Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Is the Engel curve approach viable in the estimation of alternative PPPs?

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Conventional estimates of purchasing power parities (PPP) rely on cross-country price data. Using Engel curves, Almås (Am Econ Rev 102:1093–1117, 2012) was, however, able to show that PPPs contain substantial bias. Since constructing conventional estimates is expensive and time consuming, Almås’ idea of employing Engel curves is welcome. This article examines the viability of the Engel curve approach to PPP and its sensitivity to differences in relative prices and preferences by estimating Engel curves not only between countries but also for regions within a given country. My empirical evidence from the United States and Norway suggests that the differences can be problematic, but not sufficiently to discredit the new methodology. A pragmatic approach to PPP estimation between countries that are different is to compute a PPP band, rather than a point estimate. I present a practical example of this using expenditure data from 2001, which yields a band for NOK and US dollar.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. By preferences I mean consumer preferences. However, in the “Section 5” below I explain why institutions may matter and how the definition of preferences could be broadened to include cultural and institutional factors and characteristics.

  2. Moreover, as Beatty and Crossley (2012) point out, the Engel curve methodology requires downward-sloping curves, i.e. non-homothetic preferences. At the same time, a single price index for all households implies homothetic preferences. This can, however, occur if households are distributed in finite mixtures of preferences where preferences are homothetic within groups, but non-homothetic between them. This preference structure allows for both Engel curve estimation and index computation for types.

  3. In fact, building on Beatty and Crossley (2012), constructing different PPP-estimates for different household groups may be a preferable approach when preferences are homothetic within-group but not homothetic between groups.

  4. Notice that my PPP estimates for households of different material standards of living may serve several purposes. First, they capture possible differences in institutions and relative prices between countries. Second, they allow for non-homothetic preferences within-countries; see Beatty and Crossley (2012). I do not, however, estimate the number of groups in the finite mixture of preferences.

  5. The coefficients c and f are typically negative since Engel-curves for food slope downward.

  6. Thus, I report classical t values. I have computed, but do not report, heteroskedasticity-consistent t values. The differences between the two are small.

  7. Again, the idea of a PPP-band is supported by the findings in Beatty and Crossley (2012) since a band allows for different estimates for households at different income levels.

  8. This fraction is controlled by the smoothing parameter, which is set by the analyst. I use a smoothing parameter of 0.6. in the procedure PROC LOESS of the software package SAS. For technical details on and examples of code for such non-parametric regressions, see SAS/STAT\(\circledR \) 9.2 User’s Guide, 2nd Edn. Online: http://support.sas.com/documentation/.

  9. Statistics Norway has constructed a special internet site in English on CES, sampling, weights, and latest developments. Use: http://www.ssb.no/english/subjects/05/02/forbruk_en/.

  10. The producer and distributor of the US data files are: US Dept. of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Consumer expenditure survey, 2001: Interview survey and detailed expenditure file [Computer file]. Washington, DC: US Dept. of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics [producer], 2002. Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor], 2003.

  11. The last digit in the ID represents the interview-quarter, the other the unique household.

  12. I use fmly-files from diary data (da3675.fmly011-da3675.fmly014) and detailed expenditure files (da3675.expn011-da3675.expn014).

  13. The result of 0.0809ln(7); see Theory.

  14. The t values of the intercept estimates are 18.6 and 63.3 indicate small estimated standard deviations (0.0588 and 0.0150, respectively). The estimated standard deviation of the intercept difference becomes 0.060674. Thus, the t value of testing the intercept difference is 0.16.

  15. See e.g. Rice (1995, p. 515). The estimated standard variation of the estimated intercept difference is \((0.010102^{2} + 0.00275^{2})^{0.5} = 0.010467.\)

  16. I employ different specifications as part of a broader model selection process. If the QUAIDS-specification is true to the underlying structure, then the linear AIDS-specification is an approximation. In that case, the latter may still be quite accurate in the most interesting income interval.

  17. Moreover, it allows smaller segments to have within-group homothetic preferences even if there are between-group differences.

  18. The sums of squared errors were 3.54985 for the unconstrained and 3.56906 for the constrained. There were 999 observations, 8 parameters in the unconstrained regression and 3 linear restrictions in the constrained.

    Table 6 Estimating Engel curves for food for regions: food’s share of income before tax on determinants
  19. Blundell et al. (1993) also study quadratic curves.

References

  • Ahmed N, Brzozowski M, Crossley TF (2006) Measurement errors in recall food consumption data. The Institute of Fiscal Studies, Working Paper 6/21.

  • Almås I (2012) International income inequality: measuring PPP bias by estimating Engel curves for food. Am Econ Rev 102(2):1093–1117

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banks J, Blundell RW, Lewbel A (1997) Quadratic Engel curves and consumer demand. Rev Econ Stat 79:527–539

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrett GF, Brzozowski M (2010) Using Engel curves to estimate the bias in the Australian CPI. Econ Rec 86:1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty TKM, Røed Larsen E (2005) Using Engel curves to estimate bias in the Canadian CPI as a cost of living index. Can J Econ 38(2):482–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beatty TKM, Crossley TF (2012) Lost in translation: what do Engel curves tell us about the cost of living. Unpublished manuscript, University of Minnesota, http://www.tc.umn.edu/~tbeatty/hamilton_dec_tb.pdf

  • Bee A, Meyer BD, Sullivan JX (2012) The validity of consumption data: are the consumer expenditure interview and diary surveys informative. NBER Working Paper 18308.

  • Brzozowski M, Crossley TF (2011) Viewpoint: measuring the well-being of the poor with income or consumption: a Canadian perspective. Can J Econ 44(1):88–106

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell RW, Browning M, Crawford IA (2003) Nonparametric Engel curves and revealed preference. Econometrica 71(1):205–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Pashardes P, Weber G (1993) What do we learn about consumer demand patters from micro data. Am Econ Rev 83(3):570–595

    Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Stoker TM (2005) Heterogeneity and aggregation. J Econ Lit 43(2):347–391

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell RW, Chen X, Kristensen D (2007) Semi-nonparametric IV estimation of shape-invariant Engel curves. Econometrica 75(6):1613–1669

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics (2003) Comparative Real Gross Domestic Product Per Capita and Per Employed Person. Fourteen Countries, 1960–2002. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Office of Productivity and Technology, July 29 2003

  • Bureau of Labor Statistics (2002) 2001 Consumer expenditure interview survey public use microdata documentation. US Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Division of expenditure surveys, Dec 31 2002

  • Chai A, Moneta A (2010) Retrospectives: Engel curves. J Econ Persp 24(1):225–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Charles KK, Hurst E, Roussanov N (2009) Conspicuous consumption and race. Quart J Econ 124(2):425–468

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clements KW, Chen D (2010) Affluence and food: a simple way to infer incomes. Am J Agric Econ 92(4):909–926

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa DL (2001) Estimating real income in the United States from 1888 to 1994: correcting CPI bias using Engel curves. J Pol Econ 109(6):1288–1310

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford I, Neary JP (2008) Testing for a reference consumer in international comparisons of living standards. Am Econ Rev 98(4):1731–1732

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1987) Estimation of own- and cross-price elasticities from household survey data. J Econom 36(1–2):7–30

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson J, Stillman S, Le T (2008) CPI bias and real living standards in Russia during the transition. J Dev Econ 87(1):140–160

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton B (2001) Using Engel’s law to estimate CPI bias. Am Econ Rev 91(3):619–630

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, The World Bank (2008) Global purchasing power parities and real expenditures. 2005 International Comparison Program. The World Bank, Washington DC

  • Kay JA, Keen MJ, Morris CN (1984) Estimating consumption from expenditure data. J Pub Econ 23(1–2):169–181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel A (1998) Semiparametric latent variable model estimation with endogenous or mismeasured regressors. Econometrica 66(1):105–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Logan TD (2008) Are Engel curve estimates of CPI bias biased? NBER Working Paper 13870

  • Meyer BD, Sullivan JX (2011) Viewpoint: further results on measuring the well-being of the poor using income and consumption. Can J Econ 44(1):52–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rice JA (1995) Mathematical statistics and data analysis. Wadsworth, Belmont

    Google Scholar 

  • Røed Larsen E (2009) Using inverted Engel curves to estimate material standards of living in a household. Empir Econ 36(1):109–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Røed Larsen E (2007) Does the CPI mirror the cost of living? Engel’s law suggests not in Norway. Scand J Econ 109(1):177–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Witt U (2001) Learning to consume: a theory of wants and the growth of demand. J Evol Econ 11(1):23–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I am grateful to comments and suggestions from Hilde C. Bjørnland, Terje Skjerpen, Knut Reidar Wangen, and anonymous referees. I also benefitted from discussions with Timothy Beatty and Ingvild Almås.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erling Røed Larsen.

Appendix

Appendix

Table 11 Estimating Engel curves for food for Norwegian and US income groups: food’s share of income before tax on determinants
Table 12 Non-parametric and segmented Engel curve PPP estimates
Table 13 Linear-log regressions using different definitions of food and income (t-values)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Røed Larsen, E. Is the Engel curve approach viable in the estimation of alternative PPPs?. Empir Econ 47, 881–904 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0766-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0766-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation