Skip to main content
Log in

Convergence of inflation with a common cycle: estimating and modelling Spanish historical inflation from the 16th to the 18th centuries

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The aim of this paper is twofold. First, to obtain inflation rates for the four regions of Spain analysed for the period 1501–1800 by modelling Hamilton’s (American treasure and the price revolution in Spain, 1934; War and prices in Spain, 1947) price index series by means of an unobserved component model with a common cyclical factor. And second, to prove their long-term convergence process. Therefore, convergence concerns both the cyclical variation of inflation rates common to the four regions, and trend inflation. A complete convergence of the trend inflation occurred once the monetary reforms of Charles II of Spain were introduced in order to redress the previous monetary instability known as inflation of the vellón. The predominance of the vellón in small change and the concentration of the influx of silver when inflation was comparatively lower (second half of the sixteenth century and the seventeenth century) complicate to reach simple conclusions on the monetary origin of inflation exclusively based on precious metals, but, on the contrary, suggest a monetary origin based on copper coin and fiscal distortions. So, monetary stability proved to be a necessary condition for inflation convergence and the fulfilment of the purchasing power parity condition along the eighteen century.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The vellón (billon) is a based copper coin generally used as small change. Before 1602, it also contained a proportion of silver. The bibliography on the vellón and the monetary reforms affecting its face value and composition is very abundant. For introductory purposes, see, for example, Velde and Weber (2000).

  2. Another possibility, which is followed here, is to estimate the noise variance ratio \(nvr={\sigma _{\varepsilon }^{2}}/{\sigma _{e}^{2}}\), see Young (1994). The importance of this parameter in obtaining the trend will be discussed in the Sect. 5.

  3. The consumer goods considered and their temporal availability are detailed in Hamilton (1934, 1947) appendixes. In addition to the number of goods, to increase the number of available prices to calculate the average price of a good causes its variance to reduce, that is, the sample average is more precise.

  4. The opposite \(nvr^{-1}\) has been estimated due to its numerical magnitude.

  5. The average annual rate of inflation between 1501 and 1800 was 0.5 % in Andalusia, 0.4 % in New and Old Castile and 0.3 % in Valencia. In the first half of the sixteenth century, the most inflationary period, average annual inflation rates stood at 1.4, 1.2, 1.0, and 0.9 % respectively. We agree with the remarks made by Martín Aceña (1992) when he pointed out that it is fair to speak of a “price revolution” not because of the amount prices increased, but because the trend lasted for around 150 years.

  6. The error term of the common cyclical variation has a standard variance of 1, so that differences in cyclical amplitude are seen in factor loadings.

  7. This dating rule is commonly used in business cycle analysis, albeit applied to quarterly GDP observations.

  8. A reference to inter-regional price levels in the same currency during a same base year is needed in order to ascertain whether purchasing power parity in absolute terms had been achieved. This reference could be obtained from the detailed information supplied by Hamilton but exceeds the objectives of this paper.

  9. The relationship between different \(nvr^{-1}\) parameter values and the period of oscillations included in the trend are obtained from the spectral characteristic of the filter. See, for example Harvey and Trimbur (2008).

  10. It can also be observed the limited magnitude of the dispersion of these long-term rates, which do not exceed one percentage point. This fact again allows us to show the differences between a metallic cash-based monetary system and a fiduciary one.

  11. Inflationary measures were adopted in the years 1532, 1596, 1597, 1602, 1603, 1636, 1641, 1642, 1643, 1652, 1654, 1658 and 1659; and deflationary measures in the years 1566, 1628, 1651, 1660, 1664, 1680 and 1684.

  12. A Castilian unit of account whose metallic counterpart was abandoned before the period here analysed.

References

  • Álvarez Nogal C (1997) Los banqueros de Felipe IV y los metales preciosos americanos (1621–1665). Estudios de Historia Económica. Banco de España, Madrid

    Google Scholar 

  • Álvarez Nogal C (2001) Los problemas del vellón en el siglo XVII. ¿Se consiguió abaratar la negociación del crédito imponiendo precios máximos a la plata? Revista de Historia Económica XIX:17–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cendejas JL, Hoyo J, Llorente G, Monjas M, Rivero C (2006) Ciclo económico y convergencia real en la Unión Europea. Análisis de los PIB per cápita en la UE-15. WP 10/06, BBVA Foundation, Madrid

  • Clark PK (1987) The cyclical component of U.S. economic activity. Q J Econ 102:797–814

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cogley T, Nason JM (1995) Effects of the Hodrick–Prescott filter on trend and difference stationary time series. Implications for business cycle research. J Econ Dyn Control 19:253–278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drelichman M (2005) The curse of Moctezuma: American silver and the Dutch disease. Explor Econ Hist 42:349–380

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Font de Villanueva C (2004) Pensamiento monetario y reforma económica en la Castilla de Carlos II: la estabilización de 1680–1686. PhD Dissertation, Universidad Autónoma de Madrid

  • Font de Villanueva C (2005) Política monetaria y política fiscal en Castilla en el siglo XVII: un siglo de inestabilidades. Revista de Historia Económica 1:329–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Font de Villanueva C (2008) La estabilización monetaria de 1680–1686. Pensamiento y política económica. Estudios de Historia Económica. Banco de España, Madrid

    Google Scholar 

  • García de Paso JI (1999) La economía monetaria del Padre Juan de Mariana. Moneda y Crédito 209:13–44

    Google Scholar 

  • García de Paso JI (2000) La estabilización monetaria en Castilla bajo Carlos II. Revista de Historia Económica XVIII:49–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García de Paso JI (2002) The 1628 castilian crydown: a test of competing theories of the price level. Hacienda Pública Española 163:71–91

    Google Scholar 

  • García de Paso JI (2003) La política monetaria castellana de los siglos XVI y XVII. In: Valera M, Durán JJ (eds) La moneda en Europa. De Carlos V al euro, Pirámide, Madrid, pp 101–136

    Google Scholar 

  • González MJ, Hoyo J (1983) Dinero y precios en la España del siglo XVI. Una confirmación de la tesis de Hamilton. Moneda y Crédito 166:15–46

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton EJ (1929) American treasure and the rise of capitalism, 1500–1700. Economica 27:338–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton EJ (1934) American treasure and the price revolution in Spain, 1501–1650. Octagon Books, New York (Spanish translation of A. Abad (1975), Ariel, Barcelona)

  • Hamilton EJ (1947) War and prices in Spain, 1651–1800. Harvard University Press, Harvard (Spanish translation of L. Iglesias (1988), Alianza, Madrid)

  • Harvey AC (1985) Trend and cycles in macroeconomic time series. J Bus Econ Stat 3:216–227

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey AC (1989) Forecasting structural time series models and the Kalman filter. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey AC, Jaeger A (1993) Detrending and the business cycle. J Appl Econom 8:231–247

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey AC, Trimbur T (2008) Trend estimation and the Hodrick–Prescott filter. J Jpn Stat Soc 38:41–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Llopis E, Jérez M, Álvaro A, Fernández E (2000) Índices de precios de la zona noroccidental de Castilla y León, 1518–1650. Revista de Historia Económica XVIII:665–684

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martín Aceña P (1992) Los precios en Europa durante los siglos XVI y XVII: estudio comparativo. Revista de Historia Económica X:359–395

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munro J (2007) Review of Earl J. Hamilton, American treasure and the price revolution in Spain, 1501–1650. EH.Net Economic History Services. http://eh.net/book_reviews/american-treasure-and-the-price-revolution-in-spain-1501-1650/. Accessed 15 March 2014

  • Murray CJ (2003) Cyclical properties of Baxter–King filtered time series. Rev Econ Stat 85:472–476

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nadal J (1959) La revolución de los precios españoles en el siglo XVI. Estado actual de la cuestión. Hispania, Revista Española de Historia 19:503–529

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson CR (1988) Spurious trend and cycle in the state space decomposition of a time series with a unit root. J Econ Dyn Control 12:475–488

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phelps Brown EH, Hopkins SV (1956) Seven centuries of the prices of consumables, compared with builders’ wage rates. Economica XXIII:296–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reher DS, Ballesteros E (1993) Precios y salarios en Castilla la Nueva: la construcción de un índice de salarios reales. Revista de Historia Económica XI:101–151

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruiz Martín F (1997) El problema del vellón: su incidencia en la distinta evolución económica de Castilla y de la Corona de Aragón en el siglo XVII. Manuscrits 15:97–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent TJ, Velde FR (2002) The big problem of small change. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (1989) New indexes of coincident and leading economic indicators. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 351–394

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (1991) A probability model of the coincident economic indicators. In: Lahiri K, Moore GH (eds) Leading economic indicators. New approaches and forecasting records. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Velde FR, Weber WE (2000) Fiat money in seventeenth century Castile. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson MV (1986) Univariate detrending methods with stochastic trends. J Monetary Econ 18:49–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Young PC (1994) Time-variable parameter and trend estimation in nonstationary economic time series. J Forecast 13:179–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The authors would like to thank the Instituto de Investigaciones Económicas y Sociales “Francisco de Vitoria” for the grant received for this project from the 2nd and 3rd call for proposals for research projects. The authors would also like to thank Carlos Álvarez Nogal, Félix Fernando Muñoz Pérez, Pedro Schwartz Girón and Pedro Tedde de Lorca for their comments on this work and their help in improving this paper.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to José Luis Cendejas Bueno.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Cendejas Bueno, J.L., Font de Villanueva, C. Convergence of inflation with a common cycle: estimating and modelling Spanish historical inflation from the 16th to the 18th centuries. Empir Econ 48, 1643–1665 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0840-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0840-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation