Skip to main content
Log in

Further results on monopolistic competition, markup pricing and the business cycle in Switzerland

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates how firms’ market power affects the price level. Based on a small macro-model it is shown empirically that firms have structural markup pricing power and take advantage of favourable business cycle fluctuations. To this aim, a multivariate time series model with double integrated variables is estimated. Thereby a model-based business cycle indicator can be derived. Its information content is confronted with survey data giving rise to what is going to be called semantic cross validation approach.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The nonlinearity is also preserved in the log-linear econometric version of the model.

  2. Refer to Table 4 in the Appendix for details of the test statistics.

  3. This result is relatively robust with respect to the variation of p. For 3≤p≤6 the largest eigenvalue is always larger than 0.95, the second and third largest are above 0.9, and the fourth does not exceed 0.78. At p=7 the four largest eigenvalues are 0.9266, 0.9266, 0.88, 0.88.

  4. An anonymous referee has pointed out that \(\widehat{\delta }_{1} \) implies an annual productivity growth rate of 1.25% which approximately matches the observed sample period’s average annual productivity growth rate.

  5. The estimation is performed with Cats in Rats.

  6. Summary statistics for residual properties are provided in Table 3.

  7. I am indebted to an anonymous referee for valuable advise on the issue.

  8. Analytically, it does not matter whether we use \( \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{\varepsilon }_{t} \) or \( \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{\varepsilon }^{*}_{t} \) although \( \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{\varepsilon }_{t} \) is easier to interpret economically. The following computations are nevertheless based on \( \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{\varepsilon }^{*}_{t} \) because it meant less programming effort.

  9. The computation is performed with Cats in Rats.

  10. Technically, the model is estimated by full information maximum likelihood with identity equations added for π t , \( \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{\varepsilon }^{*}_{t} \), \( \pi ^{*}_{t} \), Δp t , p t , Δw t and w t and then a once-off shock is given to the equation for \( \pi ^{*}_{t} \) or \( \ifmmode\expandafter\hat\else\expandafter\^\fi{\varepsilon }^{*}_{t} \), respectively.

  11. This assumption could also be dropped which would only mean a couple of more lines, yet not change the main implications.

References

  • Banerjee A, Russell B (2000) The relationship between the markup and inflation in the G7 plus one economies, Working Papers in Economics 2000/7, European University Institute Florence

  • Banerjee A, Cockerell L, Russell B (2001) An I(2) analysis of inflation and the markup. J Appl Econ 16:221–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee A, Mizen P, Russell B (2002) The long-run relationships among relative price variability, inflation and the markup, Working Paper ECO 2002/1, Economics Department, European University Institute, Florence

  • Bils M (1987) The cyclical behaviour of marginal costs and price. Am Econ Rev 77(5):838–855

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger CWJ, Jeon Y (2003) A time distance criterion for evaluating forecasting models. Int J Forecast 19(2):199–215

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1992) A representation of vector autoregressive processes integrated of order 2. Econom Theory 8:188–202

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S (1995) Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector autoregressive models, 1st edn, Oxford University Press

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen S, Lütkepohl H (2005) A note on testing restrictions for the cointegration parameters of a VAR with I(2) variables. Econom Theory 21:653–658

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kongsted HK (2005) Testing the nominal-to-real transformation, J Econom 124(2):205–395

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Kwiatkowski D, Phillips PCB, Schmidt P, Shin Y (1992) Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root: how sure are we that economic time series have a unit root? J Econom 54:159–178

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Lach F, Tsiddon D (1992) The behavior of prices and inflation: an empirical investigation, J Polit Econ 100(2):349–389

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lütkepohl H, Krätzig M (eds) (2004) Applied time series econometrics, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKinnon J (1991) Critical values for co-integration tests, In: Engle R, Granger C (eds), Long-run economic relationships, Oxford University Press, Washington, pp. 267–367

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw GN (1985) Small menu costs and large business cycles: a macroeconomic model of monopoly, Q J Econ 100:529–537

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paruolo P (1996) On the determination of integration indices in I(2) systems. J Econom 72(2):313–356

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Rahbek A, Kongstedt HC, Jørgensen C (1999) Trend-stationarity in the I(2) cointegration model, J Econom 90(2):265–289

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Stalder P (1994) Ungleichgewichte auf dem Schweizerischen Arbeitsmarkt: eine ökonometrische Analyse. Swiss J Econ Stat 130(3):445–463

    Google Scholar 

  • Stalder P (1995) Wage-price dynamics and unemployment persistence in Switzerland—the case of a small economy with a large share of foreign labour, discussion paper 47, Swiss Institute for Business Cycle Research at the Swiss Federal Institute of Technology Zürich

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christian Müller.

Appendix

Appendix

An extension of the basic economic model

We need to show that inflation can be linked to the markup. Define P t =ωP t m+(1−ω)P t c with 0≤ω≤1 and P t m, P t c are the prices in the monopolistic and the perfect competition sector of the economy, respectively. The procedure is as follows. It will be shown that the demand elasticity in the monopolistic sector is affected by changes in P t c. By assumption the firms in the competitive sector are price takers and hence are not affected by P t m.Footnote 11 Then, given that the same absolute change in the elasticity has a different impact on profits depending on the sign of the change, it is argued that the expected profit is maximised by choosing a price level that deviates from the one given in Eq. 2. Thus, the first and second derivatives of profits with respect to the demand elasticity need to be calculated and the two situations, one positive and the other with negative expectation errors are to be compared to one another. Finally, since P t is a weighted average of P t m and P t c and labour is assumed to have the same price everywhere in the economy it can be argued that the price setting behaviour of the monopolistic sector is reflected in the economy wide aggregates of prices and wages as it is done in the main text.

The demand elasticity and Pt c

First, the behavioral equations are re-stated:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\text{production}}}{Q_{t} = Q{\left( {L_{t} } \right)},}{\frac{{\partial Q}}{{\partial L_{t} }} > 0,} \\ {{\text{demand}}}{P^{m}_{t} = P^{m} {\left( {Q{\left( {L_{t} } \right)},P^{c}_{t} } \right)},}{\frac{{\partial P^{m} }}{{\partial L_{t} }} = \frac{{\partial P^{m} }}{{\partial Q}}\frac{{\partial Q}}{{\partial L_{t} }},} \\ {{\text{inverse demand}}}{Q_{t} = Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)},}{\frac{{\partial Q}}{{\partial P^{m}_{t} }} < 0,\;\frac{{\partial Q}}{{\partial P^{c}_{t} }} \gtreqless 0,} \\ {{\text{demand elasticity}}}{\eta _{t} = \eta {\left( {P^{m}_{t} ,Q_{t} } \right)},}{\eta ^{{ - 1}}_{t} , = \frac{{\partial P^{m} }}{{\partial Q}}\frac{{Q_{t} }}{{P^{m}_{t} }}\;{\text{with}}\;\eta _{t} < - 1.} \\ \end{array} $$

The optimal solution conditional on P t c is equivalent to Eq. 2:

$$ P^{m}_{t} = {\left( {1 + \eta ^{{ - 1}}_{t} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} a_{1} W^{{a_{2} }}_{t} \tau ^{{ - a_{3} }}_{t} , $$
(15)

We need to know the impact of P t c on η t :

$$ \begin{aligned} \eta _{t} = \frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{m} }}\frac{{P^{m}_{t} }} {{Q_{t} }} \\ = P^{m} {\left( {Q_{t} ,P^{c}_{t} } \right)}\frac{{\partial Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}} {{\partial P^{m} {\left( {Q_{t} ,P^{c}_{t} } \right)}Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}}, \\ \end{aligned} $$

and hence,

$$ \begin{aligned} \frac{{\partial \eta }} {{\partial P^{c} }} = \frac{{\partial P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}}} {{\partial P^{c} }}\frac{{\partial Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}} {{\partial P^{m} {\left( {Q_{t} ,P^{c}_{t} } \right)}Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}} + P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}\frac{{\partial {\left( {\frac{{\partial Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}} {{\partial P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}}} \right)}}} {{\partial P^{c} }} \\ = \frac{1} {{Q_{t} }}\frac{{\partial P^{m} }} {{\partial P^{c} }}\frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{m} }} + P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}\frac{{\partial {\left( {\frac{{\partial Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}} {{\partial P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}}}\frac{1} {{Q{\left( {P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}} \right)}}}} \right)}}} {{\partial P^{c} }} \\ = \frac{1} {{Q_{t} }}{\left[ {\frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{c} }} + P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}\frac{{\partial ^{2} Q}} {{\partial P^{m} \partial P^{c} }} - \frac{{P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}}} {{Q_{t} }}\frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{m} }}\frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{c} }}} \right]} \\ = \frac{1} {{Q_{t} }}{\left[ {\frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{c} }} + P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}\frac{{\partial ^{2} Q}} {{\partial P^{m} \partial P^{c} }} - \eta _{t} \frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{c} }}} \right]} \\ = \frac{1} {{Q_{t} }}{\left[ {\frac{{\partial Q}} {{\partial P^{c} }}{\left( {1 - \eta _{t} } \right)} + P^{m} {\left( {P^{c}_{t} } \right)}\frac{{\partial ^{2} Q}} {{\partial P^{m} \partial P^{c} }}} \right]}. \\ \end{aligned} $$
(16)

Profit maximisation with perfect foresight

Next, we need to show that profits negatively depend on η t . This is fairly simple and can be confirmed in any textbook. It is nevertheless given here again for completeness of the exposition. In Eq. 2 the profit maximising price is given in terms of the elasticity. Taking first and second derivatives with respect to η t produces:

$$ \frac{{\partial P^{m} }} {{\partial \eta }} = \frac{1} {{{\left( {1 + \eta _{t} } \right)}^{2} }} > 0 $$
(17)
$$ \frac{{\partial ^{2} P^{m} }} {{{\left( {\partial \eta } \right)}^{2} }} = \frac{{ - 2}} {{{\left( {1 + \eta _{t} } \right)}^{3} }} > 0 $$
(18)

due to η t <−1. This result does not change when we are looking at the variables in logs and therefore, the arguments hold also for the log–linear econometric model.

Maximising expected profit

After aggregating the results 16–18 we can evaluate what firms do when they do not know the realisation of P t c at the time they are planning production for the period t. Naturally, firms will formulate expectations at t−1 conditional on the information set I t−1 about P t c which we denote E t−1(P t c). Based on this value, the optimal price setting is given by Eq. 2. However, even if E t−1 (P t cE t−1(P t c))=0, firms have an incentive to deviate from Eq. 2 if the variance of the expectation error, is sufficiently large. To see this, notice that in the neighborhood of the optimal price according to Eq. 2 changes in the elasticity will have asymmetric effects on the profits. When demand becomes less elastic (Δη t >0), then profits will rise more than they would fall if demand would turn more elastic by the same absolute value. From Eq. 16 we know that deviations of P t c from its expected value can be regarded as expectation errors of η t which we denote by ϱ t . Therefore, applying Eq. 18 and using a second order Taylor approximation of P m around ϱ t =0 gives rise to

$$ P^{m} {\left( {\varrho _{t} } \right)} = P^{m} {\left( {E_{{t - 1}} {\left( {\eta _{t} } \right)}} \right)} + \frac{{\partial P^{m} }} {{\partial \eta }}\varrho _{t} + \frac{1} {2}\frac{{\partial ^{2} P^{m} }} {{{\left( {\partial \eta } \right)}^{2} }}\varrho ^{2}_{t} . $$

After taking expectations we obtain

$$ \begin{aligned} E_{{t - 1}} {\left( {P^{m} {\left( {\varrho _{t} } \right)}} \right)} = P^{m} {\left( {E_{{t - 1}} {\left( {\eta _{t} } \right)}} \right)} + \frac{{\partial P^{m} }} {{\partial \eta }}E_{{t - 1}} {\left( {\varrho _{t} } \right)} + \frac{1} {2}\frac{{\partial ^{2} P^{m} }} {{{\left( {\partial \eta } \right)}^{2} }}E_{{t - 1}} {\left( {\varrho ^{2}_{t} } \right)} \\ = P^{m} {\left( {E_{{t - 1}} {\left( {\eta _{t} } \right)}} \right)} + \frac{1} {2}\frac{{\partial ^{2} P^{m} }} {{{\left( {\partial \eta } \right)}^{2} }}Var{\left( {\varrho _{t} \left| {I_{{t - 1}} } \right.} \right)}. \\ \end{aligned} $$
(19)

Thus, when considering the uncertainty about P t c the optimal price deviates from the solution in Eq. 2 by \(\frac{1}{2}\frac{{\partial ^{2} P^{m} }}{{{\left( {\partial \eta } \right)}^{2} }}Var{\left( {\left. {\varrho _{t} } \right|I_{{t - 1}} } \right)}\) which is according to Eq. 16 linear in the variance of P t c and therefore related to inflation. In other words, independent of the reasons for variations in P t c firms will have an incentive to set prices above the solution in Eq. 2 which further enhances inflation. The next paragraph will establish the relation between inflation and the markup.

Summary of the empirical hypotheses

From Eq. 18 follows that changes in the markup trigger changes of the price level in the same direction. Shocks to the markup may arise in P t c and can have a positive, a negative, or no impact on the markup as Eq. 16 implies. However, irrespective of whether P t c has risen or fallen and whether uncertainty is allowed for or not, the induced variation in η t means a larger value for P t m than it would have been observed without a shock to P t c (see Eq. 19). Moreover, the larger the variation in the shock to P t c, and hence inflation, the larger the variance of η t and the larger the increase in P t m.

There are thus two channels by which inflation and the markup are linked. The first is the variance of shocks to η t which always leads to a rise in P t m. Since changes in the overall price level, namely due to changes in P t c may be responsible for variations in η t inflation will again result. Taken together, this implies a positive relation between inflation and the markup.

The second channel is provided by Eq. 16. For \( \frac{{\partial \eta }} {{\partial P^{c} }} < 0 \) initial changes in the overall price level will lead to a decline in η t and hence in P t m. Thus, inflationary impulses are not reinforced but muted. Naturally, for \( \frac{{\partial \eta }} {{\partial P^{c} }} > 0 \) the opposite holds.

The actual relationship between inflation and the markup, is therefore given by the relative importance of the two channels and the actual sign of \( \frac{{\partial \eta }} {{\partial P^{c} }} \). In fact, there may be a positive relation, a negative, or no relation at all. In the empirical model these possibilities are represented by γ<0, γ>0, or γ=0, respectively. We do not engage in further scrutinising the theoretically correct sign of this value but leave it as an empirical question.

Auxiliary analyses

Table 4 Univariate unit root tests

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Müller, C. Further results on monopolistic competition, markup pricing and the business cycle in Switzerland. Empirical Economics 31, 755–776 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-005-0051-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-005-0051-4

Keywords

Navigation