Skip to main content
Log in

On the definition of W in empirical models of yardstick competition

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Theoretical models of strategic interaction between local governments are often implemented empirically using spatial econometric techniques. In order to empirically discriminate between different theoretical explanations for strategic interactions, it is important to ensure that the spatial weights matrix W reflects the theoretical mechanisms behind the interaction of interest. However, researchers do not usually have the information required to adequately define its elements in such a way. Here, we present a method for defining these elements that captures the interest of one jurisdiction’s inhabitants in the local politics of their neighboring jurisdictions even when this information is not directly available to the researcher. The method is suitable for use in empirical models of strategic interaction between local jurisdictions and can be used to define spatial weights matrices for spatial econometric models that will be used to test or control for yardstick competition across jurisdictions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. This is a simplification. There are of course situations where inhabitants in jurisdiction \(j\) benefit from road expenditures in jurisdiction \(i\) even in the absence of direct road connections between the two jurisdictions.

  2. In general, the definition of the elements in the spatial weights matrix (the definition of neighbors) is often neglected or at least not sufficiently discussed in spatial econometric analyses. This is quite surprising because the interpretation and sometimes the significance of the spatial effect depends on the definition of the spatial weights matrix.

  3. That is, provided that we accept the relative populations of the two jurisdictions to be exogenous, which is reasonable in models of yardstick competition where migration is disregarded.

  4. The covariance matrix for the empirical model developed from the responses was corrected to reflect the fact that answers from an individual respondent could not be considered to be independent from one another. The estimation was also weighted by the proportion of answers obtained from each municipality in relation to the municipality’s population.

  5. The Umeå region consists of six municipalities including Umeå itself, and the Gothenburg region consists of 13 municipalities including Gothenburg itself. The Gothenburg area is the second largest metropolitan area in Sweden, with about 1.2 million inhabitants (about 500.000 of whom live in Gothenburg). The Umeå region represents a typical medium-sized Swedish region and has around 145.000 inhabitants (about 115.000 of whom live in Umeå). Almost 90 % of the Swedish population lives within areas of one of these two types, and around 35 % live in a major city region such as Gothenburg.

  6. We also estimated a logarithmic version of Eq. (4) that gave basically identical results to those presented in the paper.

  7. This is done based on the estimated probabilities from the ordered probit models. For the binomial models, the appropriate calculations would be \( w_{ij}=\Pr (y_{ij}=1)\), and \(w_{ij}=0\) if \(\Pr (y_{ij}=0)>\Pr (y_{ij}=1)\) while \(w_{ij}=1\) if \(\Pr (y_{ij}=1)>\Pr (y_{ij}=0)\).

References

  • Anselin L (1988) Spatial econometrics: methods and models. Kluwer Academic Publisher, Dordrecht

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Case A (1995) Incumbent behavior: vote seeking, tax setting and yardstick competition. Am Econ Rev 82:25–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Besley T, Smart M (2002) Does tax competition raise voter welfare? CEPR Discussion Paper No 3131

  • Brett C, Pinkse J (2000) The determinants of municipal tax rates in British Columbia. Can J Econ 33:695–714

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner J (2003) Strategic interaction among governments: an overview of empirical studies. Int Reg Sci Rev 26:175–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brueckner JK, Saavedra LA (2001) Do local governments engage in strategic property tax competition? J Urban Econ 54:203–229

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruns C, Himmler O (2011) Newspaper circulation and local government efficiency. Scand J Econ 113(2):470–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Case A, Hines J, Rosen H (1993) Budget spillovers and fiscal policy interdependence. J Public Econ 52:285–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Esteller-Moré A, Solé-Ollé A (2001) Vertical income tax externalities and fiscal interdependence. Evidence from the US. Reg Sci Urban Econ 31:247–272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glenn ND, Grimes M (1968) Aging, voting, and political interest. Am Sociol Rev 33(4):563–575

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayashi M, Boadway R (2001) An empirical analysis of intergovernmental tax interaction: the case of business income taxes in Canada. Can J Econ 34(2):481–503

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horrigan J, Garrett K, Resnick P (2004) The internet and democratic debate. Pew Internet and American life Project, Washington

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundberg J (2006) A spatial interaction model of benefit spillovers from locally provided public services. Reg Stud 40(6):1–14

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski C (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60:531–542

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli F (2001) Spatial patterns in local taxation: tax mimicking or error mimicking? Appl Econ 33:1101–1107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli F (2003) Reaction or interaction? Spatial process identification in multi-tiered government structures. J Urban Econ 53:29–53

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Revelli F (2005) On spatial public finance empirics. Int Tax Public Financ 12:475–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rincke J (2010) A commuting-based refinement of the contiguity matrix for spatial models, and an application to local police expenditures. Reg Sci Urban Econ 40:324–330

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Salmon P (1987) Decentralisation as an incentive scheme. Oxf Rev Econ Policy 3:24–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shields TG, Goidel RK (1997) Participation rates, socioeconomic class biases, and congressional elections: a crossvalidation. Am J Polit Sci 41(2):683–691

    Google Scholar 

  • Verba S, Schlozman K, Brady H (1995) Voice and equality: civic voluntarism in American politics. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

Download references

Acknowledgments

I’m grateful to the anonymous referee as well as the editor of this journal for constructive and useful comments. Special thanks also to Niklas Hanes, Chris Hudson, Anders Lidström, Sofia Lundberg, Elon Strömbäck, Emma Zetterdahl, Kerstin Westin, seminar participants at Umeå University and ERSA congress in Barcelona 2011 for valuable comments on previous versions of this paper. A research grant from Riksbankens Jubileumsfond is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johan Lundberg.

Appendix

Appendix

See Appendix Tables 678 and 9.

Table 6 Marginal effects corresponding to Model 1
Table 7 Marginal effects corresponding to Model 2
Table 8 Marginal effects corresponding to Model 3
Table 9 Marginal effects

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Lundberg, J. On the definition of W in empirical models of yardstick competition. Ann Reg Sci 52, 597–610 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0602-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0602-8

JEL Classification

Navigation