across different types of FDI. Although these differences are not the subject of this paper, it should be noted that according to conventional wisdom, market-seeking FDI offers more potential for productivity spillovers than resource-seeking and efficiency-seeking FDI (see, e.g., Beugelsdijk et al. 2008; Farole and Winkler 2012). The key argument underlying this conventional wisdom is that firms engaging in efficiency-seeking FDI have little incentive to create vertical linkages with local firms because foreign affiliate production is intended for the global market. In the case of market-seeking FDI, it is argued that such linkages are more likely to occur because foreign affiliate production is intended for the host country market. However, when foreign affiliates primarily export, as is the case with efficiency-seeking FDI, they do not compete with domestic firms, and therefore, they also do not have an incentive to prevent technology diffusion to domestic firms. Thus, it is theoretically unclear whether horizontal FDI is superior to vertical FDI. Unfortunately, there are no adequate data available to provide meaningful estimates of the effects of market-seeking FDI, efficiency-seeking FDI, and resource-seeking FDI on TFP in developing countries (and such an analysis is also beyond the scope of this paper). We thus leave this question for future research.

  9. Although the Penn World Tables (version 8.1) report data on TFP growth and on relative TFP levels (relative to the USA), this database contains no data on the (absolute) level of TFP.

  10. Because TFP is defined as that part of output that is not directly attributable to factor inputs, Eq. (5) is simply a definition of TFP, not a TFP function. Equation (5) thus does not imply that TFP depends negatively on the amount of inputs used and positively on output. Rather, output depends positively on the amount of inputs used and the level of TFP.

  11. Bosworth and Collins (2003, p. 115) note that “[i]n principle, growth accounts can be constructed to yield estimates of TFP that are independent of the functional form and the parameters of the production process. This requires assuming both a sufficient degree of competition so that factor earnings are proportionate to factor productivities, and the availability of accurate data on factor shares of income.”

  12. The coefficient on the first four years is the return to schooling in sub-Saharan Africa (13.4%). The coefficient on the second four years is the world average return to schooling (10.1%). The coefficient on schooling above eight years is the OECD return to schooling (6.8%). All coefficients are taken from Psacharopoulos (1994).

  13. The classification of developing countries follows that of the IMF, for the years 1992–2011 (IMF 2000, 2014)—more than half of the sample period.

  14. The Hadi (1992) procedure measures the distance of data points from the main body of data and then iteratively reduces the sample to exclude distant data points.

  15. The number in parenthesis denotes the order of integration. The order of integration is the number of times a time series must be differenced to make it stationary. Thus, an I(1) variable must be differenced once to make it stationary, or I(0).

  16. This result necessarily also applies to stationary measurement error (see, e.g., Stock 1987 which occurs when the true variable of interest is cointegrated with the observed proxy). In our case, this means that stationary measurement error in our measure of TFP (and/or FDI activity) should not seriously bias our results. If, in contrast, the measurement error is non-stationary, our cointegration tests should fail to reject the null hypothesis of no cointegration between \(\log ({\textit{TFP}}_{ {it}})\) and \(\log ({\textit{fdi}}_{ {it}})\). The reverse is that if cointegration is found between \(\log ({\textit{TFP}}_{ {it}})\) and \(\log ({\textit{fdi}}_{ {it}})\), then it can be concluded that there is no non-stationary measurement error in \(\log ({\textit{TFP}}_{ {it}})\) and/or \(\log ({\textit{fdi}}_{ {it}})\).

  17. An extension of the panel DOLS estimator is the dynamic seemingly unrelated regression (DSUR) estimator proposed by Mark et al. (2005), which was not included in the simulation study by Wagner and Hlouskova (2010). Unfortunately, the DSUR estimator is seriously biased or not applicable when, as in this study, the number of time periods is small relative to the number of cross-sectional units (see, e.g., Mark et al. 2005; Di Iorio and Fachin 2012).

  18. In the following, we always use demeaned data to account for cross-sectional dependence through common time effects.

  19. The countries and the subsamples are listed in Table 9 in the Appendix. The data used to rank the countries according to their human capital, financial market development, and trade openness levels are averaged over the period 1981–2011.

  20. Findlay (1978, p. 2) argues that domestic firms can only benefit from foreign firms if the technology gap between foreign and domestic firms is not “too wide.” Aghion et al. (2008) present a Schumpeterian growth model explaining why more FDI could have positive growth effects only where local production is relatively close to the technological frontier, whereas growth remains unchanged or is reduced when local firms do not have enough absorptive capacity to benefit from technology spillovers.

References

  • Aghion P, Burgess R, Redding SJ, Zilibotti F (2008) The unequal effects of liberalization: evidence from dismantling the licence Raj in India. Am Econ Rev 98(4):13971412

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alfaro L, Chanda A, Kalemli-Ozcan S, Sayek S (2004) FDI and economic growth: the role of financial markets. J Int Econ 64(1):89–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alfaro L, Kalemli-Ozcan S, Sayek S (2009) FDI, productivity and financial development. World Econ 32(1):111–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balasubramanyam V, Salisu N, Sapsford D (1996) Foreign direct investment and growth in EP and IS countries. Econ J 106(434):92–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltabaev B (2014) FDI and total factor productivity growth: new macro evidence. World Econ 37(2):311–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH, Griffin JM (1997) Pooled estimators versus their heterogeneous counterparts in the context of dynamic demand for gasoline. J Econom 77(2):303–327

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baltagi BH, Moscone F (2010) Health care expenditure and income in the OECD reconsidered: evidence from panel data. Econ Model 27(4):804–811

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1999) Notes on growth accounting. J Econ Growth 4(2):119–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beugelsdijk S, Smeets R, Zwinkels R (2008) The impact of horizontal and vertical FDI on host’s country economic growth. Int Bus Rev 17(4):452–472

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomström M, Lipsey RE, Zejan M (1994) What explains developing country growth? In: Baumol W, Nelson R, Wolff E (eds) Convergence and productivity: cross-national studies and historical evidence. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 243–259

    Google Scholar 

  • Blonigen BA, Wang MG (2005) Inappropriate pooling of wealthy and poor countries in empirical FDI studies. In: Graham EM, Blomström M, Moran TH (eds) Does foreign direct investment promote development?. Institute for International Economics, Washington D.C., pp 221–244

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom DE, Canning D, Sevilla J (2004) The effect of health on economic growth: a production function approach. World Dev 32(1):1–13

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borensztein ER, de Gregorio J, Lee J-W (1998) How does foreign direct investment affect economic growth? J Int Econ 45(1):115–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bosworth B, Collins SM (2003) The empirics of growth: an update. Brookings Pap Eco Act 34(2):113–206

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bwalya SM (2006) Foreign direct investment and technology spillovers: evidence from panel data analysis of manufacturing firms in Zambia. J Dev Econ 81(2):514–526

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chintrakarn P, Herzer D, Nunnenkamp P (2012) FDI and income inequality: evidence from a panel of US states. Econ Inq 50(3):788–801

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Mello LR Jr (1999) Foreign direct investment-led growth: evidence from time series and panel data. Oxford Econ Pap 51(1):133–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demetriades PO, James GA (2011) Finance and growth in Africa: the broken link. Econ Lett 113(3):263–265

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Sousa J, Lochard J (2011) Does the single currency affect foreign direct investment? Scand J Econ 113(3):553–578

    Google Scholar 

  • Di Iorio F, Fachin S (2012) A note on the estimation of long-run relationships in panel equations with cross-section linkages. Economics The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 6(20):1–18

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duffy J, Papageorgiou C (2000) A cross-country empirical investigation of the aggregate production function specification. J Econ Growth 5(1):87–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning JH (2003) Determinants of foreign direct investment: globalization-induced changes and the role of policies. In: Tungodden B, Stern N, Kolstad I (eds) Toward pro-poor policies: aid, institutions, and globalization. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 279–290

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterly W, Levine R (2001) It’s not factor accumulation: stylized facts and growth models. World Bank Econ Rev 15(2):177–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eberhardt M, Helmers C, Strauss H (2013) Do spillovers matter when estimating private returns to R&D? Rev Econ Stat 95(2):436–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Entorf H (1997) Random walks with drifts: nonsense regression and spurious fixed-effects estimation. J Econom 80(2):287–296

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eslava M, Haltiwanger J, Kugler A, Kugler M (2006) Plant turnover and structural reforms in Colombia. IMF Staff Pap 53(Special Issue):58–75

    Google Scholar 

  • Everaert G (2011) Estimation and inference in time series with omitted I(1) variables. J Time Ser Econom 2(2):1–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Farole T, Winkler DE (2012) Foreign firm characteristics, absorptive capacity and the institutional framework: the role of mediating factors for FDI spillovers in low- and middle-income countries. World Bank Policy Research Working paper no. 6265, World Bank

  • Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2015) The next generation of the Penn World Table. Am Econ Rev 105(10):3150–3182

  • Fillat C, Wörz J (2011) Good or bad? The influence of FDI on productivity growth. An industry-level analysis. J Int Trade Econ Dev 20(3):293–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Findlay R (1978) Relative backwardness, direct foreign investment and the transfer of technology: a simple dynamic model. Q J Econ 92(1):1–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görg H, Greenway D (2004) Much ado about nothing? Do domestic firms really benefit from foreign direct investment? World Bank Res Obser 19(2):171–197

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gourinchas P-O, Jeanne O (2006) The elusive gains from international financial integration. Rev Econ Stud 73(3):715–741

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Granger CWJ (1988) Some recent developments in a concept of causality. J Econom 39(1–2):199–211

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hadi A (1992) Identifying multiple outliers in multivariate data. J Roy Stat Soc B Met 54(3):761–771

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE, Jones CI (1999) Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others? Q J Econ 114(1):83–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall SG, Milne A (1994) The relevance of P-star analysis to UK monetary policy. Econ J 104(424):597–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison A, Rodríguez-Clare A (2010) Trade, foreign investment, and industrial policy for developing countries. In: Rodrik D, Rosenzweig MR (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol 5. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 4039–4214

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Herzer D (2011) The long-run relationship between outward foreign direct investment and total factor productivity: evidence for developing countries. J Dev Stud 47(5):767–785

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herzer D (2012) How does foreign direct investment really affect developing countries’ growth? Rev Int Econ 20(2):396–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Herzer D, Strulik H, Vollmer S (2012) The long-run determinants of fertility: one century of demographic change 1900–1999. J Econ Growth 17(4):357–385

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holly S, Pesaran MH, Yamagata T (2010) A spatio-temporal model of house prices in the USA. J Econom 158(1):160–173

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh C-T, Klenow PJ (2010) Development accounting. Am Econ J-Macroecon 2(1):207–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2000) World economic outlook: asset prices and the business cycle. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF (2014) World economic outlook: recovery strengthens, remains uneven. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Iršová Z, Havránek T (2013) Determinants of horizontal spillovers from FDI: evidence from a large meta-analysis. World Dev 42(2):1–15

    Google Scholar 

  • Juselius K (2006) The cointegrated VAR model: methodology and applications. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Kao C (1999) Spurious regression and residual-based tests for cointegration in panel data. J Econom 90(1):1–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kao C, Chiang MH (2000) On the estimation and inference of a cointegrated regression in panel data. In: Baltagi BH, Fomby TB, Hill RC (eds) Nonstationary panels, panel cointegration, and dynamic panels (Advances in Econometrics). Bingley, Emerald, pp 179–222

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Karabarbounis L, Neiman B (2013) The global decline of the labor share. Q J Econ 129(1):61–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klenow PJ, Rodríguez-Clare A (1997) The neoclassical revival in growth economics: has it gone too far? NBER Macroecon Annu 12:73–114

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kneller R, Stevens PA (2003) The specification of the aggregate production function in the presence of inefficiency. Econ Lett 81(2):223–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mark NC, Ogaki M, Sul D (2005) Dynamic seemingly unrelated cointegrating regressions. Rev Econ Stud 72(3):797–820

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer-Foulkes D, Nunnenkamp P (2009) Do multinational enterprises contribute to convergence or divergence? A disaggregated analysis of US FDI. Rev Dev Econ 13(2):304–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nair-Reichert U, Weinhold D (2001) Causality tests for cross-country panels: a new look at FDI and economic growth in developing countries. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 63(2):153–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2002) Foreign direct investment for development: maximising benefits, minimizing costs. OECD, Paris

    Google Scholar 

  • Otero J, Smith J (2013) Response surface estimates of the cross-sectionally augmented IPS tests for panel unit roots. Comput Econ 41(1):1–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni P (2000) Fully modified OLS for heterogeneous cointegrated panels. In: Baltagi BH, Fomby TB, Hill RC (eds) Nonstationary panels, panel cointegration, and dynamic panels (Advances in Econometrics). Bingley, Emerald, pp 93–130

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pedroni P (2001) Purchasing power parity tests in cointegrated panels. Rev Econ Stat 83(4):727–731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH (2004) General diagnostic tests for cross section dependence in panels. CESifo Working paper series no. 1229, CESifo Group, Munich

  • Pesaran MH (2006) Estimation and inference in large heterogeneous panels with a multifactor error structure. Econometrica 74(4):967–1012

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pesaran MH (2007) A simple panel unit root test in the presence of cross-section dependence. J Appl Econom 22(2):265–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett L (1996) Population growth, factor accumulation, and productivity. World Bank Policy Research Working paper no. 1567, World Bank

  • Psacharopoulos G (1994) Returns to investment in education: a global update. World Dev 22(9):1325–1343

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramirez MD (2006) Is foreign direct investment beneficial for Mexico? An empirical analysis, 1960–2001. World Dev 34(5):802–817

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rodríguez-Clare A (1996) Multinationals, linkages and economic development. Am Econ Rev 86(4):852–873

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH (1987) Asymptotic properties of least squares estimators of cointegrating vectors. Econometrica 55(5):1035–1056

  • UN (2002) Final outcome of the international conference on financing for development. United Nations, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (2000) World investment report 2000: cross-border mergers and acquisitions and development. United Nations, New York and Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner M, Hlouskova J (2010) The performance of panel cointegration methods: results from a large scale simulation study. Econom Rev 29(2):182–223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang M, Wong MCS (2009) Foreign direct investment and economic growth: the growth accounting perspective. Econ Inq 47(4):701–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Westerlund J (2007) Testing for error correction in panel data. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 69(6):709–748

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woo J (2009) Productivity growth and technological diffusion through foreign direct investment. Econ Inq 47(2):226–248

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to two anonymous referees and an anonymous associate editor for many helpful suggestions and constructive comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Dierk Herzer.

Appendix

Appendix

See Tables 7, 8, and 9.

Table 7 Summary of multi-country macroeconomic studies on the impact of FDI on total factor productivity
Table 8 Countries and summary statistics
Table 9 Countries in the subsamples

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Herzer, D., Donaubauer, J. The long-run effect of foreign direct investment on total factor productivity in developing countries: a panel cointegration analysis. Empir Econ 54, 309–342 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1206-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-016-1206-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation