Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The elasticity of taxable income of high earners: evidence from Hungary

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The paper studies how high-income taxpayers responded to the introduction of the “extraordinary tax on individuals” in Hungary in 2007. The study is based on a panel of tax returns containing information on 10 % of tax filers from 2005 and three subsequent years. We estimate the elasticity of taxable income with respect to the marginal net-of-tax rate and find that the taxable income of Hungarian high earners is moderately responsive to taxation: the estimated elasticity is about 0.24. We also find evidence for a sizeable income effect. The estimated effect is not caused by income shifting.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The relationship between the elasticity of the taxable income and the dead-weight loss of taxation was analyzed by Feldstein (1999) and Chetty (2009).

  2. Updated results of Bakos et al. (2008) have been described by Benczúr et al. (2013) for a non-technical audience.

  3. Own calculation based on a 10 % random sample of 2008 tax returns, excluding the full-time self-employed.

  4. In contrast, Goolsbee (2000) finds evidence in the US that a substantial part of the response of high-income individuals to tax changes is of a short-term nature, involving the timing of certain transactions, and thus does not represent real labor supply adjustment.

  5. The approach taken here follows Feldstein (1999), Gruber and Saez (2002), and Bakos et al. (2008).

  6. Previous studies chose different ways to operationalize the income effect in the empirical specification. This formulation follows Bakos et al. (2008) whose operationalization is a slight variant of that of Gruber and Saez (2002). For the derivation of this form and its comparison to Gruber and Saez (2002), see Appendix B.

  7. The official Hungarian term is, in literal translation, “aggregated tax base” (“összevont adóalap”).

  8. The official Hungarian term is, in literal translation, “separately taxed incomes” (“külön adózó jövedelmek”).

  9. The extraordinary tax of individuals was introduced by Act 59 of 2006 of the Republic of Hungary. According to paragraph 8, the extraordinary tax, as applied to those individuals who are not full-time self-employed, came into effect on January 1, 2007. The official Hungarian name of the tax is “magánszemélyek különadója.”

  10. This is why the official Hungarian term for this group of incomes is “income not bearing tax burden” (“adóterhet nem viselő járandóság”).

  11. For this reason, there is not as great a difference between ’taxable income’ and ’gross income’ in Hungary as in the US.

  12. The Hungarian term is ’adójóváírás.

  13. The Hungarian term is ’családi adókedvezmény.’

  14. Note that the withdrawal of all tax credits was conditional on “total income,” that is, the sum of taxable income and capital income.

  15. Employer contributions were paid at a rate of 32 % both in 2005 and in 2008.

  16. During the period 2005–2008, the exchange rate varied around the convenient equivalence EUR 1 \(=\) HUF 250. We use this exchange rate to interpret figures in Hungarian Forints (HUF) in the text.

  17. While this income range, evaluated at the current exchange rate, would be considered a middle-income sample in the economy of a highly developed country, it is within the top 5 percent of income earners in Hungary.

  18. For the majority of high-income individuals earning, “other taxable income,” it is income from abroad. Income earned abroad can, however, also be reported in another line of the tax file, depending on the type of income and the source country where it was earned. In an earlier version of this paper (Kiss and Mosberger 2011), we failed to exclude 5 individuals with income from abroad.

  19. For another 21 observations, the locality could be identified despite an erroneous (outdated) postal code.

  20. The results are robust to their exlusion. In an earlier version of this paper (Kiss and Mosberger 2011), we estimated the elasticity separately for men and women; results were similar to the overall results.

  21. All tests were performed using the ivreg2 package in Stata. More details on the tests can be found in Baum et al. (2003, 2007) and the references therein.

References

  • Aarbu KO, Thoresen TO (2001) Income responses to tax changes: evidence from the Norwegian tax reform. Natl Tax J 54:319–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Auten G, Carroll R (1999) The effect of income taxes on household behavior. Rev Econ Stat 81:681–693

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bakos P, Benczúr P, Benedek D (2008) The elasticity of taxable income: Estimates and flat tax predictions using the Hungarian tax changes in 2005. National Bank of Hungary Working Paper 2008/7

  • Baum CF, Schaffer ME, Stillman S (2003) Instrumental variables and GMM: estimation and testing. Stata J 3:1–31

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum CF, Schaffer ME, Stillman S (2007) Enhanced routines for instrumental variables/generalized method of moments estimation and testing. Stata J 7:465–506

    Google Scholar 

  • Benczúr P, Kátay G, Kiss Á (2012) Assessing changes of the Hungarian tax and transfer system: a general-equilibrium microsimulation approach. , Central Bank of Hungary MNB Working Papers 2012/7

  • Benczúr P, Kiss Á, Mosberger P (2013) The elasticity of taxable income. In: Fazekas K, Benczúr P, Telegdy Á (eds) The Hungarian labour market 2013. Hungarian Academy of Science, Budapest, pp 74–99

    Google Scholar 

  • Blomquist S, Selin H (2010) Hourly wage rate and taxable labor income responsiveness to changes in marginal tax rates. J Public Econ 94:878–889

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chetty R (2009) Is the taxable income elasticity sufficient to calculate deadweight loss? The implications of evasion and avoidance. Am Econ J Econ Policy 1:31–52

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M (1995) The effect of marginal tax rates on taxable income: a panel study of the 1986 tax reform act. J Polit Econ 103:551–572

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein M (1999) Tax avoidance and the deadweight loss of the income tax. Rev Econ Stat 81:674–680

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Giertz SH (2004) Recent literature on taxable-income elasticities. Technical Paper Series, Congressional Budget Office, Washington D.C

  • Gottfried P, Witczak D (2009) The responses of taxable income induced by tax cuts: empirical evidence from the German taxpayer panel. IAW Discussion Papers No. 57

  • Goolsbee A (2000) What happens when you tax the rich? Evidence from executive compensation. J Polit Econ 108:352–378

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber J, Saez E (2002) The elasticity of taxable income: evidence and implications. J Public Econ 84:1–32

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansson A (2007) Taxpayers’ responsiveness to tax rate changes and implications for the cost of taxation in Sweden. Int Tax Public Finan 14:563–582

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmlund B, Söderström M (2007) Estimating income responses to tax changes: a dynamic panel data approach. CESifo Working Paper No. 2121

  • Kiss Á, Mosberger P (2011) The elasticity of taxable income of high earners: evidence from Hungary. Central Bank of Hungary MNB Working Papers 2011/11

  • Kleven HJ, Schultz EA (2011) Estimating taxable income responses using Danish tax reforms. Manuscript, London School of Economics, London

  • Ljunge M, Ragan K (2004) Who responded to the tax reform of the century? Paper presented at the EEA Congress in Madrid, Madrid

  • Pirttilä J, Selin H (2011) Income shifting within a dual income tax system: evidence from the Finnish tax reform of 1993. Scand J Econ 113:120–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez E, Veall MR (2005) The evolution of high incomes in Northern America: lessons from Canadian evidence. Am Econ Rev 95:831–849

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saez E, Slemrod JB, Giertz SH (2012) The elasticity of taxable income with respect to marginal tax rates: a critical review. J Econ Lit 50:3–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sillamaa M-A, Veall MR (2001) The effect of marginal tax rates in taxable income: a panel study of the 1988 tax flattening in Canada. J Public Econ 80:341–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod J (1998) Methodological issues in measuring and interpreting taxable income elasticities. Natl Tax J 51:773–788

    Google Scholar 

  • Slemrod J, Kopczuk W (2002) The optimal elasticity of taxable income. J Public Econ 84:91–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research had been conducted before Áron Kiss started working at the European Commission. All opinions expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not represent the views of their past or present institutions. An earlier version of the paper was published as a working paper at the Central Bank of Hungary (Kiss and Mosberger 2011). Results of the working paper version have been discussed in a survey article for a non-technical audience (Benczúr et al. 2013). The authors would like to thank Péter Benczúr for his support throughout the project, Dóra Benedek, Péter Elek, Csanád Sándor Kiss and Ágota Scharle for comments on earlier drafts of the paper, participants of the 2011 conference of the IIPF in Ann Arbor, Michigan, the 2011 EEA-ESEM meeting in Oslo, the 2010 meeting of the Hungarian Society of Economics (MKE) in Budapest, and seminar participants at the University of Münster, the Ludwig–Maximilians-University in Munich, the Institute for Economics of the Hungarian Academy of Science, and the Central Bank of Hungary, for useful comments and suggestions. Any remaining error is ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Áron Kiss.

Appendices

Appendix A: Tables

See Tables 5, 6 and 7.

Table 5 Robustness analysis 1. Income limits of the sample
Table 6 Robustness analysis 2. Time period 2005–2007
Table 7 Regression results for groups by income source

Appendix B: The derivation of the income effect

In the main specifications we followed Bakos et al. (2008) in the operationalization of the income effect. Their solution is a slight variant of that by Gruber and Saez (2002), the difference being a minor step of approximation. In explaining the difference we somewhat extend the exposition of Bakos et al. (2008).

The starting point of the theory is an optimizing agent who has an income supply function \(y=y((1-\tau ),R)\), where \(\tau \) is the marginal tax rate and R is virtual income. Virtual income is defined, in a non-linear tax schedule, by the expression \(y-T\left( y \right) =R+\left( {1-\tau } \right) y\), where \(T(y)\) is the total tax due at income level \(y\). The agent’s response to a tax change can be written as:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{d}y=-\frac{\partial y}{\partial (1-\tau )}\mathrm{d}\tau +\frac{\partial y}{\partial R}\partial R. \end{aligned}$$

Introducing the uncompensated tax price elasticity \(\beta ^{u}=[(1-\tau )/y][\partial y/\partial (1-\tau )]\), the income effect \(\phi =\left( {1-\tau } \right) \partial y/\partial R\) and the compensated tax price elasticity \(\beta =\beta ^{u}-\phi \) we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}y}{y}=-\beta \frac{\mathrm{d}\tau }{1-\tau }+\phi \frac{\mathrm{d}R-y\mathrm{d}\tau }{y\left( {1-\tau } \right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Most studies estimate this equation in a log-log specification, replacing \(\mathrm{d}y/y\) by \(\hbox {log}(y_2 /y_1)\) and \((-\mathrm{d}\tau /(1-\tau ))\) by \(\log [\left( {1-\tau _2} \right) /(1-\tau _1)]\). Before Gruber and Saez (2002) the income effect was mostly assumed to be zero. They, in contrast, did include the income effect in the estimation by approximating the last term \((\mathrm{d}R-y\mathrm{d}\tau )/\left( y\left( {1-\tau } \right) \right) \) with \(\hbox {log}[\left( y_2 -T_2 \left( {y_2} \right) \right) /(y_1 -T_1 \left( {y_1} \right) )]\). As they note in a footnote on page 10 they use the approximation \(y\left( {1-\tau } \right) \approx y-T(y)\) to obtain this form. We can thus reconstruct their derivation as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}R-y\mathrm{d}\tau }{y\left( {1-\tau } \right) }\approx \frac{\mathrm{d}[y-T\left( y \right) ]}{y\left( {1-\tau } \right) }\approx \frac{\mathrm{d}[y-T\left( y \right) ]}{y-T(y)}\approx \log \left[ {\frac{y_2 -T_2 \left( {y_2} \right) }{y_1 -T_1 \left( {y_1} \right) }} \right] . \end{aligned}$$

The first equation uses the fact that \(\mathrm{d}R-y\mathrm{d}\tau \) is equal to the change in tax liability with changing tax rates and a constant income \(y\); the second step makes the approximation in the denominator described above; while the last step is just a logarithmic approximation. Thus the income effect, equal in its original form to the change in after-tax income divided by after-tax income minus virtual income, is approximated by the percentage change in after-tax income.

Bakos et al. (2008) use the same approximation \(y\left( {1-\tau } \right) \approx y-T(y)\) to justify a different estimated equation. They reach the following income effect:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\mathrm{d}R-y\mathrm{d}\tau }{y\left( {1-\tau } \right) }\approx \log \left[ {\frac{\left( y_2 -T_2 \left( {y_2} \right) \right) /y_2}{\left( y_1 -T_1 \left( {y_1 } \right) \right) /y_1}} \right] =\mathrm{d}\hbox {log}\left( {1-\hbox {AETR}} \right) . \end{aligned}$$

We can derive the approximation of Bakos et al. (2008) “backwards,” i.e., starting from the resulting form and reaching the original expression, as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \mathrm{d}\log \left( {\frac{y-T(y)}{y}} \right)&= \mathrm{d}\log \left( {\frac{R+y-y\tau }{y}} \right) =\frac{\mathrm{d}R+\mathrm{d}y-\mathrm{d}y\tau -y\mathrm{d}\tau }{R+y-y\tau }-\frac{\mathrm{d}y}{y}\\&\approx \frac{\mathrm{d}R+\mathrm{d}y-\tau \mathrm{d}y-y\mathrm{d}\tau }{y(1-\tau )}-\frac{\mathrm{d}y}{y}=\frac{\mathrm{d}R-y\mathrm{d}\tau }{y\left( {1-\tau } \right) }. \end{aligned}$$

Here the first equality follows from the definition of virtual income \(R\); the second equality follows from total differentiation; the third step uses, in the denominator, the same approximation that Gruber and Saez (2002) also use \((R+y-y\tau =y-T(y)\approx y(1-\tau ))\); while the last step is just a subtraction.

The difference between both approximations is slight. Total differentiation in the derivation of Bakos et al. means that in that step they allow \(y\) to change as well as the tax rates. In contrast, the first step in the derivation of Gruber and Saez (2002), as reconstructed here, holds exactly only if income is constant; it is an approximation if income changes.

Clearly, both approximations are legitimate. In this paper we choose the approximation of the income effect as derived by Bakos et al. for two reasons. First, while this form is reached using a crucial approximating step Gruber and Saez (2002) also use, it appears to us that altogether it is reached after fewer approximating steps. Second, we find it esthetically appealing to measure both the substitution and the income effect by the change of an easily interpretable tax rate, i.e., by the change of the marginal and average net-of-tax rate, respectively.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kiss, Á., Mosberger, P. The elasticity of taxable income of high earners: evidence from Hungary. Empir Econ 48, 883–908 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0809-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-014-0809-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation