Skip to main content
Log in

Parental time and working schedules

  • OriginalPaper
  • Published:
Journal of Population Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates the effects of working schedules and of other characteristics (including family composition) on the time devoted by mothers and fathers to different activities with children in Canadian households, by using 1992 and 1998 Canadian Time Use Surveys. Switching regression models and models with selection allow us to simultaneously model labour market participation, type of work schedules and allocation of parental time. Working time has a negative and very significant effect on parental time. Hours worked during the day or at night exert a similar effect on parental time, but the impact of hours worked in the evening is by far larger. Time worked in the evening mainly decreases leisure and social activities with children.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to Nock and Kingston (1988), they spend more time watching TV with their children.

  2. This differs, for example, from the Swedish household panel study (Household Market and Non Market Activities; see, Hallberg and Klevmarken 2002) in which no fixed format was used for activities (the respondent’s own words were recorded). See also, for example, Juster and Stafford (1991) for a discussion about the advantages and shortcomings of the different types of time use surveys.

  3. A few categories are excluded from our analysis: category 12 (sleep), as respondents were not asked with whom they were while sleeping; category 24 that concerns residual codes (missing information); categories 1–3 and category 11 that refer to paid work and school activities of respondents and which are rarely conducted in the presence of children.

  4. This could be verified with the 1998 General Social Surveys data.

  5. However, respondents were asked to evaluate the total amount of time spent in childcare by the other parent during the week preceding the survey, but this measure is rather imprecise.

  6. Note that biological and stepchildren are not distinguished in the public data files. Moreover, in 1992, variables describing family composition do not allow us to distinguish children aged between 13 and 18, whereas in 1998, children between 13 and 14 and between 15 and 18 can be differentiated.

  7. The two surveys were pooled to increase the sample size.

  8. That is 3.1% on 18.0%

  9. Increase of 7.4 from 37.0%

  10. Presser (2004) argued that the data used by Beers do not allow him to draw such a conclusion because of comparability problems; there are no such comparability problems with our data.

  11. Compared to the means, standard deviations are much larger for the average parental time of respondents whose working hours on the Designated Day cut through more than one period. This indicates that these situations are probably more diverse than others.

  12. As usual, RHS is for Right Hand Side.

  13. It is more simple to compute but less efficient than the Amemiya Generalized Least Square Estimator.

  14. The Smith and Blundell test, which allows to test endogeneity in tobit models, is not exactly adapted to our problem because it assumes that the potentially endogenous variables are continuous, whereas our variables are limited. However, under the assumption of continuity, we may consider that work schedules are not endogenous.

  15. Hallberg and Klevmarken (2002) found that total individuals’ own and their spouse’s market hours can generally be considered as exogenous variables when estimating parental time. This gives some indications on how total working time and parental time are chosen, even if this cannot provide any information on the effects of schedules.

  16. We thank an anonymous referee for having pointed this problem.

  17. As it is well-known that the second-step matrix of variances–covariances is biased, it is corrected by applying the Murphy and Topel’s (1985) method. In particular, this requires the computation of the derivatives of the Mills ratios with respect to the different parameters. Analytically, those derivatives are easy to compute; however, the derivative with respect to ρ, the correlation between the two first-step residuals, cannot be easily computed, as it involves the derivative of the bivariate normal cumulative distribution function with respect to ρ, which is numerically difficult to evaluate. For this reason, for each point of the sample, the derivatives functions of the Mills ratios with respect to ρ have been numerically approximated and then evaluated at the estimated value of ρ.

  18. For example, for mothers, there is a very strongly positive effect associated with having worked at 3 a.m., compared to the strong negative effect of having worked at 2 a.m. However, there is only one mother who has worked at 3 a.m. and not at 2 a.m., so that identification is based on a single observation. The effect of having worked at 2 a.m. or at 3 a.m. is probably of a similar magnitude as that of having worked at 1 a.m. or at 4 a.m. (that is approximately the average of the effect of having worked at 2 a.m. or at 3 a.m.).

  19. Partners’ work schedules have been reported by the respondent and are thus less precisely measured than own work schedules; for this reason, we used only dummy variables.

  20. The size of the working single mothers sample is nevertheless quite small (especially for sub-sample of mothers who work non-standard schedules).

  21. In the alternative specification, we have also introduced a variable indicating whether the respondent has worked a split shift (more than 3 h between two spells of work) during the Designated Day. Both mothers and fathers who had worked a split shift have increased direct childcare.

References

  • Ahn SC (1992) The LM test for a model with two selectivity criteria. Econ Lett 38:9–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amato PR (1994) Father–child relations, mother–child relations, and offspring psychological well-being in early adulthood. J Marriage Fam 56:1031–1042

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amato PR, Gilbreth JG (1999) Nonresident fathers and children’s well-being: a meta-analysis. J Marriage Fam 61:557–573

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beaujot R (2000) Earning and caring in Canadian families. Broadview, Canada

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1960) An economic analysis of fertility. In: Demographic and economic change in developed countries, a conference of the Universities—National Bureau Committee for Economic Research. Princeton Univ. Press for the NBER, New York

  • Beers TM (2000) Flexible schedules and shift work: replacing the ‘9-to-5’ workday? Mon Labor Rev 123:33–40

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertschek I, Kaiser U (2003) Productivity effects of organizational change: microeconometric evidence. ZEW discussion paper no. 01-32 (mimeo)

  • Bianchi SM (2000) Maternal employment and time with children: dramatic change or surprising continuity. Demography 37:401–414

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brayfield A (1995) Juggling jobs and kids: the impact of employment schedules on fathers’ caring for children. J Marriage Fam 57:321–332

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson MJ (2000) Family structure, father–child closeness and social-behavior outcomes for children. Mimeo

  • Carlson MJ (2006) Family structure, father involvement, and adolescent behavioral outcomes. J Marriage Fam 68(1):137–154

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Casper LM (1997) My daddy takes care of me! Fathers as care providers. Current Population Report P70-59. US Bureau of the Census, Washington, DC

  • Chase-Lansdale PL et al (1995) A psychological perspective on the development of caring in children and youth: the role of the family. J Adolesc 18:515–556

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig L, Bittman M (2003) The time costs of children in Australia. Mimeo

  • Greene WH (2003) Econometric analysis. Prentice Hall, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hallberg D (2003) Synchronous leisure, jointness, and household labor supply. Labour Econ 10:185–202

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hallberg D, Klevmarken A (2002) Time for children, a study of parent’s time allocation. J Popul Econ 16:205–226

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh D (1998) When we work. Am Econ Rev 88:321–325 (Papers and Proceedings)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamermesh D (2002) Timing, togetherness and time windfalls. J Popul Econ 15:601–623

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heckman J (1979) Sample selection bias as a specification error. Econometrica 47:153–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP, Osberg L (2005) Nobody to play with? The implications of leisure co-ordination. In: Hamermesh DS, Pfann GA (eds) The economics of time use, contributions to economic analysis, vol 271. Elsevier, pp 113–145

  • Johnes G (2000) Wage differentials and the responsiveness of labor supply: an international comparison. Lancaster University Management School Working Paper 2000/001

  • Juster FT (1985) Preferences for work and leisure. In: Juster FT, Stafford FP (eds) Time, goods, and well-being, survey research center. ISR, The University of Michigan, Ann Arbor

    Google Scholar 

  • Juster FT, Stafford FP (1991) The allocation of time: empirical findings, behavioral models, and problems of measurement. J Econ Lit 29:471–522

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman D et al (2006) Would you be happier if you were richer? A focusing illusion. CEPS Working Paper No. 125, Princeton University

  • Le Bourdais C, Sauriol A (1998) La part des pères dans la division du travail domestique au sein des familles canadiennes. Etudes et document No. 69, INRS-Urbanisation

  • Lee LF (1981) Simultaneous equations models with discrete and censored dependent variables. In: Manski CF, McFadden D (eds) Structural analysis of discrete data with econometric applications. MIT, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lefebvre P, Merrigan P (1999) Comportements d’utilisation du temps non marchand des familles au Québec et au Canada: une modélisation sur les microdonnées du budget-temps de 1986 et de 1992. L’Actualité Économique, Revue d’analyse Économique 75:625–663

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddala GS (1983) Limited-dependent and qualitative variables in econometrics. Cambridge Univ. Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Murphy KM, Topel RH (1985) Estimation and inference in two-step econometric models. J Bus Econ Stat 3:370–379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nock SL, Kingston PW (1988) Time with children: The impact of couples’ work-time commitments. Soc Forces 67:59–85

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Presser HB (1988) Shift work and child care among young dual-earner american parents. J Marriage Fam 50:133–148

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Presser HB (1989) Can we make time for children? The economy, work schedules, and child care. Demography 26:523–543

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Presser HB (1994) Employment schedules among dual-earner spouses and the division of household labor by gender. Am Sociol Rev 59:348–364

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Presser HB (1999) Toward a 24-hour economy. Science 284:1078–1079

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Presser HB (2004) Employment in a 24/7 economy: challenges for the family. In: Booth A, Crouter AC (eds) Work–family challenges for low-income parents and their children. Erlbaum, Mahwah, NJ, pp 83–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport B, Le Bourdais C (2001) Temps parental et formes familiales. Loisir Soc 24:585–617

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandberg JF, Hofferth SL (2000) Changes in children’s time with parents, U.S. 1981–1997. Research Report no. 00-457, Population Studies Center, University of Michigan

  • Silver C (2000) Etre présent: le temps que les couples à deux soutiens passent avec leurs enfants. Tend Soc Canadiennes 57:25–29

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith RJ, Blundell RW (1986) An exogeneity test for a simultaneous equation Tobit model with an application to labor supply. Econometrica 54:679–686

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Statistics Canada (1999) Overview of the time use of Canadians in 1998. Statistics Canada

  • Tallis GM (1961) The moment generating function of the truncated multi-normal distribution. J R Stat Soc Ser B 23:223–229

    Google Scholar 

  • Yeung WJ, Stafford F (2003) Intra-family child care time allocation: stalled revolution or road to equality? New York University, New York (mimeo)

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank participants to the conference, especially Daniel Hallberg, for their helpful comments. We also thank David Margolis for helpful discussions on econometrics. We also thank the two anonymous referees whose comments greatly helped to improve our paper. All remaining errors are ours. Support for this study was provided by grants from the Social Science and Humanities Research Council of Canada (regular grant and strategic grant on Social Cohesion). The analysis is based on data collected by Statistics Canada, but does not represent the views of Statistics Canada. The detailed results of all the complete models estimated in the paper are available upon request from the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Benoît Rapoport.

Additional information

Responsible editor: Deborah Cobb-Clark

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Appendix 1: list of control variables in the two-regime model

  1. 1.

    Predicting parental time

    Only for working respondents: respondent’s number of hours worked the Designated Day during the day, during the night and in the evening (continuous); respondent sometimes works at home (dichotomous); respondent has flexible schedules (dichotomous); respondent usually works rotating shift (dichotomous); respondent’s professional occupation (polytomous).

    For all respondents: partner’s work schedules (dichotomous variables indicating whether the respondent has worked during the day, in the evening or during the night the Designated Day); time spent by the partner with children in the previous week (continuous); time spent by the partner with children is missing (dichotomous); respondent interviewed on Saturday or Sunday (dichotomous); age of respondents (continuous, by 5-year groups); number and age of children (polytomous—15 groups); for non-working fathers, for single mothers and in the three-regime models, we used only two continuous variables: the age of the youngest child and the number of less than 18-year-old children; respondent’s educational level (polytomous); respondent born in Canada (dichotomous); respondent’s region of residence (polytomous); respondent sometimes goes to church (dichotomous).

  2. 2.

    Probability of participating to the labour market (switch part of the regression)

    1998 survey (dichotomous); respondent’s age and square age (continuous by 5-year groups); age of the youngest child and square age (continuous); number of less than 18-year-old children (continuous); respondent’s educational level (polytomous); respondent born in Canada (dichotomous); respondent’s mother born in Canada (dichotomous); respondent’s father born in Canada (dichotomous); home owner (dichotomous); respondent’s region of residence (polytomous); dummy variable indicating whether the partner of the respondent participates in the labour market (except for single mothers).

1.2 Appendix 2: a switching regression model with three regimes and endogenous switch

Let us consider the following model:

$$ \begin{array}{*{20}l} {{y_{{0i}} = X_{{0i}} \beta _{0} + u_{{0i}} } \hfill} \\ {{y_{{1i}} = X_{{1i}} \beta _{1} + u_{{1i}} } \hfill} \\ {{y_{{2i}} = X_{{2i}} \beta _{2} + u_{{2i}} } \hfill} \\ {{I^{*}_{{0i}} = 0} \hfill} \\ {{I^{*}_{{1i}} = Z_{i} \gamma _{1} + \varepsilon _{{1i}} } \hfill} \\ {{I^{*}_{{2i}} = Z_{i} \gamma _{2} + \varepsilon _{{2i}} } \hfill} \\ \end{array} $$
(6)
$$ I_{i} = m{\text{ if }}I^{*}_{{mi}} = {\mathop {\max }\limits_{k = 0,1,2} }{\left( {I^{*}_{{ki}} } \right)} $$
(7)
$$ y_{i} = y_{{mi}} {\text{ if }}I_{i} = m $$
(8)
$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {{{\left( {u_{0} ,u_{1} ,u_{2} ,\varepsilon _{1} ,\varepsilon _{2} } \right)}\prime \sim N{\left( {0,\Sigma } \right)}\quad \Sigma = {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\Sigma _{u} }} & {{\Sigma _{{u,\varepsilon }} }} \\ {{{\sum\nolimits_{u,\varepsilon }^{} \prime }}} & {{\Sigma _{\varepsilon } }} \\ \end{array} } \right)}} \hfill} \\ {{\Sigma _{u} = {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\sigma _{0} }} & {{\sigma _{{01}} }} & {{\sigma _{{02}} }} \\ {{\sigma _{{01}} }} & {{\sigma _{1} }} & {{\sigma _{{12}} }} \\ {{\sigma _{{02}} }} & {{\sigma _{{12}} }} & {{\sigma _{2} }} \\ \end{array} } \right)},\Sigma _{\varepsilon } = {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {1} & {{\sigma _{\varepsilon } }} \\ {{\sigma _{\varepsilon } }} & {1} \\ \end{array} } \right)},\Sigma _{{u,\varepsilon }} = {\left( {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\sigma _{{0,\varepsilon _{1} }} }} & {{\sigma _{{0,\varepsilon _{2} }} }} \\ \end{array} }} \\ {{\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\sigma _{{1,\varepsilon _{1} }} }} & {{\sigma _{{1,\varepsilon _{2} }} }} \\ \end{array} }} \\ {{\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{\sigma _{{2,\varepsilon _{1} }} }} & {{\sigma _{{2,\varepsilon _{2} }} }} \\ \end{array} }} \\ \end{array} } \right)}} \hfill} \\ \end{array} $$
(9)

y is the dependent variable. I i indicates to which regime individual i belongs (0, 1 or 2).

As we only observe I i and not \(I^{*}_{i} ,\) we normalise the variances of the ɛ’s to 1. Moreover, people are never observed in several regimes. As a consequence, the \( \sigma _{{ij}} \;{\left( {i = 0,1,2;i \ne j} \right)} \) will not appear in the likelihood and cannot therefore be identified.

The likelihood of an observation can be written:

$$ L = {\sum\limits_{m = 0,1,2} {f{\left( {Y = y_{m} \left| {I = m} \right.} \right)}P{\left( {I = m} \right)}} } = {\sum\limits_{m = 0,1,2} {f{\left( {Y = y_{m} } \right)}P{\left( {I = m\left| {Y = y_{m} } \right.} \right)}} } $$

where \( f{\left( {Y = y_{m} } \right)} = \varphi {\left( {y_{m} ;0,\sigma _{m} } \right)} \) is the density of Y in the regime m.

The computation of the marginal probabilities only requires the cumulative of the binormal distribution.

This model can easily be extended for M regimes, with M  ≥ 2. However, it involves the computation of the cumulative of the (M − 1) normal distribution and thus requires, for M  > 3, the use of a Geweke–Hajivassiliou–Keane simulator, for example.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Rapoport, B., Le Bourdais, C. Parental time and working schedules. J Popul Econ 21, 903–932 (2008). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-007-0147-6

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00148-007-0147-6

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation