Skip to main content
Log in

The neighborhood or the region? Reassessing the density–wage relationship using geocoded data

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

I analyze the effects of sub-city-level density of economic activity on wages. Using a geocoded dataset on employment and wages in the city areas of Sweden, the analysis is based on squares representing “neighborhoods” (\(0.0625\,\hbox {km}^{2})\), “districts” (\(1\,\hbox {km}^{2})\), and “agglomerations” (\(10\,\hbox {km}^{2})\). The wage-density elasticity depends on spatial resolution, with the elasticity being highest in neighborhood squares, where a doubling of density is associated with wage increases of 1.2 %, or roughly the size of the elasticity for region density. Moving from a mean-density neighborhood to the densest neighborhood would on average increase wages by 9 %. The results are consistent with (i) the existence of a localized density spillover effect and (ii) quite sharp attenuation of human capital spillovers. An implication of the findings is that if the data source is not sufficiently disaggregated, analyses of the density–wage link risk understating the benefits of working in dense parts of regions, such as the central business districts.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Wages and productivity are not equalized, but the underlying identifying assumption is that firms that incur higher costs (wages) must be more productive to stay competitive and survive.

  2. Technically, each square originates from a coordinate associated with an active employer. By construction, the square grid does not cover the entire geography, but only places with registered economic activity.

  3. The fact that all squares are of the same size within regressions means that no normalization is needed to obtain an exact measure of density. This feature makes interpretation of the coefficients particularly straightforward.

  4. The importance of accounting for sorting on unobservables in studies of agglomeration economies is illustrated in Combes et al. (2008), and in Andersson et al. (2013).

  5. Sweden has three metropolitan regions: Stockholm (population 2.2 m), Gothenburg (population 1 m), and Malmö (population 0.7 m), the city areas of which are sparser than most of the metropolitan areas of the United States. The Stockholm city area has about 3,500 inhabitants per square kilometer, or just short of 10,000 inhabitants per square mile, which would put it somewhere outside of the top 100 MSAs in the United States in terms of population density.

  6. The neighborhood squares are used as a base, from which higher-level resolutions are obtained by spatial aggregation.

  7. Incidentally, Combes et al. (2008) truncate their data for the same reason, using a 3 % cutoff. Adopting that cutoff would not change anything substantial in practice, and nothing in terms of conclusions.

  8. Technically, using yearly wages may be a source of bias in an OLS setting under the assumption that workers in dense areas work longer hours than workers in sparsely populated areas, where a wage-differential unmatched by productivity differences would be observed. In a fixed effects setting, this is a smaller problem, since bias would only be introduced in the parameters to the extent that workers in dense areas work increasingly longer hours, relative to workers in sparse areas during the reporting period, and to the extent that such a phenomenon is not picked up by any of the time-variant variables.

References

  • Alonso W (1960) A theory of the urban land market. Pap Reg Sci 6(1):149–157

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson M, Johansson B (2012) Regional policy as change management—a theoretical discussion with empirical illustrations. In: Rickne A, Laestadius S, Etzkowitz H (eds) Innovation governance in an open economy: shaping regional nodes in a globalized world. Routledge, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson M, Klaesson J, Larsson JP (2012) How local are spatial density externalities? Evidence from square grid data. CIRCLE working paper 2012/10

  • Andersson M, Klaesson J, Larsson JP (2013) The sources of the urban wage premium by worker skills—spatial sorting or agglomeration economies? Papers in regional science (forthcoming)

  • Angrist JD, Krueger AB (1991) Does compulsory schooling attendance affect schooling and earnings? Q J Econ 106:976–1014

    Google Scholar 

  • Arzaghi M, Henderson JV (2008) Networking off madison avenue. Rev Econ Stud 75(4):1011–1038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Capello R (2002) Entrepreneurship and spatial externalities: theory and measurement. Ann Reg Sci 36(3):387–402

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone A, Hall RE (1996) Productivity and the density of economic activity. Am Econ Rev 86(1):54–70

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes P-P, Duranton G, Gobillon L (2008) Spatial wage disparities: sorting matters! J Urban Econ 63(2):723–742

    Google Scholar 

  • Combes P-P, Duranton G, Gobillon L, Roux S (2007) Estimating agglomeration economies with history, geology and worker effects. In: Glaeser EL (ed) Agglomeration economics. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G, Puga D (2004) Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In: Henderson V, Thisse J-F (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics, vol 4. North Holland, Amsterdam, pp 2017–2063

    Google Scholar 

  • Frenken K, Van Oort F, Verburg T (2007) Related variety, unrelated variety and regional economic growth. Reg Stud 41(5):685–697

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gennaioli N, La Porta R, Lopez-de-Silanes F, Shleifer A (2013) Human capital and regional development. Q J Econ 128(1):105–164

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser EL (1999) Learning in cities. J Urban Econ 46(2):254–277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser EL (2000) The future of urban research: nonmarket interactions [with comments]. Brookings-Wharton papers on urban affairs, pp 101–149. doi:10.2307/25067375

  • Glaeser EL, Maré DC (2001) Cities and skills. J Labor Econ 19(2):316–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris CD (1954) The market as a factor in the localization of industry in the US. Ann Assoc Am Geogr 44:315–348

    Google Scholar 

  • Helsley RW, Strange WC (1990) Matching and agglomeration economies in a system of cities. Reg Sci Urban Econ 20(2):189–212. doi:10.1016/0166-0462(90)90004-m

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansson B, Klaesson J, Olsson M (2003) Commuters’ non-linear response to time distances. J Geogr Syst 5(3):315–329. doi:10.1007/s10109-003-0111-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic B, Rob R (1989) The growth and diffusion of knowledge. Rev Econ Stud 56(4):569–582

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koster HRA, van Ommeren J, Rietveld P (2013) Is the sky the limit? High-rise buildings and office rents. J Econ Geogr (forthcoming)

  • Mas A, Moretti E (2009) Peers at work. Am Econ Rev 99(1):112–145

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J (1974) Schooling, experience and earnings. National Bureau of Economics Research, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Openshaw S (1984) The modifiable areal unit problem. Geo Books, Norwich

    Google Scholar 

  • Openshaw S, Taylor PJ (1979) A million or so correlation coefficients: three experiments on the modifiable areal unit problem. In: Wrigley N (ed) Statistical applications in the spatial sciences. Pion, London, pp 127–144

  • Rauch JE (1993) Productivity gains from geographic concentration of human capital: evidence from the cities. J Urban Econ 34(3):380–400. doi:10.1006/juec.1993.1042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal SS, Strange WC (2001) The determinants of agglomeration. J Urban Econ 50(2):191–229. doi:10.1006/juec2001.2230

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal SS, Strange WC (2008) The attenuation of human capital spillovers. J Urban Econ 64(2):373–389. doi:10.1016/j.jue.2008.02.006

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storper M, Venables AJ (2004) Buzz: face-to-face contact and the urban economy. J Econ Geogr 4(4): 351–370

    Google Scholar 

  • Strange WC (2009) Viewpoint: agglomeration research in the age of disaggregation. Canad J Econ Rev Canad d’Econ 42(1):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wellman B (1996) Are personal communities local? A dumptarian reconsideration. Soc Netw 18(4):347–354

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This research has been supported by a financial grant from the Swedish Research Council for Environment, Agricultural Sciences and Spatial Planning (FORMAS).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Johan P. Larsson.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Larsson, J.P. The neighborhood or the region? Reassessing the density–wage relationship using geocoded data. Ann Reg Sci 52, 367–384 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0590-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-014-0590-8

JEL Classification

Navigation