Skip to main content
Log in

Welfare costs of shopping trips

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Using data on the number of visitors at the store level, this paper attempts to measure the welfare costs of traditional shopping trips for the U.S. census blocks. The investigation is based on an economic model, where individuals living in census blocks decide on which store to shop from based on the shopping-trip costs and idiosyncratic benefits. The welfare gains from removing shopping-trip costs in percentage terms are shown to depend on the weighted average of log distance measures between shopping stores and census blocks. The results show that the welfare gains from removing shopping-trip costs is about 4% for the average census block, with a range between 0.021 and 18% across census blocks that is further connected to their demographic or socioeconomic characteristics, especially their population density. Several practical policy implications follow regarding how shopping-trip costs can be reduced to achieve higher welfare gains.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This statistic is borrowed from the U.S. Census Bureau for the first quarter of 2020 that is consistent with the sample period of the data set used in the empirical investigation of this paper.

  2. These welfare costs cover not only walking/riding/commuting costs but also time and opportunity costs related to shopping trips. Nevertheless, these welfare costs do not cover any costs related to those during shopping (e.g., time spent after arriving at the store). See Goolsbee and Klenow (2018) or Dolfen et al. (2019) as alternative studies focusing on costs related to those during shopping (e.g., opportunity cost of time spent during shopping).

  3. The web page is https://www.safegraph.com/.

  4. The web page is https://www.census.gov/programs-surveys/acs.

References

  • Aguiar M, Hurst E (2007) Life-cycle prices and production. Am Econ Rev 97(5):1533–1559

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ahlfeldt GM, Redding SJ, Sturm DM, Wolf N (2015) The economics of density: evidence from the Berlin Wall. Econometrica 83(6):2127–2189

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Anas A, Xu R (1999) Congestion, land use, and job dispersion: a general equilibrium model. J Urban Econ 45(3):451–473

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson JE, Van Wincoop E (2004) Trade costs. J Econ Lit 42(3):691–751

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baker SR, Johnson S, Kueng L (2021) Shopping for lower sales tax rates. Am Econ J Macroecon 13(3):209–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum-Snow N (2023) Constraints on city and neighborhood growth: the central role of housing supply. J Econ Perspect 37(2):53–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bell DR, Ho T-H, Tang CS (1998) Determining where to shop: fixed and variable costs of shopping. J Mark Res 35(3):352–369

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Billings SB, Johnson EB (2016) Agglomeration within an urban area. J Urban Econ 91:13–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brief RP (1967) Measuring shopping costs. J Ind Econ 237–241

  • DellaVigna S, Gentzkow M (2019) Uniform pricing in us retail chains. Q J Econ 134(4):2011–2084

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond R (2016) The determinants and welfare implications of US workers’ diverging location choices by skill: 1980–2000. Am Econ Rev 106(3):479–524

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond R, Gaubert C (2022) Spatial sorting and inequality. Annu Rev Econ 14:795–819

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dolfen P, Einav L, Klenow PJ, Klopack B, Levin JD, Levin L, Best W (2019) Assessing the gains from E-commerce. Working Paper 25610, National Bureau of Economic Research

  • Eeckhout J, Pinheiro R, Schmidheiny K (2014) Spatial sorting. J Polit Econ 122(3):554–620

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellickson PB, Misra S (2008) Supermarket pricing strategies. Mark Sci 27(5):811–828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Florez-Acosta J, Herrera-Araujo D (2020) Multiproduct retailing and consumer shopping behavior: the role of shopping costs. Int J Ind Organ 68:102560

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goolsbee A (2000) In a world without borders: the impact of taxes on internet commerce. Q J Econ 115(2):561–576

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goolsbee AD, Klenow PJ (2018) Internet rising, prices falling: measuring inflation in a world of e-commerce. Aea Pap Proc 108:488–92

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gyourko J, Molloy R (2015) Regulation and housing supply. In: Handbook of regional and urban economics. vol 5. Elsevier, pp 1289–1337

  • Handbury J (2021) Are poor cities cheap for everyone? Non-homotheticity and the cost of living across US cities. Econometrica 89(6):2679–2715

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman J, Leibtag E (2007) Consumer benefits from increased competition in shopping outlets: measuring the effect of Wal-Mart. J Appl Economet 22(7):1157–1177

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Heblich S, Redding SJ, Sturm DM (2020) The making of the modern metropolis: evidence from London. Q J Econ 135(4):2059–2133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh C-T, Moretti E (2019) Housing constraints and spatial misallocation. Am Econ J Macroecon 11(2):1–39

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang Y, Bronnenberg BJ (2021) Consumer transportation costs and the value of E-commerce: evidence from the Dutch apparel industry. Available at SSRN 3596460. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3596460

  • Hummels DL, Schaur G (2013) Time as a trade barrier. Am Econ Rev 103(7):2935–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hunneman A, Verhoef PC, Sloot LM (2017) The moderating role of shopping trip type in store satisfaction formation. J Bus Res 78:133–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Konishi H (2005) Concentration of competing retail stores. J Urban Econ 58(3):488–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lai EL-C, Fan H, Qi HS (2020) Global gains from reduction in trade costs. Econ Theor 70(1):313–345

    Article  ADS  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall G, Pires T (2018) Measuring the impact of travel costs on grocery shopping. Econ J 128(614):2538–2557

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ, Redding SJ (2014) Missing gains from trade? Am Econ Rev 104(5):317–21

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monte F, Redding SJ, Rossi-Hansberg E (2018) Commuting, migration, and local employment elasticities. Am Econ Rev 108(12):3855–90

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sun Y, Lian F, Yang Z-Z (2021) Optimizing the location of physical shopping centers under the clicks-and-mortar retail mode. Environ Dev Sustain 1–27

  • Thomassen Ø, Smith H, Seiler S, Schiraldi P (2017) Multi-category competition and market power: a model of supermarket pricing. Am Econ Rev 107(8):2308–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tiwari P, Doi M, Kawakami T (2006) Analysis of household leisure and shopping behavior in Ibaraki Prefecture, Japan. In Review of urban & regional development studies: journal of the applied regional science conference, vol 18. Wiley Online Library, pp 165–178

  • Yilmazkuday H (2011) Agglomeration and trade: state-level evidence from US industries. J Reg Sci 51(1):139–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yilmazkuday H (2016) Constant versus variable markups: implications for the law of one price. Int Rev Econ Finance 44:154–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yilmazkuday H (2021) Welfare implications of solving the distance puzzle: global evidence from the last two centuries. J Int Trade Econ Dev 30(4):469–483

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The author would like to thank the editor Hong Sok Brian Kim and an anonymous referee for their helpful comments and suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hakan Yilmazkuday.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendix

Appendix

This section contains the technical derivations of certain results in the main text.

1.1 A1 Derivation of the expected utility

The number of individuals living in each location is fixed. Each individual living in any location chooses the shopping store that offers the maximum utility. Since the maximum of a sequence of Fréchet distributed random variables is itself Fréchet distributed, the distribution of utility for individuals living in census block b across all possible shopping stores is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} 1-G_{b}\left( u\right) =1- \prod \limits _{s} e^{-\Psi _{bs}u^{-\theta }} \end{aligned}$$
(25)

where the left-hand side is the probability that an individual of census block b gets a utility higher than u, and the right hand side is one minus the probability that the individual of census block b has utility less than u for all possible shopping locations. It is implied that:

$$\begin{aligned} G_{b}\left( u\right) =e^{-\Psi _{b}u^{-\theta }} \end{aligned}$$
(26)

where

$$\begin{aligned} \Psi _{b}=\sum _{s}\Psi _{bs} \end{aligned}$$
(27)

Given this Fréchet distribution for utility in census block b, the expected utility \({\overline{U}}_{b}\) in census block b is implied as:

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{U}}_{b}= {\displaystyle \int \limits _{0}^{\infty }} \theta \Psi _{b}u^{-\theta }e^{-\Psi _{b}u^{-\theta }}dy \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Defining the following change of variables:

$$\begin{aligned} y=\Psi _{b}u^{-\theta } \end{aligned}$$
(29)

and

$$\begin{aligned} dy=\theta e^{-\Psi _{b}u^{-\left( \theta +1\right) }} \end{aligned}$$
(30)

the expected utility can be rewritten as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{U}}_{b}= {\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }} \left( \Psi _{b}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\theta }}y^{-\frac{1}{\theta }}e^{-y}du \end{aligned}$$
(31)

which is:

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{U}}_{i}=\left( \Psi _{b}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\theta }}\Gamma \left( 1-\frac{1}{\theta }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Using \(\Psi _{b}=\sum _{s}\Psi _{bs}\), it is finally implied that:

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{U}}_{b}=\left( \sum _{s}\Psi _{bs}\right) ^{\frac{1}{\theta }} \Gamma \left( 1-\frac{1}{\theta }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(33)

which is the expression for expected utility in the main text.

1.2 A2 Derivation of shopping store probabilities

The probability that an individual of census block b chooses to shop at store s out of all possible shopping locations (represented by r) is as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{bs}&=\Pr \left[ u_{bs}\ge \max \left\{ u_{br}\right\} ;\forall r\right] \nonumber \\&= {\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }} {\prod \limits _{r\ne s}} G_{br}\left( u\right) dG_{bs}\left( u\right) \nonumber \\&= {\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }} {\prod \limits _{r}} \theta \Psi _{bs}u^{-\left( \theta +1\right) }e^{-\Psi _{br}u^{-\theta } }du\nonumber \\&= {\int \limits _{0}^{\infty }} \theta \Psi _{bs}u^{-\left( \theta +1\right) }e^{-\Psi _{b}u^{-\theta } }du \end{aligned}$$
(34)

Since we have:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d}{du}\left[ -\frac{1}{\Psi _{b}}e^{-\Psi _{b}u^{-\theta }}\right] =\theta u^{-\left( \theta +1\right) }e^{-\Psi _{b}u^{-\theta }} \end{aligned}$$
(35)

it is implied that:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{bs}=\frac{\Psi _{bs}}{\Psi _{b}}=\frac{A_{bs}\left( P_{s}\tau _{bs}\right) ^{-\theta }\left( W_{b}\right) ^{\theta }}{\sum _{r}A_{br}\left( P_{r}\tau _{br}\right) ^{-\theta }\left( W_{b}\right) ^{\theta }}=\frac{A_{bs}\left( P_{s}\tau _{bs}\right) ^{-\theta }}{\sum _{r}A_{br}\left( P_{r}\tau _{br}\right) ^{-\theta }} \end{aligned}$$
(36)

where the last expression, which is the same as in in the main text, has been obtained after \(\left( W_{b}\right) ^{\theta }\)’s have been effectively eliminated.

1.3 A3 Derivation of welfare changes

As shown in the main text, the welfare (expected utility) \({\overline{U}}_{b}\) of an individual living in census block b is given by the following expression:

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{U}}_{b}=\left( \sum _{s}A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }\right) ^{\frac{1}{\theta }}\Gamma \left( 1-\frac{1}{\theta }\right) \end{aligned}$$
(37)

Taking the total derivative of this expression can be achieved as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} d{\overline{U}}_{b}=\sum _{s}\frac{\partial {\overline{U}}_{b}}{\partial A_{bs} }dA_{bs}+\sum _{s}\frac{\partial {\overline{U}}_{b}}{\partial Z_{s}}dZ_{s} +\sum _{s}\frac{\partial {\overline{U}}_{b}}{\partial \tau _{bs}}d\tau _{bs} \end{aligned}$$
(38)

When average benefits \(A_{bs}\)’s and productivity measures \(Z_{s}\)’s are unchanged (i.e., \(dA_{bs}=dZ_{s}=0\)), this expression can be simplified as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} d{\overline{U}}_{b}=\sum _{s}\frac{\partial {\overline{U}}_{b}}{\partial \tau _{bs} }d\tau _{bs} \end{aligned}$$
(39)

which can be rewritten as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} d{\overline{U}}_{b}&=\sum _{s}\frac{1}{\theta }\frac{{\overline{U}}_{b}\left( \frac{-\theta }{\tau _{bs}}A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }\right) }{\left( \sum _{s}A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s} }\right) ^{-\theta }\right) }d\tau _{bs}\nonumber \\&=-\sum _{s}\frac{{\overline{U}}_{b}\left( A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs} }{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }\right) }{\left( \sum _{s}A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }\right) }\frac{d\tau _{bs}}{\tau _{bs} } \end{aligned}$$
(40)

Taking \({\overline{U}}_{b}\) to the left-hand side results in:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d{\overline{U}}_{b}}{{\overline{U}}_{b}}=-\sum _{s}\frac{\left( A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }\right) }{\left( \sum _{s}A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }\right) }\frac{d\tau _{bs}}{\tau _{bs}} \end{aligned}$$
(41)

which can be rewritten as follows:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d{\overline{U}}_{b}}{{\overline{U}}_{b}}=-\sum _{s}\lambda _{bs}\frac{d\tau _{bs}}{\tau _{bs}} \end{aligned}$$
(42)

as the expenditure share of \(\lambda _{bs}=\frac{A_{bs}\left( P_{s}\tau _{bs}\right) ^{-\theta }}{\sum _{r}A_{br}\left( P_{r}\tau _{br}\right) ^{-\theta }}\) in the main text can be rewritten as \(\lambda _{bs}=\frac{A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }}{\sum _{s} A_{bs}\left( \frac{\tau _{bs}}{Z_{s}}\right) ^{-\theta }}\) by using \(P_{s}=\frac{W}{Z_{s}}\) in the main text. Finally, using \(\frac{dx}{x}\approx d\log x\), the following expression can be obtained:

$$\begin{aligned} d\log {\overline{U}}_{b}=-\sum _{s}\lambda _{bs}d\log \tau _{bs} \end{aligned}$$
(43)

which represents welfare changes as in the main text.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor (e.g. a society or other partner) holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yilmazkuday, H. Welfare costs of shopping trips. Ann Reg Sci (2024). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-024-01258-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-024-01258-1

JEL Classification

Navigation