Skip to main content
Log in

Locational disadvantage of the hub

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
The Annals of Regional Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We show how spatial evolution is different between the two representative models of economic geography: [Krugman 99:483–499, 1991] and [Ottaviano et al. 43:409–436, 2002]. We analyze the impacts of falling transport costs on the spatial distribution of economic activities and welfare for a network economy consisting of three regions located on a line. It is normally considered that a hub city, i.e., a central region, always has locational advantage and manufacturing workers gain from trade. This is true in the former model, but not in the latter when markets are opened up to trade. This is because the price competition is so keen in the central region that the manufacturing sector moves to the peripheral regions, which aggravates the social welfare. We then show that when goods are close substitutes and share of manufacturing is of an intermediate level, the manufacturing activities completely disappear from the central region leading to a full agglomeration in one peripheral region.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In a different setting, De Fraja and Norman (1993) analytically show that duopolistic firms always cluster at the market center, where consumers are uniformly distributed over a line segment.

  2. \(n_{r}\) coincides with \(n\) in the presence of trade in this section, but not necessarily in the next section.

  3. When \(T\rightarrow \infty \), the simultaneous Eq. 4 degenerates into:

    $$Y_{r} {\left( {G_{r} } \right)}^{{\sigma - 1}} = w^{\sigma }_{{\text{r}}} ,Y_{r} = 3^{{ - 1}} {\left( {\mu w_{r} + 1 - \mu } \right)},G_{r} = 3^{{\frac{1}{{1 - \sigma }}}} w_{r} $$

    which yields \(w_{r}=1\) for all \(r\).

  4. The same proposition holds using a similar model of Forslid and Ottaviano (2003).

  5. The stable equilibrium path in this paper is different from a dynamic equilibrium path in macroeconomics.

  6. Alternatively, \(\tau \) may be regarded as the costs of loading and unloading a unit good between neighboring regions. In the network economy, each good should be unloaded and loaded at the center of a port city in transporting it from one periphery to the other.

  7. Such a bell-shaped relationship between the transport costs and spatial distribution is reminiscent of the Hotelling’s model with logit (Anderson et al. 1992, Chap. 9.4).

  8. Note however that hub regions sometimes change in the long history. For example, while the hub ports of Europe were Venice and Bruges in the 12th century, the economic center was gradually moving to the plain of Champagne, the middle point between the ports, in the 13th century, as documented by Pirenne (1969).

  9. The manufacturing shares of value of shipments in Nagoya MA (Aichi and Mie prefectures), Tokyo MA (Tokyo and Kanagawa), and Osaka MA (Osaka and Hyogo) were 9.4, 14.9, and 30%, respectively in 1909. The shares in Nagoya MA, Tokyo MA, and Osaka MA were 8.5, 26.2, and 21.7% in 1940, and 14.1, 13.3, and 10.8%, respectively in 2000.

  10. The two models differ in the existence of marginal input requirement \(c\). However, it can be readily shown that introduction of marginal input requirement into the OTT model does not alter the result.

  11. This is what Brander and Krugman (1983) and Clarke and Collie (2003) have obtained. Note, however, that the former is Cournot duopoly and the latter is Bertrand duopoly, whereas ours a is monopolistic competition with a continuum of firms producing differentiated goods.

  12. The US had been the center of the automobile industry in terms of production (export) and consumption (import) until World War II. However, Japan’s car exports to the US increased 14-fold between 1967 and 1973. Japan was exporting 31% of its total production in 1973 and captured 21% of the total vehicle market of the US in 1981. Although consumers in the US would gain from trade, automobile firms were severely damaged. The US administration therefore proposed a voluntary restraint agreement in 1980 to reduce losses from trade by raising trade costs (Howes 1993).

References

  • Ago T, Isono I, T Tabuchi (2003) Locational disadvantage and losses from trade: three regions in economic geography. CIRJE Discussion Paper CF-224, University of Tokyo

  • Anas A (2004) Vanishing cities: what does the new economic geography imply about the efficiency of urbanization? Journal of Economic Geography 4:181–199

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, de Palma A, J-F Thisse (1992) Discrete choice theory of product differentiation. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson SP, Schmitt N, J-F Thisse (1995) Who benefits from antidumping legislation? J Int Econ 38:321–337

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin R, Forslid R, Martin P, Ottaviano G, Robert-Nocoud F (2003) Economic geography and public policy. Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Behrens K, Gaigné C, Ottaviano G, J-F Thisse (2003) Interregional and international trade: 70 years after Ohlin. CEPR Discussion Paper No.4065

  • Brander J, Krugman P (1983) A ‘reciprocal dumping’ model of international trade. J Int Econ 15:313–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christaller W (1933) Die zentralen orte in Süddeutschland. Translated by Baskin CW (1966) to Central places of southern Germany. Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ

  • Clarke R, Collie DR (2003) Product differentiation and the gains from trade under Bertrand duopoly. Can J Econ 36:658–673

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cronon W (1991) Nature’s megalopolis: Chicago and the Great West. Norton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • De Fraja G, Norman G (1993) Product differentiation, pricing policy and equilibrium. J Reg Sci 33:343–363

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forslid R, Ottaviano G (2003) An analytically solvable core–periphery model. Journal of Economic Geography 3:229–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furusawa T, Konishi H (2002) Free trade networks. Working Paper 548, Boston College

  • Ginsburgh V, Papageorgiou YY, Thisse J-F (1985) On existence and stability of spatial equilibria and steady-states. Reg Sci Urban Econ 15:149–158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenhut ML, Norman G, Hung C-S (1987) The economics of imperfect competition. Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Howes C (1993) Japanese auto transplants and the US automobile industry. Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. J Polit Econ 99:483–499

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1993a) On the number and location of cities. Eur Econ Rev 37:293–298

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P (1993b) The hub effect: or, threeness in international trade. In: Ethier WJ, Helpman E, Neary JP (eds) Theory, policy and dynamics in international trade. Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman P, Elizondo RL (1996) Trade policy and the Third World metropolis. J Dev Econ 49:137–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monfort P, van Ypersele T (2003) Integration, regional agglomeration and international trade. CEPR Discussion Paper No.3752

  • Ottaviano G, Tabuchi T, Thisse J-F (2002) Agglomeration and trade revisited. Int Econ Rev 43:409–436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pirenne H (1969) Medieval Cities. Princeton Univ. Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Tabuchi T, J-F Thisse, Zeng D-Z (2005) On the number and size of cities. Journal of Economic Geography 5:423–448

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Venables AJ, Limão N (2002) Geographical disadvantage: a Heckscher-Ohlin-von Thünen model of international specialisation. J Int Econ 58:239–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank K. Behrens for insightful comments and suggestions, and M. Fujita, W. Strange, T. Takahashi and an anonymous referee for useful comments. We also thank participants of seminars at Kyoto University, Nagoya University, University of Tokyo, Oita University, and the NARSC Meetings in Philadelphia.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Takanori Ago.

Appendices

Appendix A: Comparative statics

Comparative statics

  1. 1.

    Applying the implicit function theorem to Eq. 4 with \(\lambda{\lambda}^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) and \(w_{r}=1\), \(f_{4}\equiv V_{1}-w_{1}/G_{1}^{\mu }=0\) and \(f_{5}\equiv V_{3}-w_{3}/G_{3}^{\mu }=0\), we have

    $${\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial w_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial w_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial w_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial w_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial w_{3} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial w_{3} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial V_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial V_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial w_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial V_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} } \right)} = {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial V_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial V_{3} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial V_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial V_{3} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial V_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial V_{3} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{4} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{4} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{4} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{4} }}{{\partial V_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{4} }}{{\partial V_{3} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial V_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial V_{3} }}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{4} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{5} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} } \right)} = {\left( {0\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\mu - 1}} & {0} & {0} & {0} & {0} \\ {0} & {{\mu - 1}} & {0} & {0} & {0} \\ {0} & {0} & {{\mu - 1}} & {0} & {0} \\ {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} {\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {0} & {0} & {1} & {0} \\ {0} & {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} {\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {0} & {0} & {1} \\ \end{array} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{3{\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {0} \\ {0} & {{3{\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} \\ {{3{\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}}} & {{3{\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}}} \\ {{_{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} 3^{{\frac{{\sigma - 1 - \mu }}{{\sigma - 1}}}} }} & {0} \\ {0} & {{_{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} 3^{{\frac{{\sigma - 1 - \mu }}{{\sigma - 1}}}} }} \\ \end{array} } \right)}$$

    By rearranging it, we get

    $$\frac{{\partial V_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }} = \frac{{\partial V_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }} = \frac{{3^{{\frac{{1 - \sigma + \mu }}{{1 - \sigma }}}} }}{{\sigma - 1}}{\left( {1 - \sigma + \mu \sigma } \right)}$$
    (13)
    $$\frac{{\partial V_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }} = \frac{{\partial V_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }} = 0$$
    (14)
  2. 2.

    From (1), let \(f_{6}\equiv V_{1}-V_{2}\) and \(f_{7}\equiv V_{1}-V_{3}\). Then, we similarly have

    $$\begin{aligned} & T^{\sigma } {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial w_{1} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial w_{2} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial w_{3} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} } \right)} = T^{\sigma } {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial \lambda _{2} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial w_{2} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial w_{3} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{6} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{6} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{6} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{6} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{6} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{7} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{7} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{7} }}{{\partial w_{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{7} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} & {{\frac{{\partial f_{7} }}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{\frac{{\partial f_{1} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{2} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{3} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{6} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ {{\frac{{\partial f_{7} }}{{\partial T}}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} } \right)} \\ & = {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\mu - 1}} & {0} & {0} & {{3{\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {0} \\ {0} & {{\mu - 1}} & {0} & {0} & {{3{\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} \\ {0} & {0} & {{\mu - 1}} & {{3{\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}}} & {{3{\left( {1 - \mu } \right)}}} \\ {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} {\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} {\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {0} & {{_{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} 3^{{\frac{{\sigma - 1 - \mu }}{{\sigma - 1}}}} }} & {{_{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} 3^{{\frac{{\sigma - 1 - \mu }}{{\sigma - 1}}}} }} \\ {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} {\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {0} & {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} {\left( {\mu - 1} \right)}}} & {{_{{\frac{{2\mu }}{{1 - \sigma }}}} 3^{{\frac{{\sigma - 1 - \mu }}{{\sigma - 1}}}} }} & {{_{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} 3^{{\frac{{\sigma - 1 - \mu }}{{\sigma - 1}}}} }} \\ \end{array} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} \\ & \cdot {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {0} \\ {0} \\ {0} \\ {{3^{{\frac{\mu }{{1 - \sigma }}}} \mu }} \\ {0} \\ \end{array} } \right)} \\ \end{aligned} $$

    where each element is evaluated at \(T\rightarrow \infty \), \(\lambda _{r}^{\ast }=1/3\) and \(w_{r}^{\ast }=1\) for all \(r\). By rearranging it, we obtain

    $$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {T^{\sigma } \frac{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}{{\partial T}}}{ = \frac{{\mu {\left( {\sigma - 1} \right)}}}{{9{\left( {\sigma - 1 - \mu \sigma } \right)}}} > 0} \\ {T^{\sigma } \frac{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}{{\partial T}}}{ = - \frac{{2\mu {\left( {\sigma - 1} \right)}}}{{9{\left( {\sigma - 1 - \mu \sigma } \right)}}} > 0} \\ \end{array} $$

Appendix B: Proof of Lemma 1

Let

$${\mathop \mu \limits^ \vee } \equiv \frac{{4\sigma }}{{11\sigma + 18}}\widehat{\mu }_{2} \equiv \frac{{4\sigma {\left( {5\sigma + 18} \right)}}}{{37\sigma ^{2} + 252\sigma + 324}}\overline{\mu } _{2} \equiv \frac{{2\sigma }}{{4\sigma + 9}}$$

where \(\check{\mu}<\hat{\mu}_{2}.\) Domains of the four trade patterns (C1)–(C4) are illustrated in Fig. 4. We show that when for \(\tau \) is just below \(\tau _{\rm{trade}},\) the stable path enters the domain of neighboring trade between \(1\) and \(2\) and between \(2\) and \(3\) (C5) in Fig. 5 for \(\mu<\check{\mu}\) (Lemma 2) and the domain of one-way trade from \(1\) and \(3\) to \(2\) (C1) for \(\check{\mu}<\mu<\hat{\mu}_{2}\) (Lemma 3), but that it does not enter the domains of (C2), (C3), and (C4) (Lemmas 4–6). The shaded triangular domain of (C5) is given by the three boundary conditions \(\lambda _{r}<2\left( \alpha -\tau \right) /\sigma \tau \) (\(r=1,2,3\)), where \(\lambda _{r}\) is no longer \(1/3\) since \(\tau \) is slightly less than \(\tau _{\rm{trade}}.\) The vertexes of the triangle in Fig. 5 are computed as:

$${\left( {\frac{{2{\left( {a - \tau } \right)}}}{{\sigma \tau }},\frac{{2{\left( {a - \tau } \right)}}}{{\sigma \tau }}} \right)},{\left( {\frac{{2{\left( {a - \tau } \right)}}}{{\sigma \tau }},\frac{{{\left( {\sigma + 4} \right)}\tau - 4a}}{{\sigma \tau }}} \right)},{\left( {\frac{{{\left( {\sigma + 4} \right)}\tau - 4a}}{{\sigma \tau }},\frac{{2{\left( {a - \tau } \right)}}}{{\sigma \tau }}} \right)}$$
(15)

Also, define the RHS of Eq. 2 as

$$\lambda _{r} \equiv \lambda _{r} {\left[ {V_{r} {\left( {\lambda ^{*} } \right)} - {\sum\limits_{s = 1}^3 {\lambda _{s} V_{s} {\left( {\lambda ^{*} } \right)}} }} \right]}$$

for \(r=1,2,3.\)

Fig. 4
figure 4

(C1) one-way trade from 1 and 3 to 2, (C2) one-way trade from 1 to 2 and neighboring trade between 2 and 3, (C3) autarky in 1 and one-way trade from 2 to 3, (C3’) autarky in 3 and one-way trade from 2 to 1, (C4) one-way trade from 2 to 1 and 3

Fig. 5
figure 5

(C1)–(C4) same as Fig. 4, (C5) neighboring trade

Lemma 2

If \(\mu<\check{\mu},\) the stable equilibrium path \(\lambda{ \lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) passing through \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) enters the domain of neighboring trade (C5) with

$$\frac{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}{{\partial \tau }} = \frac{{\partial \lambda _{3} }}{{\partial _{\tau } }} < 0$$

Proof

In the case of neighboring trade, we compute the Jacobian of Eq. 2 and evaluate it at \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\). Then, the stability condition is given by

$$\mu < \widetilde{\mu } \equiv \frac{{2\sigma {\left( {7\sigma + 18} \right)}}}{{34\sigma ^{2} + 153\sigma + 162}}$$
(16)

Applying the implicit function theorem to \(y_{1}=y_{3}=0\) at \(\lambda{ \lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\), we get

$$\frac{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}{{\partial \tau }} = \frac{{\partial \lambda _{3} }}{{\partial \tau }} = \frac{{{\left( {2 - \mu } \right)}\sigma {\left( {\sigma + 6} \right)}}}{{18a{\left[ {\mu {\left( {34\sigma ^{2} + 162} \right)} - 2\sigma {\left( {7\sigma + 18} \right)}} \right]}}} < 0$$
(17)

where the inequality is due to Eq. 16. Therefore, the slope of the stable equilibrium path is \(1.\)

On the other hand, the marginal change in the first vertex of Eq. 15 at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) is

$$\frac{{\partial \lambda _{1} }}{{\partial \tau }} = \frac{{\partial \lambda _{3} }}{{\partial \tau }} = - \frac{{{\left( {\sigma + 6} \right)}^{2} }}{{18a\sigma }} < 0$$
(18)

Hence, the vertex moves toward the same direction as the stable equilibrium path for a marginal decrease in\(\ \tau \). For the stable equilibrium path \(\lambda{\lambda}^{\ast }(\tau )\) to enter the domain of neighboring trade (C5), the change in the stable path Eq. 17 is smaller then the latter Eq. 18 in absolute value, i.e.

$$ -\frac{(\sigma +6)^{2}}{18\alpha \sigma }<\frac{\left( 2-\mu \right) \sigma \left( \sigma +6\right) ^{2}}{18\alpha \left[ \mu \left( 34\sigma ^{2}+153\sigma +162\right) -2\sigma \left( 7\sigma +18\right) \right] }<0$$

The first inequality is equivalent to \(\mu<\check{\mu}\). However, since \( \check{\mu}<\tilde{\mu}\), this lemma holds for \(\mu<\check{\mu}.\)

Lemma 3

If \(\check{\mu}<\mu<\hat{\mu}_{2},\) the stable equilibrium path \( \lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) passing through \(\boldsymbol{\lambda } ^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) enters the domain (C1) with

$$ \frac{\partial \lambda _{1}}{\partial \tau }=\frac{\partial \lambda _{3}}{ \partial \tau }<0$$

Proof

Computing and evaluating the Jacobian of Eq. 2 at \(\lambda{ \lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) for one-way trade to the center, we have the stability condition

$$ \mu<\hat{\mu}_{2}$$
(19)

The comparative statics at \(\boldsymbol{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) is

$$ \frac{\partial \lambda _{1}}{\partial \tau }=\frac{\partial \lambda _{3}}{ \partial \tau }=\frac{2\sigma (\sigma +6)^{2}(2-\mu )}{9\alpha \left[ \mu \left( 37\sigma ^{2}+252\sigma +324\right) -4\sigma \left( 5\sigma +18\right) \right] }<0$$

where the inequality is due to Eq. 19.

For the equilibrium path to enter the domain of the one-way trade to the center (C1), it is necessary that

$$ \frac{2\sigma (\sigma +6)^{2}(2-\mu )}{9\alpha \left[ \mu \left( 37\sigma ^{2}+252\sigma +324\right) -4\sigma \left( 5\sigma +18\right) \right] }<- \frac{(\sigma +6)^{2}}{18\alpha \sigma }<0$$

which is equivalent to \(\check{\mu}<\mu \). Hence, this lemma is true for \( \check{\mu}<\mu<\hat{\mu}_{2}.\)

Lemma 4

There is no stable equilibrium path \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) passing through \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \( \tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) that enters domain (C2).

Proof

Computing and evaluating the Jacobian of Eq. 2 at \(\lambda{ \lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) for one-way trade from 1 to 2 and neighboring trade between 2 and 3, we have the stability condition

$$\eqalign {z\equiv (53\sigma ^{3}+453\sigma ^{2}+1188\sigma +972)\mu ^{2}-12\sigma (5\sigma ^{2}+28\sigma +36)\mu \cr +16\sigma ^{2}\left( \sigma +3\right) >0}$$

The comparative statics at \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) is

$$ \frac{\partial \lambda _{3}}{\partial \tau }=\frac{(\mu -2)\sigma (\sigma +6)^{2}}{9\alpha z}<0$$

where inequality holds from \(z>0\). Thus, any slight decrease in \(\tau \) leads to \(\lambda _{3}>1/3\!\), which does not pass through domain (C2).

Lemma 5

If \(\mu<\bar{\mu}_{2}\), then there is no stable equilibrium path \( \lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) passing through \(\lambda{\lambda } ^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) that enters domain (C3).

Proof

Computing and evaluating the Jacobian of Eq. 2 at \(\lambda{ \lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) autarky in \(1\) and one-way trade from \(2\) to \(3\), we have the stability condition

$$ \mu<\frac{4\sigma (2\sigma +9)}{13\sigma ^{2}+99\sigma +162}$$
(20)

Since \(\bar{\mu}_{2}<\frac{4\sigma (2\sigma +9)}{13\sigma ^{2}+99\sigma +162} \), stability condition Eq. 20 is met. The comparative statics at \( \lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade }}\) is

$$ \frac{\partial \lambda _{3}}{\partial \tau }=\frac{(\mu -2)\sigma (\sigma +6)^{2}}{9\alpha \lbrack (13\sigma ^{2}+99\sigma +162)\mu -4\sigma \left( 2\sigma +9\right) ]}>0$$
(21)

where the inequality holds from Eq. 20. We also have \(d\lambda _{3}/d\lambda _{1}=-2\) along the equilibrium path \(\lambda{\lambda } ^{\ast }(\tau )\) at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}.\)

For the equilibrium path to enter domain (C3), \(\lambda{\lambda} ^{\ast }(\tau )\) should not enter the neighboring trade triangle (C5). This is shown to be equivalent that Eq. 21 is smaller than the partial derivative of the vertical axis of the southeast vertex \({\left( {{{\left( {{\text{2}}\alpha - \tau } \right)}} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {{\text{2}}\alpha - \tau } \right)}} {\sigma \tau ,}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\sigma \tau ,}} \right)}{\left[ {{{\left( {\sigma + 4} \right)}\tau - 4\alpha } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\left( {\sigma + 4} \right)}\tau - 4\alpha } {\sigma \tau }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\sigma \tau }} \right]}\) in absolute value. A straightforward computation yields \(\mu >\bar{\mu}_{2}.\)

Lemma 6

There is no stable equilibrium path \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) passing through \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \( \tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) that enters domain (C4).

Proof

Computing and evaluating the Jacobian of Eq. 2 at \(\lambda{ \lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) for one-way trade from the center, we have the stability condition

$$ \mu<\bar{\mu}_{2}$$
(22)

The comparative statics at \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) with \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) is

$$ \frac{\partial \lambda _{1}}{\partial \tau }=\frac{\partial \lambda _{3}}{ \partial \tau }=\frac{2(\mu -2)\sigma (\sigma +6)^{2}}{18\alpha \lbrack (14\sigma ^{2}+99\sigma +162)\mu -2\sigma \left( 5\sigma +18\right) ]}>0$$

where the inequality holds from Eq. 22. For the equilibrium path to enter the domain of the one-way trade from the center (C4), it is necessary that

$$ \frac{(\mu -2)\sigma (\sigma +6)^{2}}{18\alpha \lbrack (14\sigma ^{2}+99\sigma +162)\mu -2\sigma \left( 5\sigma +18\right) ]}>\frac{(\sigma +6)^{2}}{36\alpha \sigma }$$

or equivalently \(\mu >\bar{\mu}_{2}\), which contradicts Eq. 22.

Appendix C: Lemma 7

Lemma 7

In the OTT model with \(\mu<\mu _{2}^{\ast }\), the stable equilibrium path \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) passing through \( \lambda{\lambda }=(1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) is always axisymmetric for all \(\lambda _{1}^{\ast }=\lambda _{3}^{\ast }\in (0,1/2).\)

Proof

Let \(y_{rs}\equiv \left. \partial y_{r}/\partial \lambda _{s}\right\vert _{\lambda _{1}^{\ast }=\lambda _{3}^{\ast }}\). Since \(y_{11}=y_{33}\) and \( y_{13}=y_{31},\) the two eigenvalues are real and given by \(y_{11}\pm y_{13}\) in an axisymmetric equilibrium \(\lambda _{1}^{\ast }=\lambda _{3}^{\ast }.\) Let \(X\equiv y_{13}(\lambda _{1}-\lambda _{3})\), then

$${\mathop X\limits^ \cdot } = y_{{13}} {\left( {{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{1} - {\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{3} } \right)} = {\left( {y_{{11}} - y_{{13}} } \right)}X$$

in the vicinity of an axisymmetric equilibrium. We show \(y_{11}-y_{13}<0\) below so that \(X\ \)goes to zero, which necessarily results in the axisymmetric configuration \(\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}\). Let

$$ \bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\equiv \frac{2\sigma }{\sigma +4}<\tau _{\rm{ trade}}$$

at which full trade starts.

  1. 1.

    Neighboring trade \(0<\mu \leq \check{\mu}\) and \(\bar{ \tau}_{\rm{trade}}\leq \tau \leq \tau _{\rm{trade}}.\)

    Noting that \(y_{1r}=\partial \lambda _{1}\left( V_{1}-\sum_{s=1}^{3}\lambda _{s}V_{s}\right) /\partial \lambda _{r}\) about an axisymmetric equilibrium because \(V_{1}-\sum_{s=1}^{3}\lambda _{s}V_{s}=0\) holds, we have

    $$ \rm{sgn}\left( {\it{y}}_{11}-{\it{y}}_{13}\right) =\rm{sgn}\left( \tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right) -\tau \right)$$
    (23)

    where

    $$ \tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right) =\frac{2\alpha \left( 4\sigma -18\mu -19\mu \sigma +27\mu \sigma \lambda _{1}\right) }{\sigma \left( 2\lambda _{1}-1\right) \left( 4\sigma -6\mu -13\mu \sigma +21\mu \sigma \lambda _{1}\right) }$$
    (24)

    It is readily shown that \(\tau ^{\prime }\left( \lambda _{1}\right)<0\) for all \(\mu<\hat{\mu}_{2}\). Four cases may arise.

    1. 1a.

      For \(0<\mu \leq \hat{\mu}_{1}\) and \(\bar{\tau}_{ \rm{trade}}\leq \tau \leq \tau _{\rm{trade}}.\)

      Solving \(\tau \left( 0\right) =\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\) yields sgn\( \left( \bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}-\tau \left( 0\right) \right) =\)sgn\(\left( 2\sigma /\left( 8\sigma +9\right) -\mu \right) \). If \(\mu<2\sigma /\left( 8\sigma +9\right) ,\) then we have \(\tau \geq \bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade} }>\tau \left( 0\right) >\tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right) ,\) where the last inequality is due to \(\tau ^{\prime }\left( \lambda _{1}\right)<0\). That is, if \(\mu<2\sigma /\left( 8\sigma +9\right) ,\) then \(y_{11}<y_{13}\) holds from Eq. 23. Therefore, we only have to show \(\hat{\mu}_{1}<2\sigma /\left( 8\sigma +9\right) .\)

      Let

      $$f{\left( {\lambda _{1} } \right)} \equiv 36\mu ^{2} \sigma ^{2} {\left( {\lambda _{1} } \right)}^{4} - 12\mu \sigma {\left( {108\mu + 2\sigma + 73\mu \sigma } \right)}{\left( {\lambda _{1} } \right)}^{3} + {\left( {1981\mu ^{2} \sigma ^{2} + 5580\mu ^{2} \sigma + 3888\mu ^{2} + 202\mu \sigma ^{2} + 360 + 4\sigma ^{2} } \right)}{\left( {\lambda _{1} } \right)}^{2} - 6{\left( {164\mu ^{2} \sigma ^{2} + 552\mu ^{2} \sigma + 414\mu ^{2} + 9\mu \sigma ^{2} - 8\mu \sigma - 36\mu + 4\sigma ^{2} + 8\sigma } \right)}\lambda _{1} + 4{\left( {35\mu ^{2} \sigma ^{2} + 118\mu ^{2} \sigma + 99\mu ^{2} - \mu \sigma ^{2} - 14\mu \sigma - 18\mu + 2\sigma ^{2} + 4\sigma \lambda } \right)}$$
      (25)

      Let \(J\left( \mu ,\sigma \right) \) be the discriminant of the fourth-order polynomial \(f(\lambda _{1}).\) By definition, we have \(J\left( \hat{\mu} _{1},\sigma \right) =0\) and \(J\left( 2\sigma /\left( 8\sigma +9\right) ,\sigma \right)<0\), which implies \(\hat{\mu}_{1}<2\sigma /\left( 8\sigma +9\right) \).

    2. 1b.

      Neighboring trade \(\hat{\mu}_{1}<\mu<\check{\mu}\) and \(\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\leq \tau \leq \tau _{\rm{trade}}.\)

    In this case, \(\lambda _{1}\) lies in the interval of \([1/3,1/2]\). Since \( \tau ^{\prime }\left( \lambda _{1}\right)<0\), \(\tau \left( 1/3\right) >\tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) for all \(\lambda _{1}\in \lbrack 1/3,1/2]\). Furthermore, \(\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}>\tau \left( 1/3\right) \) for \(\mu = \check{\mu},\) and hence \(\tau >\tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right) \), which means \(y_{11}<y_{13}\) at \(\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}.\)

  2. 2.

    One-way trade to the center \(\check{\mu}<\mu<\hat{\mu}_{2}\) and \(\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\leq \tau \leq \tau _{\rm{ trade}}.\)

    A direct computation yields

    $$ \left. y_{11}-y_{13}\right\vert _{\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}}=\frac{\alpha ^{2}\sigma \,\,\left( 18\mu -4\sigma +4\mu \sigma +3\mu \sigma \lambda _{1}\right) }{\gamma \mu \left( \sigma \lambda _{1}+2\right) ^{3}}$$

    Since the RHS is increasing in \(\mu \) and \(\lambda _{1}\), substituting \(\mu = \hat{\mu}_{2}\) and \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\), we have

    $$ \left. y_{11}-y_{13}\right\vert _{\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}}<-\frac{2\alpha ^{2}\sigma ^{2}\left( 19\sigma +126\right) }{3\gamma \left( 5\sigma +18\right) \left( \sigma +4\right) ^{3}}<0$$
  3. 3.

    Full trade \(\mu<\acute{\mu}\equiv \left( \sigma ^{2}-4\right) /\left( 10\sigma ^{2}+48\sigma +50\right) \) and \( \tau<\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}.\)

The full trade condition \(\mu<\acute{\mu}\) is equivalent to at \(\lambda _{1}^{\ast }(\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}})>0\), which the interior equilibrium condition at \(\tau =\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}.\)

Since the stable equilibrium path \(\lambda{\lambda }^{\ast }(\tau )\) and its inverse function \(\tau _{c}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \)are increasing functions, we get

$$\tau _{c}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) >\tau _{c}\left( 0\right) =\frac{4\alpha \left( 2+7\mu +\sigma +5\mu \sigma \right) }{4+4\sigma +\sigma ^{2}+2\mu +2\mu \sigma }>\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}} $$
(26)

On the other hand, the definition in Eq. 24 is revised by

$$ \tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right) =\frac{3\alpha \mu \left( 2\sigma +3\right) }{\mu +2\sigma +\sigma ^{2}+94\mu \sigma -\mu \sigma ^{2}+3\mu \sigma \left( \sigma +2\right) \lambda _{1}}$$

Since \(\tau ^{\prime }\left( \lambda _{1}\right)<0\) holds, we have

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\tau {\left( {\lambda _{1} } \right)}}{ < \tau {\left( 0 \right)} = \frac{{3a\mu {\left( {2\sigma + 3} \right)}}}{{\mu + 2\sigma + \sigma ^{2} + 94\mu \sigma - \mu \sigma ^{2} }}} \\ {}{ < \frac{{3a{\mathop \mu \limits^\prime }{\left( {2\sigma + 3} \right)}}}{{{\mathop \mu \limits^\prime } + 2\sigma + \sigma ^{2} + 94{\mathop \mu \limits^\prime }\sigma - {\mathop \mu \limits^\prime }\sigma ^{2} }}} \\ {}{ = \frac{{a{\left( {\sigma - 2} \right)}{\left( {2\sigma + 3} \right)}}}{{3\sigma ^{3} + 18\sigma ^{2} + 17\sigma - 6}}} \\ {}{ < \overline{\tau } _{{trade}} } \\ \end{array} $$
(27)

where the second inequality is due to \(\partial \tau \left( 0\right) /\partial \mu >0\) and the last inequality is from \(\sigma >2\) which is from \( \mu<\acute{\mu}\). Putting Eqs. 26 and 27 together, we have \(\tau \left( \lambda _{1}\right)<\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}<\tau _{c}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \), which is \(y_{11}<y_{13}\) at \(\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3} .\)

It is known in the two-dimensional dynamics that the equilibrium point is a node (resp. saddle point) if \(\left\vert y_{11}\right\vert >\left\vert y_{13}\right\vert \) (resp. \(\left\vert y_{11}\right\vert<\left\vert y_{13}\right\vert \!\)).

Appendix D: Proposition 4

From Lemma 7, a stable interior equilibrium path should be on the curve

$$ \Delta V_{12}(\lambda _{1},\tau )\equiv \left. V_{1}-V_{2}\right\vert _{\lambda _{2}=1-2\lambda _{1},\lambda _{3}=\lambda _{1}}=0$$

which passes through \((\lambda _{1},\tau )=(1/3,\tau _{\rm{trade}})\). It intersects with \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\) if \(f(\lambda _{1})>0\) holds for all \( \lambda _{1}\in \lbrack 1/3,1/2]\), which corresponds to disappearance of the center. This is equivalent to \(f(\tilde{\lambda}_{1})>0\), where \(\tilde{ \lambda}_{1}\) is the smallest solution of \(f^{\prime }(\lambda _{1})=0\). In this way, we are able to classify the stable paths as follows.

Proposition 4

In the OTT model with \(\mu<\mu _{2}^{\ast }\), the interior stable equilibrium path passing through \((\lambda _{1},\tau )=(1/3,\tau _{ \rm{trade}})\) is either one of the following:

If \(\hat{\mu}_{1}<\mu<\mu _{2}^{\ast }\), \(\lambda _{2}^{\ast }\) decreases monotonically from \(1/3\) to \(0\) at positive \(\tau ;\)

If \(\mu<\hat{\mu}_{1},\) \(\lambda _{2}^{\ast }\) decreases from \(1/3\) and then increases to \(1\).

(C6) stands for full trade between any pair of regions. Since the denominator of \(\Delta V_{12}(\lambda _{1},\tau )\) is positive except \( \lambda _{1}=\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma ,\) define the numerator of \(\Delta V_{{12}} {\left( {\lambda _{1} ,\tau } \right)}\) by \(\Delta V_{12}^{n}(\lambda _{1},\tau )\) for all \(\lambda _{1}\neq \left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma .\) Because the implicit function \(\Delta V_{12}^{n}(\lambda _{1},\tau )=0\) is quadratic in \( \tau \) in all cases of (C1), (C4), (C5) and (C6), it has two explicit solutions: \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) ,\) which are inverse functions of \(\lambda _{1}^{\ast }(\tau ).\)

Lemma 8

The function \(\lambda _{1}^{\ast }(\tau )\) is continuous for all domain of \(0\leq \lambda _{1}\leq 1/2\) and \(0\leq \tau \leq \tau _{ \rm{trade}}\) irrespective of the trade patterns.

Proof

From the implicit functional theorem, \(\lambda _{1}^{\ast }(\tau )\) is continuous inside the cases of (C1), (C4), (C5), and (C6). Therefore, we only have to check the continuity at the boundaries. However, say, at the boundaries of cases (C1) and (C4), if \(\Delta V_{{12}} {\left( {\lambda _{1} ,\tau } \right)}\) holds in case (C1), then this also holds in case (C4). The same is true for all other boundaries.

Lemma 9

The functions \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) are real for all \(\lambda _{1}\in \lbrack 1/2,\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma )\) except that there are at most \(2\) discontinuous points in the interval.

Proof

First, we consider the number of discontinuous points. The denominator of \( \tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) is common and quartic in \(\lambda _{1}\) with the positive coefficient of \(\left( \lambda _{1}\right) ^{4}\). Since, the denominator is shown to be negative at \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\), \(\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma \), there exist at most two discontinuous points.

Second, we show that \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) are real. The common terms in the square root of \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) are \(f(\lambda _{1})\), which is defined by (25). \( f(\lambda _{1})\) is quartic in \(\lambda _{1}\) with a positive coefficient of \(\left( \lambda _{1}\right) ^{4}\). It is readily shown that

$$ f^{\prime }(1/2)>0\qquad \lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \frac{\sigma +2}{ \sigma }-0}f^{\prime }\left( \frac{\sigma +2}{\sigma }\right) >0$$

and the larger inflexion point is outside the interval of \([1/2,\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma )\!\!\!\). These imply that both \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\) and \( \lambda _{1}=\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma -0\) are on the left-hand side of the quartic curve with a positive slope. Since \(f(1/2)>0\), we have \( f(\lambda _{1})>0\) for all \(\lambda _{1}\in \lbrack 1/2,\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma )\), which means real \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \!\!\).

Lemma 10

When a stable equilibrium lying on \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) (resp. \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \)) disappears, then it will jump to the same \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) (resp. \( \tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \)) or the corners \(\lambda _{1}=0,1/2.\)

Proof

It is readily shown that \(\Delta V_{12}(\lambda _{1},\tau )=0\) is quartic in \(\lambda _{1}\) in cases (C1) and quadratic in \(\lambda _{1}\) in case (C6). Since \(\lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \pm \infty }\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =\)lim\(_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \pm \infty }\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =0\) holds for all cases of (C1), (C4), (C5) and (C6), \( \tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) have at most one trough \((\check{\lambda}_{1},\check{\tau}),\) at which a jump may occur.

Case (C1)

Suppose \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) has a peak \((\hat{\lambda}_{1},\hat{\tau}),\) such that \(\check{\tau}<\hat{\tau}\) is in the interval of \([0,1/2]\), then a stable equilibrium path \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) may jump at the trough \((\check{\lambda} _{1},\check{\tau}_{b})\) to the different curve \(\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) .\) However, such a trough-peak combination violates the property in that there are more than \(4\) solutions of \(\lambda _{1}\) in \(\Delta V_{12}(\lambda _{1},(\check{\tau}+\hat{\tau})/2)=0\) as shown below.

From Lemma 9, \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) is discontinuous at most \(2\) points.

  1. 1.

    If \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) is continuous in \( \lambda _{1}\in \lbrack 1/2,\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma )\), then \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) necessarily crosses the horizontal line \( \tau =(\check{\tau}+\hat{\tau})/2\) in \((\max \{\check{\lambda}_{1},\hat{ \lambda}_{1}\},\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma )\) in addition to \(4\)points of intersection in \([\min \{\check{\lambda}_{1},\hat{\lambda}_{1}\},\max \{ \check{\lambda}_{1},\hat{\lambda}_{1}\}],\) thus violating the property.

  2. 2.

    If \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) is discontinuous only at \(\bar{\lambda}_{1}\in (1/2,\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma )\), then \( \tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) goes to either \(-\infty \) or \(+\infty .\) However, the sign of \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) does not change in the vicinity of \(\bar{\lambda}_{1}\) \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) since \(\bar{\lambda}_{1}\) must be a repeated root of the quartic denominator of \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) .\) Hence, the above case 1 applies.

  3. 3.

    If \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) is discontinuous at two distinct \(\bar{\lambda}_{1},\tilde{\lambda}_{1}\) with \(1/2<\bar{\lambda} _{1}<\tilde{\lambda}_{1}<\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma \), then \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) changes its sign in the vicinity of \(\bar{ \lambda}_{1},\tilde{\lambda}_{1}.\) If \(\lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \bar{ \lambda}_{1}-0}\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =-\infty ,\) then \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) crosses \(\tau =(\check{\tau}+\hat{\tau})/2\) in \((\check{\lambda}_{1},\bar{\lambda}_{1})\), and hence the number of intersection points with \(\tau =(\check{\tau}+\hat{\tau})/2\) exceeds \(4.\)

On the other hand, if \(\lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \bar{\lambda} _{1}-0}\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =+\infty ,\) then it must be that \( \lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \bar{\lambda}_{1}+0}\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =-\infty \) \(\lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \tilde{\lambda} _{1}-0}\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =-\infty \) and \(\lim_{\lambda _{1}\rightarrow \tilde{\lambda}_{1}+0}\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) =+\infty .\) Thus, \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) crosses the horizontal line \(\tau =(\check{\tau}+\hat{\tau})/2\) in \((\tilde{\lambda} _{1},\left( \sigma +2\right) /\sigma ),\) and hence the number of intersection points with \(\tau =(\check{\tau}+\hat{\tau})/2\) exceeds \(4.\)

Cases (C4) and (C5)

It is easily shown that the equilibrium path crosses at most once at the boundary between cases (C1) and (C4) and at the boundary between cases (C1) and (C5). Therefore, once a stable equilibrium path crosses one of the boundaries, it will never cross again, implying that the above trough-peak combination does not arise. Hence, it will be sure to hit the corner \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\) (resp. \(0\)) in case (C1) [resp. (C4)].

Case (C6)

Since \(\Delta V_{12}(\lambda _{1},\tau )=0\) is quadratic in \(\lambda _{1},\) the above trough-peak combination cannot arise.

Lemma 10 together with Lemma 8 ensures that the stable equilibrium path starting from \(\bf{\lambda }^{\ast }=(\rm 1/3,1/3,1/3)\) at \(\tau =\tau _{\rm{trade}}\) will keep on the same curve or hit the corners. The only exception occurs when \(d\tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) /d\lambda _{1}=d\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) /d\lambda _{1}=\infty \), which corresponds to \(d\lambda _{1}^{\ast }(\tau )/d\tau =0\). At this point, an equilibrium does not disappear, and the two stable curves \( \tau _{a}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) and \(\tau _{b}\left( \lambda _{1}\right) \) are connected. This is case 2 with \(\mu<\hat{\mu}_{1},\) where the path first moves toward \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\) and then moves back to \( \lambda _{1}=0,\) resulting in \((0,1,0)\). Otherwise, the path moves according to case 1 with \(\mu >\hat{\mu}_{1}\) and reaches \((1/2,0,1/2)\) monotonically. Finally, since there is no stable equilibrium path approaching an interior solution of \(\lambda _{1}\) at \(\tau =0,\) Proposition 4 is proven.

Appendix E: Proof of Proposition 3

  1. 1.

    In the case of neighboring trade, when \(\lambda _{2}=0\), we have

    $$ \left. \frac{\partial \left( V_{1}-V_{3}\right) }{\partial \lambda _{1}} \right\vert _{\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}=1/2}=\frac{4\alpha ^{2}\sigma \left[ \mu \left( 11\sigma +36\right) -8\sigma \right] }{3\gamma \mu \left( \sigma +4\right) ^{3}}$$

    which is negative for all \(\mu \leq \mu _{2}^{\ast }\), implying that \( {\bf{\lambda} }^{\ast }=(1/2,0,1/2)\) is a stable during the neighboring trade of \(\tau >\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}.\) This equilibrium continues during \(\tau >\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\) if \(\left. V_{1}-V_{2}\right\vert _{\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}=1/2,\lambda _{2}=0,\tau = \bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}}\geq 0,\) which is equivalent to

    $$ \mu >\frac{2}{11}$$

    Otherwise, \((1/2,0,1/2)\) ceases to be an equilibrium, leading to the new equilibrium \((0,1,0)\) for a sufficiently large period of time.

  2. 2.

    In the case of full trade, when \(\lambda _{2}=0\), we get

    $$ \left. \frac{\partial \left( V_{1}-V_{3}\right) }{\partial \lambda _{1}} \right\vert _{\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}=1/2}=\frac{2\sigma \tau \left[ \mu \left( \sigma ^{2}+14\sigma +18\right) +2\sigma (\sigma +2)\right] }{3\gamma \mu \left( \sigma +2\right) ^{2}}\left( \tau _{\rm{break}}-\tau \right)$$

    where

    $$\tau _{{break}} \equiv \frac{{6a\mu {\left( {2\sigma + 3} \right)}}}{{\mu {\left( {\sigma ^{2} + 14\sigma + 18} \right)} + 2\sigma {\left( {\sigma + 2} \right)}}}$$

    That is, \((1/2,0,1/2)\) is a stable equilibrium for \(\tau >\tau _{\mathrm{ \rm break}}\). Since

    $$\frac{{\partial {{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }} {\lambda _{2} \left| {_{{\lambda _{3} = 1 - \lambda _{1} }} } \right.}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\lambda _{2} \left| {_{{\lambda _{3} = 1 - \lambda _{1} }} } \right.}}}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }} = \frac{{18a^{2} \mu ^{2} \sigma ^{3} {\left( {2\sigma + 3} \right)}^{2} {\left( {2\lambda _{1} - 1} \right)}}}{{\gamma {\left( {\sigma + 2} \right)}^{2} {\left( {\mu \sigma ^{2} + 2\sigma ^{2} + 14\mu \sigma + 18\mu + 4\sigma } \right)}^{2} }}$$

    \({{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{2} } {\left. {\lambda _{2} } \right|}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\left. {\lambda _{2} } \right|}_{{\lambda _{3} = 1\lambda _{1} }} \) is maximized at \(\lambda _{1}=0,1.\) Solving \({{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{2} } {\lambda _{2} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\lambda _{2} } = 0\) at \(\lambda _{1}=1\) yields \(\mathrm{sgn }(\overset{\cdot }{\lambda _{2}})=\mathrm{sgn}\left( \check{\mu}_{1}-\mu \right) ,\) where

    $$ \check{\mu}_{1}\equiv \frac{\left( 5\sigma +2\right) \left( \sigma +2\right) }{8\sigma ^{2}+25\sigma +18+3\sqrt{32\sigma ^{4}+240\sigma ^{3}+489\sigma ^{2}+324\sigma +36}}$$

    The stability condition is therefore

    $$ \mu >\check{\mu}_{1}$$

    This equilibrium continues during \(\tau >\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\) if \( \left. V_{1}-V_{2}\right\vert _{\lambda _{1}=\lambda _{3}=1/2}\geq 0\!\!\), which is equivalent to

    $$ \bar{\tau}_{\rm{break}}\equiv \frac{8\alpha \left( 1-\mu \right) }{7\mu \sigma +6\mu +2\sigma +12}<\tau \leq \bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}$$

    where \(\bar{\tau}_{\rm{break}}<\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\) holds for \( \mu >2/11\). Solving \({{\mathop {\lambda _{2} }\limits^ \cdot }} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\mathop {\lambda _{2} }\limits^ \cdot }} \lambda }} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} \lambda _{2} = 0\) at \( \lambda _{1}=1\) and \(\tau =\bar{\tau}_{\rm{break}}\) yields

    $$ \bar{\mu}_{1}\equiv \frac{3\sqrt{193\sigma ^{4}+1044\sigma ^{3}+1932\sigma ^{2}+1296\sigma +144}-13\sigma ^{2}-50\sigma -36}{98\sigma ^{2}+310\sigma +252}$$

    However, it can be shown that \(\check{\mu}_{1}>\bar{\mu}_{1}\) for all \(\mu >2/11\).

  3. 3.

    Finally, we consider the case that \((1/2,0,1/2)\) becomes unstable when full trade starts at \(\tau =\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}.\) Since

    $$\frac{{{\partial {\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\partial {\mathop \lambda \limits^ \cdot }_{2} } {\lambda _{2} \left| {_{{\lambda _{3} = 1 - \lambda _{1} }} } \right.}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\lambda _{2} \left| {_{{\lambda _{3} = 1 - \lambda _{1} }} } \right.}}}{{\partial \lambda _{1} }} = \frac{{2\sigma \alpha ^{2} {\left( {8\sigma ^{2} - 17\mu \sigma ^{2} - 19\mu \sigma - 72\mu + 16\sigma } \right)}{\left( {2\lambda _{1} - 1} \right)}}}{{3\gamma \mu {\left( {\sigma + 4} \right)}^{2} {\left( {\sigma + 2} \right)}^{2} }}$$

    at \(\tau =\bar{\tau}_{\rm{trade}}\). \({{\mathop {\lambda _{2} }\limits^ \cdot }} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\mathop {\lambda _{2} }\limits^ \cdot }} {\left. {\lambda _{2} } \right|_{{\lambda _{3} = 1 - \lambda _{1} ,\tau = \overline{\tau } _{{_{{trade}} }} }} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {\left. {\lambda _{2} } \right|_{{\lambda _{3} = 1 - \lambda _{1} ,\tau = \overline{\tau } _{{_{{trade}} }} }} }\) is maximized at \(\lambda _{1}=0,1/2\) or \(1.\) Solving \({\lambda _{2} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\lambda _{2} } {{\mathop {\lambda _{2} }\limits^ \cdot }}}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\mathop {\lambda _{2} }\limits^ \cdot }} = 0\) at \(\lambda _{1}=1/2\) and \(1\) yields the stability conditions

    $$ \mu >\tilde{\mu}_{1}\qquad \rm{and}\qquad \mu >\frac{2}{11}$$

    where

    $$ \tilde{\mu}_{1}\equiv \frac{\left( 5\sigma +2\right) \left( \sigma +2\right) }{2\left( 7\sigma ^{2}+30\sigma +29\right) }$$

    Hence, the conditions for the stable path reaching \((1,0,0)\) or \((0,0,1)\) are summarized as

    $$ \mu _{1}^{\ast }\equiv \max \left\{ \frac{2}{11},\min \left\{ \tilde{\mu} _{1},\check{\mu}_{1}\right\} \right\}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ago, T., Isono, I. & Tabuchi, T. Locational disadvantage of the hub. Ann Reg Sci 40, 819–848 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-005-0030-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00168-005-0030-x

JEL Classification

Navigation