Introduction

Invasive meningococcal disease (IMD) accounts worldwide for around 75,000 deaths annually (Lozano et al. 2012). Incidence rates correlate with age and socio-economic deprivation especially crowded housing.

Although disease incidence is at historic lows, the overall case–fatality ratio (CFR) ranges between 5 and 10 % in developed countries (Healy et al. 2002; Pouwels et al. 2013; Ben-Shimol et al. 2012; Scholten et al. 1994). Some of these survivors acquire long-term sequelae (e.g., neurologic disability, limb or digit loss, and hearing loss).

The introduction of vaccinations against other meningococcal serotypes (A, C, W, Y) has caused a shift towards serogroup B becoming the main cause of IMD in high income countries (Sridhar et al. 2015), though in Israel it has been dominant since reliable records became available in the mid-1970s.

Australasia (especially New Zealand), Europe (especially Eire and Eastern Norway), North America (especially Eastern Canada), and South America (especially Chile) had high incidence of MEN B. In contrast, China, India and sub-Saharan Africa (except for South Africa) had very few cases (Sridhar et al. 2015). The CFR from serogroup B meningococcal disease (MEN B) ranges between 3 and 10 % in non-outbreak scenarios (Sridhar et al. 2015). There can also be substantial morbidity due to long-term sequelae in survivors (Centres for Disease Control and Prevention 2005), despite the fact that sequelae-related damage has decreased, due to medical care improvements, including earlier diagnostic recognition.

In Israel, overall IMD incidence rates declined from 1.7 to 1.0/100,000 during the past 30 years (Israel Center for Disease Control 2012). Meningitis constituted 69.2 % of all cases, the most common serogroup being MENB which accounted for around three-quarters of IMD case isolates (76.9 %) (Ben-Shimol et al. 2012).

Prevention and control of IMD is a public health challenge due to the rapid disease onset, occasional fulminant course, and subsequent sequelae and mortality. Efficacious vaccines against serogroups A, C, Y, W135 are available. A licensed (Gorringe and Pajon 2012), immunogenic and tolerable MENB vaccine (Gill 2013) received positive endorsement from the European Medicines Agency (Novartis 2012) (Bexsero, Novartis) and approval from the US FDA (FDA News Release 2014). In September 2015, MEN B was added to the routine childhood immunization programme schedule in the UK (Hakin and Cosford 2015) after repeated cost-utility analyses (Wise 2014).

This study uses cost-utility analysis, to evaluate the possibility of instituting a nationwide vaccination programme of infants against MENB in Israel in terms of its cost per disability-adjusted life year (DALY) averted. The model could easily be adapted for use in other developed or developing countries.

Methods

Data sources

Data on cases in Israel during 2000–2010 (Erickson and De Wals 1998) were supplemented with data from 2011 to 2013 obtained from the Ministry of Health’s Epidemiology department. Detailed information was obtained on 236 IMD cases (73 % being MEN B) in the Jerusalem district from published data (Stein-Zamir et al. 2008, 2014), hospital files and laboratory results. Data from Jerusalem were extrapolated to the whole of Israel, whenever national data were not available. From these reports, we calculated national age-specific incidence rates, mortality and morbidity rates and case fatality rates for MEN B infections.

Cost-utility analysis: basic model

A Microsoft Excel spreadsheet model was constructed, incorporating vaccine efficacy, epidemiological, health service utilisation, demographic and economic data (listed with sources in Supplementary Material Appendix I). The model calculated the effect of vaccinations against MEN B (for a 10-year period) on incidence and mortality over a 100-year time horizon. Age, gender and ethnic population and birth cohort projections were based on the trend for the years 2006–2013 (Central Bureau of Statistics 2015).

The cost–utility ratio (CUR) calculated the net costs per averted disability-adjusted life year (DALY) added as a result of using the new vaccine, using the formula:

$${\text{Net costs per averted DALY }} = \frac{{{\text{Costs of vaccination }}{-}{\text{ Savings in treating IMD}}}}{\text{DALYs averted from decreased mortality and morbidity}}.$$

Costs are viewed from a societal perspective at mid-2013 price levels at the average annual exchange rate of 3.61 shekels to the US dollar (Central Bureau of Statistics 2015). These included costs not only incurred by the health and welfare services but also of work absences and transport costs to receive treatment. All future costs and DALY were discounted at an annual rate of 3 %. Data on out-of-pocket expenses or DALYs averted from reduced caregiver burden were not available.

Vaccine efficacy

Unfortunately, at the time of constructing the model, there was a lack of published information on clonal complexes, protein variants and peptide identities which precluded us from making an Israeli-specific estimate of cases caused by strains covered by the vaccine. In the absence of Israeli-specific strain data, we conservatively assumed the strain coverage of the vaccine to be the lower bound of a UK estimate of 66 % (JCVI 2014; Tu et al. 2014) increasing to 88 % in a sensitivity analysis (JCVI 2014), which takes into account the evidence that use of the meningococcal antigen typing system (MATS) assay, underestimated 4CMenB vaccine strain coverage (Frosi et al. 2013). Following recent recommendations for the UK (JCVI 2014), we assumed a three dose vaccine schedule (2, 4, 12 months) as opposed to a four dose schedule (Vesikari et al. 2013).

Vaccine efficacy against covered strains was assumed to be 90 % (Pouwels et al. 2013; JCVI 2014; Tu et al. 2014, Christensen et al. 2013). We conservatively assumed the first dose offered no protection, but the second dose provided 47 % overall protective efficacy (Arnold et al. 2011). Because of evidence of waning efficacy found in similar outer membrane vaccine types (Holst et al. 2003) we incorporated differential waning rates by age of vaccination (<1, 1–3 and >3 years old) into the model [Personal Communication, Hules, Novartis] following a negative exponential trend similar to that found with MEN C vaccination (De Wals et al. 2011).

Intervention costs

We assumed a baseline vaccine price of $60 per dose (range $10–$110), in keeping with vaccine prices used in previous cost-utility analyses (Pouwels et al. 2013; Tu et al. 2014; Christensen et al. 2013). Since at each point of the vaccine schedule the infant received other concurrent vaccinations, additional transport costs and work losses for bringing the child to the clinic were not included. Provision was made for treatment costs, transport costs and work losses arising from the visits to health service providers for vaccine side effects, mainly fever related (Vesikari et al. 2013; Gossger et al. 2012; McNicholas et al. 2007).

Incidence of GP visits for side effects of 0.23 % was based on the 0.13 % excess of fevers in persons (Vesikari et al. 2013) receiving MENB plus routine vaccinations (0.74 %) over persons receiving just routine vaccinations (0.61 %). Incidence of hospital visits of 0.00034 % was obtained by adjusting GP visit incidence by the reported ratio of hospital to GP visit from a post-marketing trial in New Zealand (McNicholas et al. 2007). A sensitivity analysis was based on the 2.2 times higher vaccine related serious adverse events reported in another study (Gossger et al. 2012).

Vaccine wastage based on operational experience in Israel was around 0.5 %. Costs were included relating to nurse’s and administration time, health education, syringes and swabs. Due to excess capacity in the system, no extra cold chain costs were incurred. Costs of vaccinating older children in nurseries or schools by public health nurses were calculated separately, with appropriate provision for travelling time and costs.

Herd immunity

Our baseline scenario assumed there was no herd immunity (see discussion). However, herd immunity was incorporated into a sensitivity analysis by assuming that the age-specific force of infection was directly proportional to the number of incident cases, treating the Jewish and non-Jewish populations as separate sectors (i.e.: vaccinating a 1-year old would only affect 1-year olds and not susceptible older children or adults). The reduced force of infection after vaccination was then applied to the exposed population (i.e.: unvaccinated persons who had not previously contracted MEN B).

This sectorial separation generally holds for persons in kinder-garden, school and army but is weaker when applied for university and workplace population interactions. A second sensitivity analysis on herd immunity assumed the effect of reduced force of infection applied across all age groups.

Costs of acute cases

Acute care costs were calculated by multiplying the expected number of cases by the unit costs of health services received. Chemoprophylaxis and follow-up costs, of contacts which included time taken to trace and visit contacts (Wright et al. 2013), were added.

Chronic sequelae

Incidence, costs and disability weight (DW) associated with chronic sequelae from MEN B are described in detail in the Supplementary Material (Appendix III).

Averted DALY losses

Total DALY losses averted were calculated by summing the morbidity and mortality DALY losses averted from decreased incidence of MENB as a result of vaccination (see Supplementary Material Appendix IV).

Decision rules

Taking into account the resources available in Israel, an intervention was defined as being very cost-effective and cost-effective if the cost per averted DALY is less than the per capita GNP of $36,167 in 2013 (Central Bureau of Statistics 2015) or between 1 and 3 times the per capita GDP ($36,167–$108,501), respectively. If the cost per averted DALY is more than three times the GDP per capita ($108,501) then the intervention was regarded as not being cost-effective (WHO Commission on MacroEconomics and Health 2001).

Sensitivity analyses

One-way sensitivity analyses were carried out by varying the values of major input parameters (vaccination costs, incidence rates, waning rates, incidence and costs of sequelae, herd immunity, discount rate) in turn by +20 %. This enabled elasticity’s of the CUR (defined as % change in CUR/% change in major variable) to be compared across a homogeneous metric.

Two-way sensitivity analyses were carried out on the ex-ante expected major drivers of vaccination costs and carriage strain coverage.

Three-way sensitivity analyses were carried out on by vaccination costs, incidence rates, carriage strain coverage along with adding two dose (JCVI 2014) catch-up campaigns for ranges of children aged 1–2, …, 1–5 (i.e. up to pre-school) … 1–12 (i.e. up to senior school), 1–13.

Results

Epidemiology

During 2000–2013, 940 reported cases of IMD occurred in Israel (annual incidence rate 0.94/100,000). Around 699 cases (74.4 %) were caused by MEN B (annual incidence rate 0.70/100,000), 57.2 % in males. The majority of MEN B cases (85.7 %) occurred in children <15 years, infants accounting for 36 % of all cases (annual incidence rate of 12.0/100,000). Around 73 people died from MEN B (CFR = 5.4 %). The CFR was 4.5 % in infants, and 6.7, 3.9 and 6.6 % in persons aged 1–4, 5–14 and 15+, respectively.

Cost-utility analysis, treatment costs

Applying the age–gender and ethnic-specific incidence rates from 2000 to 2013 to the 2013 population of 7,978,067 (Central Bureau of Statistics 2015) gives an estimate of 56.1 cases of MEN B in 2013. Around 62.9 % of these cases would require a visit to a primary care physician (PCP costing $13.80).

Around 7.9 % of MEN B deaths (0.24 cases) occur before the patient reaches the emergency room (ER) costing $341 per case (Ginsberg et al. 2015). A further 0.24 cases die in the ER, costing $565 per case (Ministry of Health 2012; Jacobs and Noseworthy 1990). Another 2.6 cases die in intensive care units (ICU). Around 55.3 cases are hospitalised (average cost of $9511), based on 3.5 days in an ICU (Jacobs and Noseworthy 1990; Scott et al. 2002) and 6.1 days in a non-ICU department (Ministry of Health 2012). All 53 survivors utilise audio-visual screening tests ($1007) and a post-discharge out-patient visit ($77) (Ministry of Health 2012).

Chemoprophylaxis costs for the average of 41 contacts per case, of whom, approximately 5 % are untraceable with 80 % receiving post-exposure prophylaxis at a health centre, amount to $27.71 per contact.

Vaccination results in their being 155 fewer cases, of which 95.5 % were prevented during the first 25 years of the programme (Table 1). Average cost per incident case was $11,286. Total projected costs of treating incident cases in the no vaccine scenario are $51.9 million, falling to $49.1 million if vaccinations were implemented (Table 2).

Table 1 Effects (2013–2112) of vaccinating Israeli cohort aged 0–1 for 10 years with/without 1–4 years catch-up
Table 2 Discounted costs, savings and costs per averted disability-adjusted life year (Israel 2013)

Sequelae incidence and costs (Table 2)

The neurological sequelae rate was 19.3 % (Stein-Zamir et al. 2014). Discounted average lifetime costs (age-specific in the model, but presented for illustration just for the age group 1–4 years) of treating a case with severe neurological disorders [1.75 % of survivors (Stein-Zamir et al. 2014)] were $701,000, mild-to-moderate neurological disorders [7.0 % (Stein-Zamir et al. 2014), $256,000], light neurological disorders [10.5 % (Stein-Zamir et al. 2014), $29,400], bilateral hearing loss (1.75 %, $167,000), unilateral hearing loss (1.75 %, $96,000), mild hearing disorder (3.5 %, $20,700), seizures [1.75 % (Holst et al. 2003), $53,400 (Scott et al. 2002)], scarring [3.9 % (Healy et al. 2002; Scholten et al. 1994; Edwards et al. 1981; Vesikari et al. 2013), $6900 (Bettinger et al. 2013)], renal problems (3.5 % (Healy et al. 2002; Scholten et al. 1994; Erickson and De Wals 1998; Bettinger et al. 2013), $121,000 (Erickson and De Wals 1998; Slack et al. 2005; Buysse et al. 2008, 2010)], digital amputations (0.64 %, $2954).

The total projected costs of treating sequelae in the no-vaccination scenario are $189,000,000, almost four times the $49,000,000 costs of treating the acute phase of MEN B (including chemoprophylaxis and follow-up). Costs of treating sequelae fall to $47,300,000 in the vaccination scenario (Table 2).

Intervention costs

Persons receiving MENB plus routine vaccinations were assumed to have an excess 0.23 % visits to a PCP (Vesikari et al. 2013) for medical attention (costing $13.80 per visit) mainly on account of fevers, compared with recipients of routine vaccinations only. Excess hospitalizations in 0.00034 % of vaccinations (Gossger et al. 2012) were assumed for an average of four days, costing $2244 per admission.

The target population are the 170,819 (Central Bureau of Statistics 2015) infants born in 2013 and the subsequent nine years. While vaccine coverage would be nationwide (i.e. 100 %), compliance rates were assumed to be 93 and 98 % in the Jewish and non-Jewish populations, respectively, based on coverage achieved for DTaP and Hepatitis B vaccinations (Central Bureau of Statistics 2015).

Total vaccination costs for a MEN B vaccination programme in 2013 amount to $32,500,000 million, with (discounted) intervention costs over 10 years being $315,400,000 (Table 2).

Cost-utility ratios

The 10-year vaccination programme would result in 155 fewer MEN B cases, 16 fewer deaths and an extra 1336 potential years of life added (Table 1). Total treatment costs of MEN B cases and sequelae would fall by $1.4 and $13.1 million, respectively. A further $102,000 would be saved in delayed burial costs. In addition, around $5.5 million would be saved due to decreased work absences, resulting in a total saving of $20.1 million, resulting in a net programme cost of $295.3 million (Table 2).

Decreased mortality, incident and sequelae cases would avert 964, 3.8 and 8.2 discounted DALYs, respectively (Table 3). The net cost ($295.3 million) per averted DALY (976) amounts to $302,630 (Table 2), as this is in excess of thrice the per capita GDP threshold of $108,501, the intervention is not cost-effective. If the vaccine strain coverage was 88 % then the cost per averted DALY falls to $245,472, which is still not cost-effective.

Table 3 Disability-adjusted life years lost due to mortality and morbidity by intervention (Israel 2013)

Catch-up campaigns

Costs ranged from a not cost-effective $302,590 to $412,255 per averted DALY if children aged 1–2 and 1–12, respectively, are included in the campaign (Fig. 1). Vaccine costs would have to fall below $19.33 or $12.62 per dose to ensure that the average cost per averted DALY of including children aged 1–5 (pre-schoolers) or aged 1–12 (pre senior-schoolers) in a national infant vaccination campaign would be cost-effective. For vaccine strain coverage of 88 %, cost per averted DALY ranged from $244,781 to $332,617 (Fig. 1). Vaccine costs would have to fall below $24.88 or $16.86 per dose, respectively, to attain cost-effectiveness for 1–2 and 1–12-year-old catch-up campaigns.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Cost per disability-adjusted life year by catch-up ages and strain coverage (Israel 2003)

Sensitivity analyses (Fig. 2 and Supplementary Material Appendix II)

Adjustment of the vaccine price by 20 % to $72 and $48 per dose resulted in costs per averted DALY of $360,000 and $245,000, respectively. The break-even vaccine price for cost-effectiveness is $19.44 and rises to $24.88 if the vaccine strain coverage rises to 88 %.

Fig. 2
figure 2

Cost per disability-adjusted life year (one-way sensitivity analyses, Israel 2013)

Because of the small size of the Jerusalem sequelae study, we carried out a sensitivity analysis of MEN B sequelae rates based on data from five (n = 1480) literature studies (Healy et al. 2002; Scholten et al. 1994; Erickson and De Wals 1998; Bettinger et al. 2013; Viner et al. 2012), except for mild-medium and light neurological sequelae where no alternative data (to our Jerusalem data) were available. An average DW of 0.19 with a cost of $57,710 per amputee was imputed for amputations based on applying limb specific costs data (World Health Organization 1996) to the (sometimes multiple) limb specific distribution of amputee cases from the literature (Erickson and De Wals 1998; Slack et al. 2005; Viner et al. 2012; Buysse et al. 2009). After making all these adjustments the cost per averted DALY to $298,000.

The CUR was sensitive to changes in the MEN B incidence rate, vaccine efficacy and its waning rate. However, to attain cost-effectiveness, incidence rates would have to rise from 0.70 to 1.77 per by 100,000. Cost-effectiveness would not be obtained (CUR = $204,474) even with 100 % vaccine efficacy against all strains (c.f. 66 %) or had a 0 % waning rate (CUR = $199,563). The CUR was insensitive to changes in the discount rate, MEN B, vaccine side effects, disability weights of sequelae or unit treatment costs (Fig. 2).

Assuming our baseline conservative assumption, that the new protein-based vaccine does not induce herd immunity is erroneous (Dellicour and Greenwood 2007), results in the model showing the cost per averted DALY decreasing to a still not cost-effective range of between $234,000 and $284,000 depending on whether carriage was within or across age groups (Fig. 2).

At the baseline price of $60 per vaccine shot, threshold incidence rates for cost-effectiveness would be 1.83, 2.5 and 2.93 for catch-up campaigns covering infants, 0–5 and 0–12-year olds, respectively (Fig. 3, upper). For illustration, assuming we could identify an area with 3/100,000 incidence rates (about four times the national average), then the cost-effective vaccine price thresholds would be $105 (around current price), $83 and $62, respectively (Fig. 3, lower).

Fig. 3
figure 3

Cost per disability-adjusted life year (upper) and break-even vaccine cost (lower) by incidence and age of vaccination (Israel 2013)

Discussion

MENB is the leading cause of invasive meningococcal disease (IMD) in Israel. The availability of a new vaccine against MEN B prompted an ex-ante evaluation of a three dose childhood vaccination programme.

The price of the vaccine is obviously a major driver of costs per DALY averted. At $60 per dose, the intervention cost of $302,630 per DALY averted, clearly renders it not cost-effective. Vaccine prices would have to fall below $19.44 and $4.32 in order to render the intervention to be cost-effective or very cost-effective. Catch-up campaigns (based on a two dose schedule) would not be a cost-effective addition due to the lower child age-specific incidence rates. However, they could become cost-effective if the vaccine costs were to fall substantially. Focussed campaigns in high risk areas (such as universities) or at times of disease outbreaks are likely to be cost-effective even at present vaccine prices depending on the level of excess disease incidence.

Our vaccine price (used to attain the British $48,000 cost-effectiveness threshold) threshold of $6.79 was far smaller than the reported $24 threshold vaccine price in a British modelling study (Christensen et al. 2013). This difference was primarily attributable to the British model being based on far higher disease incidence rates. In addition, the British model assumed herd immunity, which caused a 41 % reduction in the cost-utility ratio (CUR) compared to their sensitivity analysis omitting herd immunity. A recent re-evaluation study suggested that routine infant vaccination could be cost-effective if the vaccine could be procured at <20 % of the list price of around $110 a dose, although the cost-effective threshold vaccine price varied with different assumptions used in the modelling (Christensen et al. 2014).

A manufacturer-funded model developed by Novartis (Huels et al. 2013) incorporated all the elements of the burden of disease model (McNicholas et al. 2007) that favoured the adoption of the vaccine, resulting in a $12–$33 price range for economically justifiable infant vaccinations (compared to our models $6.79) based on the same $48,000 threshold. The most questionable of these assumptions being the accounting of lost productivity associated with a potential slight decrease in IQ for a significant proportion of survivors (Meningococcal B Pilot Project Task Group 2014).

In contrast, our costs per DALY averted were lower than those of a recent Dutch study (with no herd immunity) (Pouwels et al. 2013), despite incidence rates being about 50 % higher than in Israel. The Dutch study reported the vaccine price would have to fall below $4.55 (compared to $10.14 in our study) in order for cost-effectiveness ratio to fall below their $64,000 threshold. We can only speculate that, besides inevitable difference in model structures, our use of a three as opposed to a four dose schedule and higher vaccine efficacy (81.4 vs. 75 %) contributed to this difference.

Our reported cost per averted DALY was also far lower than the $4.6 million reported from Ontario, Canada (Tu et al. 2014). This was mainly attributable to the far lower annual incidence rates in Ontario (0.19 vs. 0.70/100,000) but also due to the Canadian study using a higher baseline vaccine price ($72.83 vs $60 per dose), lower sequelae costs and being carried out just from a payer perspective and therefore not including benefits from decreased work losses.

A recent model (excluding herd immunity) based in Italy (Tirani et al. 2015), which has very low incidence of meningococcal disease, showed that at a vaccine price of $89 per dose the introduction of routine infant Men B vaccinations is unlikely to be cost-effective.

A model based in Chile reported a $15 per dose vaccine cost-effectiveness threshold, based on a single dose mass vaccination protocol that was used in an epidemic outbreak scenario, with a high incidence rate of 5.9/100,000 (Izuierdo et al. 2015). Calculation of a comparative Israeli outbreak-based cost-utility analyses is beyond the scope of this paper as this will involve fewer doses to a far wider age group.

Our 19.3 % neurological sequelae rate was obtained from the follow-up study of 57 MEN B survivors aged 0–14 during 2000–2013 (De Wals et al. 2011), this was higher than 12.5 and 15.8 % rates reported for all serogroups in the USA (Chandran et al. 2011), and in a recent global meta-analysis (Brouwer et al. 2013), respectively.

Our baseline estimate of the CUR could be biased upwards (i.e.: making the vaccine appear to be less favourable economically) due to lack of data on:

  1. (i)

    possible sequelae, such as visual defects (Sridhar et al. 2015; Chandran et al. 2011; Edmond et al. 2010), behavioural problems (Wright et al. 2013; Edmond et al. 2010], psychological disorders (Wright et al. 2013; Viner et al. 2012).

  2. (ii)

    payments for resources such as for personal social services, home and environmental adaptations (Wright et al. 2013).

  3. (iii)

    potential DALY losses due to care burden of spouses or parents of a person handicapped by sequelae.

  4. (iv)

    work absences in adulthood arising from hearing disorders, seizures, amputations or renal disease.

An additional cause of upward bias is the fact that there has been a downward trend in reported MEN B cases since 2011, and so our incidence estimates, which were based on the 2000–2013 average, may have overestimated the impact of the vaccination.

Evidence for herd immunity was inferred from a French outbreak that suggested meningococcal OMV-based vaccines reduce meningococcal carriage in children aged 1–7 and may hence confer herd immunity (Delbos et al. 2013). A meta-analysis reported that meningococcal carriage increased with age till 19 years and then declined (Christensen et al. 2010). However, while this analysis was carried out in European countries (where disease caused by serogroups B and C dominate), no separate analysis was presented for serogroup B on its own. Weaker evidence of herd immunity comes only from MEN C conjugate vaccine studies (Trotter and Edmunds 2006; Ramsay et al. 2003).

A study of English University students reported that MENB vaccines reduced meningococcal carriage rates during the year after vaccination and therefore might affect transmission when widely implemented (Read et al. 2014). The UK guidelines stated that impact on acquisition of carriage would have a limited impact on the cost-effectiveness of an infant programme, since it is driven by direct individual protection rather than by herd immunity (JCVI 2014). As MENB vaccine has only been used at a population level since September 2015, it is not yet known if it will confer herd immunity (Meningococcal B pilot Project Task Group 2014). Therefore, we conservatively assumed, in our baseline analysis, the absence of herd protection. If this assumption is erroneous, then our baseline CUR will be upwardly biased (Trotter and Edmunds 2006).

Our CUR is slightly underestimated (i.e. making the vaccine appear to be more favourable economically) because we were unable to determine the few cases where sequelae were not mutually exclusive hence slightly overestimating averted DALYs. The CUR will also be downwardly biased if there is serogroup replacement as a result of the vaccination. However, no evidence exists as to serogroup replacement four years after the introduction of serogroup C vaccinations in the UK (Trotter et al. 2004). The vaccines true effectiveness will only be revealed through post-licensure surveillance (Gorringe and Pajon 2012). A further cause of downward bias could be that if the secular decline in IMD which was observed over the past 30 years (Israel Center for Disease Control 2012) continues, then the actual number of cases prevented by vaccination would be overestimated.

The spreadsheet model that we used could be simply and quickly adapted (by changing incidence, CFR, DEMOGRAPHIC and cost-parameters) by middle income or developing countries, especially in the meningitis belt of Africa, to evaluate the cost per QALY of introducing childhood vaccinations against MEN B. Such information will be useful for potential funding agencies such as governments or the Global Vaccine Initiative.

In September 2014, the advisory committee on infectious disease and vaccines of the Ministry of Health decided not to recommend the adoption of the new MEN B vaccine into the routine childhood vaccination programme. This was primarily because the extent of vaccine strain coverage is currently undetermined in Israel but should hopefully be available in the near future. It was also noted (on the basis of the results of this paper) that the vaccination at current price levels is unlikely to be cost-effective (even if strain coverage is very high). Vaccination will be cost-effective only in high incidence regions or if there will be a substantial decrease in prices.