Skip to main content
Log in

Equity premium over different investment horizons

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper studies the adequate size of equity premium over different investment horizons based on spatial dominance. We find that the puzzle with respect to the size of equity premium disappears as investment horizons get longer in terms of the spatial dominance; therefore, the adequate size of equity premium should be dependent upon the investment horizon.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For instance, (Lewis 1991; Handa et al. 1993) show that asset pricing models cannot be rejected at longer holding intervals, and (Daniel and Marshall 1997; Parker and Julliard 2005) find that the risk premium can be explained better by long horizon consumption-based models.

  2. For example, in order to analyse the effect of time diversification, the mean–variance framework was used in Lloyd and Haney (1980); Lloyd and Modani (1983); Lee (1990); Thorley (1995) and Hodges et al. (1997), while (Hodges and Yoder 1996) applied the stochastic dominance analysis.

  3. We would like to thank an anonymous referee for addressing this issue.

  4. For more details about multi-period stochastic dominance, readers are referred to Levy (1973); Levy and Paroush (1974a) and Levy and Paroush (1974b).

  5. Hodges and Yoder (1996) provided the empirical study based on the stochastic dominance analysis with the assumption of \(i.i.d.\) returns, but they cannot provide any evidence for the relationship between dominance and the different investment horizons.

  6. For instance, the sample analogue estimators of the integrated local time and the integrated integrated local time are expressed as

    $$\begin{aligned} \hat{{L}}(T,x)=\Delta \sum _{i=1}^n {e^{-ri\Delta }} 1\{X_{i\Delta } \le x\},I\hat{{L}}(T,x)=\Delta \sum _{i=1}^n {e^{-ri\Delta }(x-} X_{i\Delta } )1\{X_{i\Delta } \le x\}, \end{aligned}$$

    where \(\Delta \) and \(\hbox {n}(=T/\Delta )\) indicate an observation interval and the number of observations for a given time period from 0 up to T, respectively.

  7. For instance, the sample observation inside the k-th holding period is denoted by (\(X^{k}_{i\varDelta })=\{ X^{k}_{1\varDelta , }X^{k}_{2\varDelta ,\ldots .,}X^{k}_{n\varDelta ,}\}\) for i = 1,...n, k = 1,...N.

  8. We also performed the test using daily T-bill rates simply obtained by dividing by 252, and the results of the second spatial dominance analysis with this data were very similar to the ones reported in the paper. We appreciate the referee who suggested using continuously compounding annual returns for the riskless asset in our analysis.

  9. The method in Capozza and Cornell (1979) was used to obtain the continuously compounding returns.

  10. We thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this point. In general, the investors should consider the conditional distribution of returns on information at the time of the investment decision. However, it might only apply to the 3-month maturity of the risk-free bond since there is no risk-free rate to compare for longer horizons.

  11. We use the overlapping returns for all the sampling intervals from 3 months to 10 years not just for 10 years for consistency of tests. In addition, the results with short horizons are very similar when we do not use overlapping data.

  12. When there exists serial dependence in the data, the form of the sampling distribution is generally unknown and depends on the unknown underlying distributions. To deal with this problem, the sampling distribution of the test statistics is approximated using a resampling scheme based on subsampling methods. See Politis and Romano (1999) and Linton et al. (2005).

  13. We also analysed the first spatial dominance test over various time periods with S&P500, DJIA and NASDAQ as risky assets, but cannot find any dominance in the first order. We do not report the specific results to save space.

  14. This finding seems in contrast to the traditional equity premium puzzle. Our findings are similar to the evidence of a reverse puzzle in Lim et al. (2006) who found that T-bill stochastically dominates equities. The approach and data sets used in our paper are different from the ones in the literature since we used high-frequency data whereas most of the empirical evidence for equity premium is based on the annual or quarterly data since the consumption data are only available for low frequency. Moreover, our spatial dominance tests are based on asset returns and not consumption data.

  15. We do not present the figures of the integrated spatial distribution functions of the cumulative returns for the NASDAQ as a risky asset since the patterns are very similar to those in Figs. 1 and 2.

  16. We would like to thank to an anonymous referee who suggested a sub-period analysis.

  17. In this case, the spatial dominance tests were employed for 3-month to 3- year investment horizons since we have small number of observations and we tried the subsample size in the range of [\(N^{0.3 } N ^{0.65}\)] so that the number of different subsample sizes is 30 and reported the median value of corresponding \(p\) values.

  18. Merton (1973) suggested that variation in expected returns over time could potentially introduce horizon effect. Barberis (2000) and Gil-Bazo (2006) addressed this issue based on the returns predictability.

References

  • Barberis N (2000) Investing for the long run when returns are predictable. J Finance 55(1):225–264

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capozza DR, Cornell B (1979) Treasury bill pricing in the spot and futures markets. Rev Econ Stat 61(4):513–520

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll C, Samwick A (1997) The nature of precautionary wealth. J Monetary Econ 40(1):41–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cho Y, Linton O, Whang Y (2007) Are there Monday effects in stock returns: a stochastic dominance approach. J Empir Finance 14(5):736–755

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Constantinides G (1990) Habit formation: a resolution of the equity premium puzzle. J Political Econ 98(3):519–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daniel K, Marshall D (1997) Equity-premium and risk-free-rate puzzles at long horizons. Macroecon Dyn 1(02):452–484

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein L, Zin S (1991) Substitution, risk aversion, and the temporal behavior of consumption and asset returns: an empirical analysis. J Political Econ 99(2):263–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Bazo J (2006) Investment horizon effects. J Bus Finance Acc 33(1–2):179–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Handa P, Kothari S, Wasley C (1993) Sensitivity of multivariate tests of the capital asset-pricing model to the return measurement interval. J Finance 48(4):1543–1551

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodges C, Taylor W, Yoder J (1997) Stocks, bonds, the sharpe ratio, and the investment horizon. Financial Anal J 53:74–80

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodges C, Yoder J (1996) Time diversification and security preferences: a stochastic dominance analysis. Rev Quant Finance Acc 7(3):289–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim C (2009) Test for spatial dominances in the distribution of stock returns: evidence from the Korean stock market before and after the East Asian financial crisis. Stud Nonlinear Dyn Econ 13(4):1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee W (1990) Diversification and time: Do investment horizons matter? J Portfolio Manag 16(3):21–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari D, Levy H (1977) The capital asset pricing model and the investment horizon. Rev Econ Stat 59(1):92–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy H (1973) Stochastic dominance, efficiency criteria, and efficient portfolios: the multi-period case. Am Econ Rev 63(5):986–994

  • Levy H, Paroush J (1974a) Multi-period stochastic dominance. Manag Sci 21:428–435

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levy H, Paroush J (1974b) Toward multivariate efficiency criteria. J Econ Theory 7(2):129–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis KK (1991) Should the holding period matter for the intertemporal consumption-based CAPM? J Monetary Econ 28(3):365–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lim G, Maasoumi E, Martin V (2006) A reexamination of the equity-premium puzzle: a robust non-parametric approach. N Am J Econ Finance 17(2):173–189

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Linton O, Maasoumi E, Whang Y (2005) Consistent testing for stochastic dominance under general sampling schemes. Rev Econ Stud 72(3):735–765

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd W, Haney R Jr (1980) Time diversification. J Portfolio Manag 6(3):5–9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lloyd W, Modani N (1983) Stocks, bonds, bills, and time diversification. J Portfolio Manag 9(3):7–11

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McFadden D (1989) Studies in the economics of uncertainty., Testing for stochastic dominanceSpringer, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R (2003) The equity premium: Why is it a puzzle? Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Mehra R, Prescott E (2003) Handbook of the economics of finance., The equity premium in retrospectElsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Mehra R, Prescott E (1985) The equity premium: a puzzle. J Monetary Econ 15(2):145–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton R (1973) An intertemporal capital asset pricing model. Econometrica 41(5):867–887

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Park J (2007) The spatial analysis of time series. In proceedings of the FEMES Meetings, Beijing

  • Parker JA, Julliard C (2005) Consumption risk and the cross section of expected returns. J Political Econ 113(1):185–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Politis D, Romano J, Wolf M (1999) Subsampling. Springer Verlag, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Post T (2003) Empirical tests for stochastic dominance efficiency. J Finance 58(5):1905–1932

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thorley S (1955) The time-diversification controversy. Financial Anal J 51:68–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank Joon Y. Park for many helpful discussions and suggestions. We also thank the editor and two anonymous referees for helping us to improve the quality of this paper substantially. This paper was supported by Samsung Research Fund, Sungkyunkwan University, 2013.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chang Sik Kim.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Lee, E., Kim, C.S. & Kim, IM. Equity premium over different investment horizons. Empir Econ 48, 1169–1187 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0812-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0812-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation