Evidence for preference-based sorting
In this subsection we examine the difference in commuting preferences between telecommuters and non-telecommuters. We do this by estimating the effect of commuting time on job search and the propensity to change jobs, for both groups. We standardize this effect by the effects of wage on job search and mobility to obtain the marginal costs of one-way commuting time (MCC), measured as the average amount of daily wage people are willing to give up to shorten their (one-way) commute with 1 min (Van Ommeren and Fosgerau 2009). First, in Fig. 3 we show the bivariate relationship between commuting time and job search and mobility for the whole sample. It is clear that both the share of people looking for a job and the share of people changing jobs within 2 years are positively related with commuting time. This confirms the intuitive notion that longer commutes are seen as a negative aspect of jobs.Footnote 9
In Table 3 we estimate the daily MCC using the two distinct approaches. We follow the literature and use a random effects probit model to deal with potential heterogeneity among different individuals.Footnote 10 According to the job search model in column (1) commuting time has a greater effect on job search for telecommuters than for non-telecommuters. In monetary terms, non-telecommuters are willing to accept a 1 min longer one-way commute for €2.63 per work day, while telecommuters are willing to accept a 1 min longer commute for €3.80.Footnote 11 Note that this is in spite of the fact that, by definition, telecommuters commute less frequently, compared to non-telecommuters, so the MCC per commuting trip may be even higher for telecommuters. Furthermore, according to this model age has a positive but marginally decreasing effect on the propensity to search, and higher educated people search more. The effect of telecommuting itself is insignificant.
Table 3 Willingness to pay for commuting regressions
In column (2) we estimate the same model with job mobility (changing jobs within 2 years) as the dependent variable. According to this model the MCC is €1.91 for non-telecommuters, and €2.15 for telecommuters. These values are lower than the estimates in the previous model. The ratio between these values is also lower (1.13 vs. 1.44). According to this model the effect of age on mobility is predominantly negative, and higher educated people seem more mobile, but not significantly so. The effect of telecommuting itself on job moving is not significant.
In conclusion, this part of the analysis shows that the MCC is between 13 and 44% higher on average for telecommuters, in spite of the fact that their commuting frequency is lower. Therefore, it is established that preferences of telecommuters differ significantly from non-telecommuters in terms of commuting tolerance. More specifically, if there was only sorting based on commuting preferences, not taking into account these preferences when analyzing the effect of telecommuting on commuting time would lead to underestimation of the real effect. We find no evidence that telecommuting is a positive job asset in itself.
Commuting time
In this subsection we estimate the effect of telecommuting on commuting time, controlling for preference-based sorting by employing individual fixed effects. We start with an OLS model, and we compare the resulting estimates with the results of a fixed effects model. Because the dependent variable is in logs, 187 observations with 0 commuting time are excluded from the analysis, so we are left with 18,543 observations.
Table 4 shows the OLS results. In column (1) we use a telecommuting dummy that corresponds to our telecommuting definition. According to this model telecommuting results in a 11.7% longer commute on average.Footnote 12 Furthermore, a 10% increase in daily wage is associated with a 4.8% increase in commuting time, the level of education has a positive effect on commuting time, commuting patterns are gendered (women have about 7.6% shorter commutes), and individuals with children at home have about 7% shorter commutes. Except for the insignificant effect of age, these findings are in line with earlier results on Dutch commuting behaviour, which showed that females, and people with children, have shorter commutes on average, and people of higher socio-economic status commute longer (Van Ham 2002; Burger et al. 2014). Employees of larger firms commute longer according to this model.
Table 4 OLS commuting time regressions
In column (2) we distinguish between 1, 2, 3, and more than 3 days of telecommuting per month. The results show that the positive effect found in the previous column is mainly driven by telecommuters that telecommute 2–4 days per month, as the effect of telecommuting 1 day per month is small and insignificant. The coefficients of the other variables are virtually unaffected by this alternative measure of telecommuting. In column (3) we measure telecommuting by the usual number of hours per week spent telecommuting. Arguably this is the most precise measure of telecommuting intensity. According to the model every 8 additional hours of telecommuting lead to a 5.2% increase in commuting time. The other coefficients are again similar to those in previous models.
In Table 5 we estimate the same models including individual specific fixed effects that correct for all time-invariant attributes of individuals, including preferences. Coefficients are estimated based on variation within individuals over time. The results from column (1) indicate that telecommuting leads to 5% longer commutes, rather than the 11.7% estimated in column one. Thus, the extent of the bias due to sorting is positive (+ 128%) according to this specification. The fixed effects model results in several different coefficients compared to the OLS estimates. First, the effect of daily wage on commuting time is lower when accounting for time-invariant unobservables. This may for instance be driven by correlations between capability and labour mobility. Second, it seems that ageing does not significantly influence commuting time. Third, changes in firm size and having children at home have significant but smaller effects on commuting time, compared to the OLS model. Finally, while we see an increasing pattern in the effects of education on commuting, the estimates are not significant.
Table 5 FE commuting time regressions
Column (2) is the fixed effects equivalent of Table 4, column (2). The results from this column show that compared to non-telecommuters, individuals that telecommute 1 day per month accept a 6.1% longer commute, those telecommuting 2 days per month a similar but lower 5.1%, those that telecommute 3 days do not have significantly longer commutes. This result is somewhat counter-intuitive as it suggests positive but decreasing effect of telecommuting on commuting time. It should, however, be noted that the only significant difference in coefficients between consecutive categories is the one between no telecommuting and telecommuting 1 day per month. Other coefficients in this model are similar to those in the previous column.
Finally, in column (3) we estimate the effect of (changes in) the usual weekly hours spent telecommuting on (changes in) commuting time. The effect is estimated at a 3.5% increase in commuting time for every 8 additional weekly hours spent working at home, indicating a 50% upward bias due to preference-based sorting in the OLS estimate in column (3), Table 4.
From the analyses in this subsection we conclude that telecommuting significantly affects commuting time and overall, the bias induced by preference-based sorting of individuals into telecommuting is positive rather than negative, between 50 and 128%.Footnote 13 An explanation for this may be that overall, the (negative) bias induced by residential preferences is stronger than the (positive) bias due to commuting preferences. According to our results telecommuting allows people to accept 5% longer commutes on average, and for every 8 additional weekly hours spent working from home, people accept a 3.5% longer commute.
Sensitivity analysis
In this subsection we subject our results to several sensitivity checks. We employ a stricter identification approach based on the timing and intensity of telecommuting, and two alternative identification approaches using a Lagged Dependent Variable Model and a Long Difference model.
First, we analyze individuals that telecommuted at some point during the study period. For these individuals we know that they are able to telecommute, so the decision of whether or not to telecommute, and for how many days and hours, suffers less from potentially omitted variables and self-selection. The drawback of this approach is that the external validity of the results is limited, because the effects we obtain in principle only apply to those able to telecommute. The results of these timing regressions, presented in Table 6, “Appendix A”, are comparable to the estimates from Table 5.
Second, we use an identification method based on a lagged dependent variable, proposed by Angrist and Pischke (2008) as a robustness check for fixed effects models. Specifically, instead of assuming that telecommuting is randomly assigned across respondents conditional on unobserved time-invariant characteristics, this method assumes random assignment conditional on the 1 year lag of commuting distance. Checking the robustness of our results to this assumption makes sense because commuting time is time-varying, and those who start to telecommute may do so because over time, they have become tired of their long commute. This method thus corrects for a different type of selection bias (based on commuting history), and as Angrist and Pischke (2008) note, the results of fixed effects and lagged dependent variable models can be regarded as bounding the effect of interest, depending on the type of selection bias that is controlled for. In Table 7 we show the results of the models based on this identification strategy, and it is reassuring that the outcomes of this analysis are remarkably similar to the estimates from Table 5.
Third, we estimate a “long-differences” model in which we only include the first and last year of our data, controlling for time-invariant characteristics of respondents. This approach is only based on 516 respondents for whom we have data for both years. The idea behind this robustness check is that it takes time to get used to new technologies and situations, and to adjust behaviour in housing and labour markets. The results, presented in Table 8, suggest that our estimates based on short-run behaviour may be somewhat conservative. Respondents that have picked up telecommuting between 2002 and 2014 have on average 32% longer commuting times, and every 8 h increase in weekly telecommuting hours during this period resulted in 20.5% longer commuting times. It should, however, not be ruled out that these high estimates are the result of sample selection effect: respondents with high residential mobility are less likely to be contacted over multiple years, but they are more prone to shorten their commutes by moving residence (Van Ommeren 1998).
Finally, we investigate whether there are nonlinearities in the effect of hours working from home on commuting time. We do this by estimating a dummy specification, in which the variable denoting weekly hours spent working from home is divided up into 7 categories (0, 0–8, 8–16, 16–24, 42–32, 32–40, and 40+). The model, presented in the column (1) of Table 9 in “Appendix A”, is an alternative version of Table 5 column (3), and the marginal effects of the dummies are depicted in Fig. 4. While the graph does not show significant effects of telecommuting categories 16–24 and 32–40, the overall pattern of point estimates follows a somewhat linear pattern, at least up until the 24–32 h mark. Considering the observed pattern, and the significance of the other dummies, we may conclude that the parametric approach in Table 5 column (3) is a reasonable approximation of the nonparametrically estimated shape of the relationship, and as it is more efficient it has our preference. In Table 9 columns (2–4) we show the results of this dummy specification using the other identification strategies, and in all specifications the pattern is roughly linear until 24–32 h.
In conclusion, the main result—that the effect of telecommuting on commuting time remains positive after controlling for sorting—is robust to identification based on the timing and intensity of telecommuting, and to an identification strategy based on a lagged dependent variable. A “long-difference” model suggests our estimates are somewhat conservative, and a linear specification of average weekly hours working from home is not problematic.