Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Gender ratio, divorce rate, and intra-household collective decision process: evidence from iranian urban households labor supply with non-participation

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper provides an empirical investigation on the individual labor supply of Iranian spouses in an intra-household collective decision framework in which gender ratio and divorce rate play a central role for resource allocation of household. The dataset is taken from the Households’ Expenditures Survey (2008) and the Annual Statistical Yearbook (2008) of Iran. I have conducted the parameters estimation and hypothesis testing using switching regression technique to catch the presence of the widespread non-participation of spouses across Iranian households. Reduced forms of labor supply are estimated considering the endogeneity of wage rates. The findings show that the unitary model of resource allocation and the collective model of decision process under Iranian civil procedure rules are strongly rejected, but the Pareto efficiency in the family resource allocation and validity of the specified model are confirmed. Furthermore, the coherency condition of labor supply reduced forms is satisfied. The structural labor supplies are derived from the reduced forms, and they indicate that leisure is a normal good for spouses. They also show the cross elasticity of a wife’s labor supply with respect to her husband’s wage is negative. The calculated marginal effect of non-labor income on the wife’s share is 0.76. The gender ratio and the divorce rate are both significant determinants of the sharing rule and the estimated coefficients of these variables are consistent with theoretical considerations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to the civil procedures of Iran, groom should accept a commitment according which he should pay a dower upon to request of the bride during their life or when she wants to get divorce. The dower usually is determined by real estate or golden coins which by norm amounts to 250 ounce. Moreover, if the divorce is initiated by husband, he should pay half of all their properties and assets to his wife.

  2. In a well-described survey, (Xu 2007) categorizes the intra-household models and its empirical evidence.

  3. Note that housewives and students are excluded from the sample, and all individuals with non-zero working hour are considered as employed.

References

  • Altonji JG, Hayashi F, Kotlikoff LJ (1993) Is the extended family altruistically linked? direct tests using micro data. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

  • Apps PF, Rees R (1988) Taxation and the household. J Public Econ 35(3):355–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ashworth, JS, Ulph DT (1981) Endogeneity I: estimating labour supply with piecewise linear budget constraints. In: Brown CV (ed) Taxation and labour supply. George Allen and Unwin, London p 53–68

  • Basu K (2006) Gender and say: a model of household behaviour with endogenously determined balance of power*. Econ J 116(511):558–580

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloemen HG (2010) An empirical model of collective household labour supply with non-participation. Econ J 120(543):183–214

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bloemen HG, Stancanelli EGF (2005) Financial wealth, consumption smoothing and income shocks arising from job loss. Economica 72(287):431–452

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Chiappori P-A, Magnac T, Meghir C (2007) Collective labour supply: heterogeneity and non-participation. Rev Econ Stud 74(2):417–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F, Browning M, Chiappori P-A, Lechene V (1993) Intra household allocation of consumption: a model and some evidence from french data. Ann Econ Stat 29:137–156

    Google Scholar 

  • Browning M (2000) The saving behaviour of a two-person household. Scand J Econ 102(2):235–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Bourguignon F, Chiappori P-A, Lechene V (1994) Income and outcomes: a structural model of intrahousehold allocation. J Political Econ 102:1067–1096

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning M, Chiappori P-A (1998) Efficient intra-household allocations: a general characterization and empirical tests. Econometrica 66:1241–1278

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chau TW, Li H, Liu PW, Zhang J (2007) Testing the collective model of household labor supply: evidence from china. China Econ Rev 18(4):389–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen Z, Woolley F (2001) A cournot–nash model of family decision making. Econ J 111(474):722–748

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A (1988) Rational household labor supply. Econometrica J Econ Soc 56:63–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A (1992) Collective labor supply and welfare. J Political Econ 100:437–467

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Ekeland I (2006) The micro economics of group behavior: general characterization. J Econ Theory 130(1):1–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Fortin B, Lacroix G (2002) Household labor supply, sharing rule and the marriage market. J Political Econ 110(1):37–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chiappori P-A, Fortin B, Lacroix G (2002) Marriage market, divorce legislation, and household labor supply. J Political Econ 110(1):37–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho D, Cho J, Song B (2010) An empirical analysis of the gender earnings gap between the public and private sectors in Korea: a comparative study with the US. J Jpn Int Econ 24(3):441–456

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clark A, Couprie H, Sofer C (2004) La modélisation collective de l’offre de travail. Rev Econ 55(4):767–789

    Google Scholar 

  • Crespo L (2005) Estimation and testing of household labour supply models: evidence from Spain. Citeseer, Barcelona

    Google Scholar 

  • Donni O (2003) Collective household labor supply: nonparticipation and income taxation. J Public Econ 87(5):1179–1198

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernandez-Val I (2003) Household labor supply: evidence for Spain. Investig Econ 27(2):239–275

    Google Scholar 

  • Fortin B, Lacroix G (1997) A test of the unitary and collective models of household labour supply*. Econ J 107(443):933–955

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman JA, Ruud P (1984) Family labor supply with taxes. Am Econ Rev 74:242–248

    Google Scholar 

  • Hourriez J-M(2005). Estimation of a collective model of labor supply with female nonparticipation. CREST-INSEE mimeo

  • Johnson WR, Skinner J (1986) Labor supply and marital separation. Am Econ Rev 438:455–469

    Google Scholar 

  • Keshavarz-Haddad GR, Mohit S (2012) Dual job holding in Iran. Tahghighat-e-eghtesadi 47:85–108

    Google Scholar 

  • Koolwal GB, Ray R (2002) Estimating the endogenously determined intrahousehold balance of power and its impact on expenditure pattern: evidence from Nepal, vol 2814. World Bank, Office of the Senior Vice President, Development, Economics

  • Lacroix G, Radtchenko N (2011) The changing intra-household resource allocation in Russia. J Popul Econ 24(1):85–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leuthold JH (1968) An empirical study of formula income transfers and the work decision of the poor. J Hum Resour 3:312–323

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ligon E (2003) Dynamic intra-household bargaining (with an application to bangladesh). Unpublished manuscript, UC Berkeley

  • Lundberg S, Pollak RA (1993) Separate spheres bargaining and the marriage market. J Political Econ 101:988–1010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Pollak RA (1996) Bargaining and distribution in marriage. J Econ Perspect 10(4):139–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg S, Rose E (1999) The determinants of specialization within marriage. School of Economics and Finance, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong

    Google Scholar 

  • Maitra P, Ray R (2003) The effect of transfers on household expenditure patterns and poverty in South Africa. J Dev Econ 71(1):23–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manser M, Brown M (1980) Marriage and household decision-making: a bargaining analysis. Int Econ Rev 21(1):31–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McElroy MB (1990) The empirical content of nash-bargained household behavior. J Hum Resour 25: 559–583

  • McElroy MB, Horney MJ (1981) Nash-bargained household decisions: toward a generalization of the theory of demand. Int Econ Rev 22(2):333–349

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moreau N (2000) Une application d’un modèle collectif d’offre de travail sur données françaises. Économie prévision 146(5):61–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stevenson B (2008) Divorce law and women’s labor supply. J Empir Leg Stud 5(4):853–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ulph D (1989) A general non-cooperative Nash model of household consumption behaviour. Johann Wolfgang Goethe-Universität, Frankfurt

    Google Scholar 

  • Xu Z (2007) A survey on intra-household models and evidence

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to GholamReza Keshavarz Haddad.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Haddad, G.K. Gender ratio, divorce rate, and intra-household collective decision process: evidence from iranian urban households labor supply with non-participation. Empir Econ 48, 1365–1394 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0828-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0828-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation