Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Outsourcing and firm productivity: a production function approach

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper is aimed at analyzing the relationship between outsourcing and productivity. Specifically, this paper deals with outsourcing at the firm level and focuses on the role of contracting out of manufacturing activities. I obtain new insights on this topic, mainly using a precise measure for outsourcing and analyzing differences across industries. Using an unbalanced panel of Spanish manufacturing firms, I estimate a production function depending on traditional inputs (labor, capital, and materials) and an index of production subcontracting. I find that for manufacturing as a whole, outsourcing intensity has a positive effect on productivity, showing an elasticity of output with respect to outsourcing around 0.15. When analyzing industry level results, I find that outsourcing intensity has a positive effect on productivity, mainly for firms belonging to light industries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For example, the Oslo Manual (OECD 2005) considers the implementation of new ways of organizing relations with other firms such as the outsourcing or subcontracting to be an organizational innovation.

  2. These industrial services includes activities such as processing of inputs which are then sent back to the establishment for final assembly or sales, maintenance of production machinery, and engineering or drafting services.

  3. I adopt a production function approach because this paper focuses on the relationship between outsourcing and productivity. The estimation of the production function is commonly used in the analysis of productivity (see Ackerberg et al. 2007).

  4. This substitution is commonly used in the context of the logit transform \( {\text {log}}(\frac{z}{1-z}) \), where z is a share ranging from 0 to 1 (see Hall 2011). This issue is related to the estimation of a Cobb–Douglas production function with zero input levels. Empirical literature proposes three main solutions to this problem (see Moss 2000): (i) substituting a small nonzero value for the zero observations; (ii) using a functional form that allows for zero inputs (such as a quadratic production function); and (iii) bootstrapping.

  5. I consider 11 industries. Industry breakdown is defined in Appendix 2.

  6. See Blundell and Bond (2000); and Griliches and Mairesse (1998) for a discussion about this problem.

  7. As I said in Sect. 3, ratio \(\frac{\text {sr}}{1-\text {sr}}\) is an index of production subcontracting. It is not a direct measure of subcontracted purchases, and therefore, measuring the quantitative contribution of outsourcing is not straightforward.

References

  • Abraham KG, Taylor S (1996) Firms’ use of outside contractors: theory and evidence. J Labor Econ 14:394–424

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Abramovsky L, Griffith R, Mari S (2004) Offshoring of business services and its impact on the UK economy. IFS Briefing Note. doi:10.1920/bn.ifs.2004.0051

    Google Scholar 

  • Ackerberg D, Benkard L, Berry S, Pakes A (2007) Econometric tools for analyzing market outcomes. In: Heckman J (ed) Handbook of econometrics, vol 6. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 4171–4276

    Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Wei SJ (2005) Fear of outsourcing: is it justified? Econ Policy 20(42):308–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amiti M, Wei SJ (2006) Service offshoring, productivity and employment: evidence from the US. CEPR Discussion Paper No 5475

  • Anderton B, Brenton P (1999) Outsourcing and low-skilled workers in the UK. B Econ Res 51(4):267–286

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano M, Bond S (1991) Some tests of specification for panel data: monte carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev Econ Stud 58:277–297

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartel A, Lach S, Sicherman N (2012) Technological change and the make-or-buy decision. J Law Econ Organ. doi:10.1093/jleo/ews035

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Bond S (2000) GMM estimation with persistent panel data: an application to production functions. Econom Rev 19(3):321–340

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borga M, Zeile WJ (2004) International fragmentation of production and the intrafirm trade of United States multinational companies. Bureau of Economic Analysis WP 2004–2002

  • Campa J, Goldberg LS (1997) The evolving external orientation of manufacturing industries: evidence from four countries. NBER Working Paper No 5919

  • Díaz-Mora C (2008) What factors determine the outsourcing intensity? a dynamic panel data approach for manufacturing industries. Appl Econ 40(19):2509–2521

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Estevao M, Lach S (1999) Measuring temporary labor outsourcing in US manufacturing. NBER Working Paper No 7421

  • Falk M, Koebel B (2000) Outsourcing of services, imported materials, and the demand for heterogeneous labour: an application of a generalized Box-Cox function. Centre for European Economic Research (ZEW) Discussion Paper No 2000:51

  • Feenstra RC, Hanson GH (1995) Foreign investment, outsourcing and relative wages. NBER Working Paper No 5121

  • Feenstra RC, Hanson GH (1996) Globalization, outsourcing, and wage inequality. Am Econ Rev 41(1–2):240–245

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra RC, Hanson GH (1999) The impact of outsourcing and high-technology capital on wages: estimates for the United States, 1979–1990. Q J Econ 114(3):907–940

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fixler DJ, Siegel D (1999) Outsourcing and productivity growth in services. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 10:177–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Girma S, Görg H (2004) Outsourcing, foreign ownership, and productivity: evidence from UK establishment-level data. Rev Int Econ 12(15):817–832

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodman B, Steadman R (2002) Services: business demand rivals consumer demand in driving job growth. Mon Labor Rev 125(4):3–16

    Google Scholar 

  • Görg H, Hanley A, Strobl E (2008) Productivity effects of international outsourcing: evidence from plant level data. Can J Econ 41(2):670–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Görzig B, Stephan A (2002) Outsourcing and firm-level performance. German Institute for Economic Research Discussion Paper No 309

  • Griliches Z, Mairesse J (1998) Production functions: the search for identification. In: Strøm S (ed) Econometrics and economic theory in the 20th century: the Ragnar Frisch centennial symposium. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 169–203

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hall BH (2011) Innovation and productivity. NBER Working Paper No 17178

  • Hanson GH, Mataloni RJ, Slaughter MJ (2004) Vertical production networks in multinational firms. NBER Working Paper No 9723

  • Heshmati A (2003) Productivity growth, efficiency and outsourcing in manufacturing and service industries. J Econ Surv 17(1):79–112

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D, Jun I, Yi KM (2001) The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. J Int Econ 54(1):75–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McMillan J (1995) Reorganizing vertical supply relationships. In: Siebert H (ed) Trends in business organization: do participation and cooperation increase competitiveness?. JCB Mohr, Tübingen, pp 203–222

    Google Scholar 

  • Moss CB (2000) Estimation of the Cobb-Douglas with zero input levels: bootstrapping and substitution. Appl Econ Lett 7:677–679

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005) Oslo manual (3rd edn): proposed guidelines for collecting and interpreting innovation data. Paris

  • Olsen KB (2006) Productivity impacts of offshoring and outsourcing: a review. STI Working Paper 2006/1

  • Paul CJM, Yasar M (2009) Outsourcing, productivity and input composition at the plant level. Can J Econ 42(2):422–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel D, Griliches Z (1992) Purchased services, outsourcing, computers, and productivity in manufacturing. In: Griliches Z (ed) Output measurement in the service sector. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp 429–460

  • Ten Raa T, Wolff EN (2001) Outsourcing of services and the productivity recovery in US manufacturing in the 1980 and 1990s. J Prod Anal 16:149–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeats AJ (2001) Just how big is global production sharing? In: Arndt SW, Kierzkowski H (eds) Fragmentation: new production patterns in the world economy. Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp 108–143

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I would like to thank José Carlos Fariñas and Jordi Jaumandreu for their valuable suggestions and discussion. I also wish to acknowledge useful comments by Saul Lach and Frank Verboven, and by the audiences at the 32nd EARIE meeting and at the 23rd Annual Congress of the European Economic Association. I thank the editor, Subal C. Kumbhakar, and two anonymous referees for useful comments. I acknowledge financial support from the Ministerio de Ciencia e Innovación (Spain) project ECO2010-18947, and from Fundación Banco Herrero. Errors are mine.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alberto López.

Appendices

Appendix 1: definitions of variables

Capital stock :

Capital at current replacement values is computed recursively from an initial estimate and the data on firms’ investments in equipment goods (but not buildings or financial assets), actualized by means of a price index of capital goods, and using sectorial estimates of the rates of depreciation. Real capital is then obtained by deflating the current replacement values.

Entrant firm :

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 when the firm has been created during the period.

Exiting firms :

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 when the firm is going to exit during the period (stop activity or stop manufacturing).

Hours of work :

Total normal hours of work plus overtime minus lost hours, computed by multiplying hours per worker by the number of workers.

Hours per worker :

Normal hours of work plus overtime minus lost hours per worker.

Industry dummies :

Eighteen industry dummies (ESEE Industries. See Appendix 2).

Intermediate consumption :

Sum of purchases of materials and external services minus the variation of intermediate inventories. Nominal intermediate consumption is deflated by the firm’s specific price index of intermediate consumption.

Merger and acquisition :

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 in the years subsequent to a merger or acquisition.

Output :

Goods and services production. Sales plus the variation of inventories deflated by the firm’s output price index.

Proportion of temporary workers :

Ratio between temporary workers and total number of workers.

Price :

Paasche-type price index computed by starting from the percentage price changes that the firm reports to have made in the markets in which it operates.

consumption :

Paasche-type price index computed by starting from the percentage variations in the prices of purchased materials, energy and services reported by the firms.

Scission :

Dummy variable that takes the value 1 in the years subsequent to a scission.

Subcontracted purchases :

Purchases of elaborated products or customized components. Nominal subcontracted purchases are deflated by the firm’s specific price index of intermediate consumption.

Workers :

Approximation of the average number of workers during the year.

Appendix 2: industry definitions

NACE code (3-digit)

ESEE Industries

Industry breakdown

221 to 224

Ferrous and non-ferrous metals

Metals and metal products

311 to 319

Metal products

 

240 to 249

Non-metallic mineral products

Non-metallic minerals

251 to 255

Chemical products

Chemical products

481, 482

Rubber and plastic products

 

321 to 329

Industrial and agricultural machinery

Ind. and agric. machinery

330, 391 to 399

Office and data processing machinery

Office mach. and elec. goods

341 to 347

Electrical goods

 

351 to 355

  

361 to 363

Motor vehicles

Transport equipment

371, 372

Other transport equipment

 

381 to 389

  

413

Meats, meat preparation

Food, drink and tobacco

411, 412

Food products and tobacco

 

414 to 423, 429

  

424 to 428

Beverages

 

431 to 439

Textiles and clothing

Textile, leather and shoes

453 to 456

  

441, 442

Leather and leather products

 

451, 452

  

461 to 468

Timber, wood products

Timber and furniture

471 to 475

Paper and printing products

Paper and printing products

491 to 495

Other manufacturing products

Other manufacturing products

Appendix 3

See Tables 9 and 10

Table 9 Firms by industry and number of observations
Table 10 Variable descriptive statistics

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

López, A. Outsourcing and firm productivity: a production function approach. Empir Econ 47, 977–998 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0770-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0770-x

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation