Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Doctors with borders: occupational licensing as an implicit barrier to high skill migration

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Research on the political economy of immigration overlooks the specificity of human capital in skilled occupations and its implications for immigration preferences and policymaking. Conclusions that skilled Americans are unconcerned about labor market competition from skilled migrants build on a simple dichotomy between high and low skill migrants. In this article we show that natives turn to occupational licensing regulations as occupation-specific protectionist barriers to skilled migrant labor competition. In practice, high skill natives face labor market competition only from those high-skill migrants who share their occupation-specific skills. Licensure regulations ostensibly serve the public interest by certifying competence, but they can simultaneously be formidable barriers to entry by skilled migrants. From a collective action perspective, skilled natives can more easily secure sub-national, occupation-specific policies than influence national immigration policy. We exploit the unique structure of the American medical profession that allows us to distinguish between public interest and protectionist motives for migrant physician licensure regulations. We show that over the 1973–2010 period states with greater physician control over licensure requirements imposed more stringent requirements for migrant physician licensure and, as a consequence, received fewer new migrant physicians. By our estimates over a third of all US states could reduce their physician shortages by at least 10 percent within 5 years just by equalizing migrant and native licensure requirements. This article advances research on the political economy of immigration and highlights an overlooked dimension of international economic integration: regulatory rent-seeking as a barrier to the cross-national mobility of human capital, and the public policy implications of such barriers.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. See supplemental appendix for a list of licensed occupations.

  2. Mattoo and Carzaniga (2003. For example, for US hospitals to offshore diagnostic radiology services, foreign radiologists must hold a valid medical license for the state in which the hospital is located. Public safety concerns notwithstanding, countries including the United Kingdom and Singapore impose less stringent licensure requirements for the same activities (Yu and Levy 2010).

  3. The US Department of Health and Human Services defines physician shortage areas as those with a population-to-primary-care-physician ratio of greater than 3,500/1. Several factors contribute to shortages, including inadequate federal funding for graduate medical education, and weak incentives to enter primary care medical specialties and to locate in rural areas. See the supplemental appendix for further details on the measurement of physician shortages (https://dl.dropboxusercontent.com/u/3771432/doctors_licensing_SuppApp.pdf).

  4. Official ISCO-08 statistical definition of professional occupation: “Professionals increase the existing stock of knowledge, apply scientific or artistic concepts and theories, teach about the foregoing in a systematic manner, or engage in any combination of these activities.”

  5. Iversen and Soskice (2001) use an earlier version of the classification to measure skill specificity in a similar manner.

  6. Some skill sets can more easily translate across borders than others. The technical skills of an engineer or a doctor, for example, are likely more portable across national boundaries than those of a lawyer or accountant whose professional expertise is jurisdiction specific.

  7. Facchini and Mayda (2008) and Milner and Tingley (2011) assume factor mobility in their analyses of migration attitudes and policies. Hainmueller and Hiscox (2010) dismiss factor specificity by assuming a small open economy in which all goods are traded such that consumption effects could outweigh wage competition. Their reasoning does not hold when skill-specific protection is possible. Further, as we note, the only high-skill occupations are professional services, which frequently are nontraded. Inattention to skill specificity is probably also responsible for indeterminate findings on the labor market effects of migration.

  8. To some extent, the definition of occupational categories for the purposes of regulation is endogenous to lobbying because regulatory boards issue “scope of practice guidelines” that draw boundaries where functional overlap occurs in occupational tasks (e.g., nurse practitioners and physicians).

  9. See Carpenter (1996) and Wood and Waterman (1991) on funding as a form of legislative control over agencies.

  10. Historically, states frequently prohibited non-citizens from obtaining medical licenses regardless of where they were educated; however, most states eliminated these regulations in the 1970s after the US Supreme Court ruled them unconstitutional (Plascencia et al. 2003). Figure 2 suggests that IMG licensure requirements grew more stringent as a replacement for outlawed citizenship requirements.

  11. To take the exams, IMGs must provide proof that they graduated from a foreign medical school listed in the International Medical Education Directory, a list maintained by the US Educational Commission for Foreign Medical Graduates. The directory includes foreign medical schools that are accredited by their respective governments. This requirement provides another quality screen.

  12. With the exception of Canada, prior experience in foreign countries does not count toward this requirement.

  13. The system of post-graduate residency is almost entirely federally funded. The number of slots has been somewhat fixed since 1996, when Congress froze funding for additional slots.

  14. On patient health outcomes, see Norcini et al. (2010). On disciplinary actions, see Morrison and Wickersham (1998). Indeed, non-citizen IMGs consistently outperform US citizen/permanent resident IMGs at every stage of assessment described. To the extent that the latter group more clearly signals poor quality by the inability to gain admission to a US school, this pattern further establishes the effectiveness of foreign IMG quality screening.

  15. Svorny and Toma (1998). State legislatures tend to defer—even in matters of legislation—to their state medical boards and departments of health. Medical boards often assist in writing bills considered by lawmakers. Changes to a state’s medical practice act rarely are contentious, though professional organizations do lobby (see, e.g., c.f 1999 Alaska Senate Bills 71 and 29).

  16. Earlier licensure data are available, but our sample is constrained by the availability of other variables. See the supplemental appendix for details regarding data sources. https://dl.dropboxusercontent.com/u/3771432/doctors_licensing_SuppApp.pdf.

  17. Although institutional features are not randomly assigned, medium- and long-term concerns guide legislators in bureaucratic agency design (Epstein and O’Halloran 1996; Lewis 2003). The vast majority of state medical boards were created between 1870 and 1915. Because financing structures established early in a board’s history persist over time, they should be orthogonal to other salient board and state characteristics during our sample period. As an example of this persistence, a strong correlation exists between self-financing in 1952 and during our sample period (Council of State Governments 1952: p. 80). More broadly, states with self-financed licensing boards for other professions are more likely to have self-financed medical boards, suggesting that idiosyncratic factors early in a board’s history shape institutional design, rather than profession-specific considerations (ibid.).

  18. These categories are identified by the DHS. New admittees enter on a temporary or permanent visa. Adjustments of status are conversions to permanent legal residence. DHS identifies the occupation of a legal migrant upon his or her entry into the United States. For adjustments of status, the DHS uses the immigrant’s occupation prior to the individual becoming a legal permanent resident.

  19. We utilized data covering 1973–2008 from DHHS. Data for 2009 and 2010 were gathered separately and harmonized with this longer time series. See the supplemental appendix for a detailed discussion of data sources used to construct our variables. https://dl.dropboxusercontent.com/u/3771432/doctors_licensing_SuppApp.pdf.

  20. Models estimated by OLS provide identical results in terms of statistical significance and very similar results with regard to the substantive impact of board independence.

  21. See supplemental appendix for all summary statistics.

  22. We obtain similar results if we use the difference in requirements between IMGs and US medical graduates as our dependent variable.

  23. Results available upon request.

  24. A small percentage of candidates are matched outside of this process.

  25. Polsky et al. (2002). Medical licenses are not transferrable across states. In order to practice in another state, physicians must apply for a new medical license. Trainees benefit from a network and sources of information about potential opportunities, which reduce the transaction costs involved in finding employment locally.

  26. See Li et al. (2000) and Coren (2007). Residents also cite educational and career-development benefits from moonlighting (Hunt et al. 1992).

  27. Silliman et al. (1987) and Li et al. (2000). Even where residency programs prohibit or limit moonlighting, these rules tend to be enforced weakly (Li, Tabor and Martinez 2000).

  28. See, e.g., Silliman et al. (1987). IMGs typically are older, more likely to have dependents, and less likely to have a family support network nearby, which suggests that IMGs would moonlight at high rates (Gozu et al. 2009). At the same time, IMGs are less heavily indebted, which may make them less likely to moonlight (Gozu et al. 2009; Silliman et al. 1987).

  29. IMGs are less likely to be board certified than their US-trained counterparts (Akl et al. 2007).

  30. Systematic data on physicians who did not complete residency are limited, but one survey of rural departments of emergency medicine indicated that approximately 20 % of their staff physicians were residents-in-training. More importantly, a further 19 % of staff physicians had not completed residency and were no longer enrolled in residency programs (authors’ calculations based on McGirr et al. 1998: pp. 333–335). A variety of placement companies and websites cater to physicians who did not complete residency. These organizations list both clinical and non-clinical positions, particularly in biomedical research and allied health professions (Yoo et al. 2009).

  31. Even with disaggregated data, we would probably be unable to identify most of the parameters because most IMGs in the United States originate from approximately 20 countries.

  32. Entry into the United States through educational/work visas, and the accompanying documentation from their US sponsors, ensures that these migrants are physicians as the occupation is defined in the United States. It is possible that migrants entering on family reunification visas self-report as physicians and therefore appear in our data. Non-practicing physicians in our data do not bias our results, because their state-location choice should not correlate with the stringency of state physician licensing.

  33. https://dl.dropboxusercontent.com/u/3771432/doctors_licensing_SuppApp.pdf.

  34. The expected increase in foreign physicians into a state correlates highly with the degree of physician shortage it faces (ρ = 0.77).

  35. These estimates must be interpreted with caution. We have no way of accounting for attrition if foreign-trained physicians leave the state after completing their training or if additional physicians—either foreign or domestically trained—migrate to the state in question.

  36. States to the left of the line may have political environments that are hostile to undocumented workers—something that may proxy for the overall desirability of a state from the point of a view of a foreign-born individual. This area is left for future research.

  37. Our estimates of reduced emergency department visits compare favorably to other highly-touted healthcare reforms, such as the introduction of High Deductible Health Plans (HDHPs) with Health Savings Accounts. Based on estimates of the impact of HDHPs (Wharam et al 2007), equalizing licensure requirements for native and foreign-educated physicians would reduce emergency department visits as much as enrolling an additional 2.5 million American in HDHPs, or an 18.5 percent increase in current HDHP enrollment. See the supplemental appendix for a detailed explanation of these cost estimates. https://dl.dropboxusercontent.com/u/3771432/doctors_licensing_SuppApp.pdf.

References

  • Akl, E. A., et al. (2007). The United States physician workforce and international medical graduates: Trends and characteristics. Journal of General Internal Medicine, 22(2), 264–268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G.S. (2009). Human Capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

  • Borjas, G. J. (1994). The economics of immigration. Journal of Economic Literature, 32, 1667–1717.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulet, J. R., et al. (2006). The international medical graduate pipeline: Recent trends in certification and residency training. Health Affairs, 25(2), 469–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Broscheid, A., & Teske, P. (2003). Public members on medical licensing boards and the choice of entry barriers. Public Choice, 114(3), 445–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, D. P. (1996). Adaptive signal processing, hierarchy, and budget control in federal regulation. American Political Science Review, 90(2), 283–302.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coren, J. S. (2007). A moonlighting position can help you hone your medical skills while boosting your income. Family Practice Management, 14(3), 41–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Council of State Governments. (1952). Occupational licensing legislation in the states. Chicago: The Council of State Governments.

    Google Scholar 

  • Culler, S. D., & Bazzoli, G. J. (1985). The moonlighting decisions of resident physicians. Journal of Health Economics, 4(3), 283–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dill, M. J., & Salsberg, E. S. (2008). The complexities of physician supply and demand: Projections through 2025. Washington, DC: Association of American Medical Colleges.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorsey, E. R., Nicholson, S., & Frist, W. H. (2011). Commentary: Improving the supply and distribution of primary care physicians. Academic Medicine, 86(5), 541–543.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, D., & O’Halloran, S. (1996). Divided government and the design of administrative procedures: A formal model and empirical test. Journal of Politics, 58(2), 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Facchini, G., & Mayda, A. M. (2008). From individual attitudes towards migrants to migration policy outcomes: Theory and evidence. IZA Working Paper No. 3512.

  • Facchini, G., & Mayda, A. M. (2012). Individual attitudes towards skilled migration: An empirical analysis across countries. The World Economy, 35(2), 183–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frieden, J. A. (1991). Invested interests: The politics of national economic policies in a world of global finance. International Organization, 45(4), 425–451.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M., & Kuznets, S. (1945). Income from independent professional practice. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodson, J. D. (2010). Patient protection and Affordable Care Act: Promise and peril for primary care. Annals of Internal Medicine, 152(11), 742–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gozu, A., Kern, D. E., & Wright, S. M. (2009). Similarities and differences between international medical graduates and U.S. medical graduates at six Maryland community-based internal medicine residency training programs. Academic Medicine, 84(3), 385–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Graddy, E. (1991). Interest groups or the public interest: Why do we regulate health occupations? Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law, 16(1), 25–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (2001). Special interest politics. Boston: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hainmueller, J., & Hiscox, M. J. (2007). Educated preferences: Explaining individual attitudes toward immigration in Europe. International Organization, 61(2), 399–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hainmueller, J., & Hiscox, M. J. (2010). Attitudes toward highly skilled and low skilled immigration: Evidence from a survey experiment. American Political Science Review, 104(01), 61–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, G. H., Scheve, K., & Slaughter, M. J. (2007). Public finance and individual preferences over globalization strategies. Economics and Politics, 19(1), 1–33.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanson, G. H., Scheve, K., & Slaughter, M. J. (2009). Individual preferences over high-skilled immigration in the United States. In Jagdish Bhagwati & Gordon Hanson (Eds.), Skilled immigration today: Prospects, problems and policies (pp. 207–243). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Hiscox, M. J. (2002). Commerce, coalitions and factor mobility: Evidence from congressional votes on trade legislation. American Political Science Review, 96(3), 593–608.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, K. R., Hillman, B. J., & Witzke, D. B. (1992). Moonlighting during the radiology residency. Investigative Radiology, 27(11), 978–983.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T. (2005). Capitalism, democracy and welfare. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2001). An asset theory of social policy preferences. American Political Science Review, 95(4), 875–894.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jolly, P., et al. (2011). Participation in U.S. graduate medical education by graduates of international medical schools. Academic Medicine, 86(5), 559–564.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King, M., et al. (2010). Integrated public use microdata series, current population survey: Version 3.0 [database]. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kleiner, M. M. (2000). Occupational licensing. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), 189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kleiner, M. M., & Krueger, A. B. (2010). The prevalence and effects of occupational licensing. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 48(4), 676–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kugler, A. D., & Sauer, R. M. (2005). Doctors without borders? Relicensing requirements and negative selection in the market for physicians. Journal of Labor Economics, 23(3), 437–465.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Law, M. T., & Kim, S. (2005). Specialization and regulation: The rise of professionals and the emergence of occupational licensing regulation. The Journal of Economic History, 65(03), 723–756.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H. E. (1979). Quacks, lemons, and licensing: A theory of minimum quality standards. The Journal of Political Economy, 87(6), 1328–1346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, D. E. (2003). Presidents and the politics of agency design: Political insulation in the United States government bureaucracy, 1946–1997. Redwood City, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, J., Tabor, R., & Martinez, M. (2000). Survey of moonlighting practices and work requirements of emergency medicine residents. American Journal of Emergency Medicine, 18(2), 147–151.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mattoo, A., & Carzaniga, A. G. (Eds.). (2003). Moving people to deliver services. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGirr, J., Williams, J. M., & Prescott, J. E. (1998). Physicians in rural West Virginia emergency departments: Residency training and board certification status. Academic Emergency Medicine, 5(4), 333–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mick, S. S., Lee, S. Y. D., & Wodchis, W. P. (2000). Variations in geographical distribution of foreign and domestically trained physicians in the United States: “Safety nets” or “surplus exacerbation”? Social Science and Medicine, 50(2), 185–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Milner, H., & Tingley, D. (2011). The economic and political influences on different dimensions of United States immigration policy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morrison, J., & Wickersham, P. (1998). Physicians disciplined by a state medical board. Journal of the American Medical Association, 279(23), 1889–1893.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norcini, J. J., et al. (2010). Evaluating the quality of care provided by graduates of international medical schools. Health Affairs, 29(8), 1461–1468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2), 211–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plascencia, L. F. B., Freeman, G. P., & Setzler, M. (2003). The decline of barriers to immigrant economic and political rights in the American states: 1977–2001. International Migration Review, 37(1), 5–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polsky, D., et al. (2002). Initial practice locations of international medical graduates. Health Services Research, 37(4), 907–928.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Santos Silva, J. M. C., & Tenreyo, S. (2010). On the existence of the maximum likelihood estimates in Poisson regression. Economics Letters, 107, 310–312.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Silliman, R. A., et al. (1987). Debt, moonlighting and career decisions among internal medicine residents. Journal of Medical Education, 62(6), 463–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1971). The theory of economic regulation. The Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2(1), 3–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svorny, S., & Toma, E. F. (1998). Entry barriers and medical board funding autonomy. Public Choice, 97(1/2), 93–106.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tenn, S. A. (2001). Three essays on the relationship between migration and occupational licensing. Chicago: The University of Chicago.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B. R. (1980). Physicians, DNA research scientists and the market for lemons. In Blair and Rubin (Eds.), Regulating the professions. Washington, DC: Lexington Books.

  • Weingast, B. R., & Moran, M. J. (1983). Bureaucratic discretion or congressional control? Regulatory policymaking by the Federal Trade Commission. Journal of Political Economy, 91(5), 765–800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wharam, J.F., et al. (2007). Emergency department use and subsequent hospitalizations among members of a high-deductible health plan. Journal of the American Medical Association, 297(10), 1093-1102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whelan, G. P., et al. (2002). The changing pool of international medical graduates seeking certification training in US graduate medical education programs. Journal of the American Medical Association, 288(9), 1079–1084.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, B. D., & Waterman, R. W. (1991). The dynamics of political control of the bureaucracy. American Political Science Review, 85(3), 801–828.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yoo, P. S., et al. (2009). AVAS Best Clinical Resident Award (Tied): Fate of non-designated preliminary general surgery residents seeking a categorical residency position. The American Journal of Surgery, 198, 593–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu, K.-H., & Levy, F. (2010). Offshoring professional services: Institutions and professional control. British Journal of Industrial Relations, 48(4), 758–783.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

For their assistance with data collection, we are grateful to John Simanski and Michael Hoeferin of the Office of Immigration Statistics, US Department of Homeland Security, and Amber Dushman of the American Medical Association. We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the University of Virginia’s Bankard Fund for Political Economy and Quantitative Collaborative Seed Grant Initiative. For their thoughtful feedback and suggestions, we thank the editors of Public Choice, two anonymous reviewers, Christina Davis, Gary Freeman, Tim Garson, Jason Hicks, Eric Patashnik, Craig Volden, Gay Wehrli, Casey White, and participants at the 2012 Midwest Political Science Association and International Political Economy Society meetings.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sonal S. Pandya.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Peterson, B.D., Pandya, S.S. & Leblang, D. Doctors with borders: occupational licensing as an implicit barrier to high skill migration. Public Choice 160, 45–63 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0152-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0152-8

Keywords

Navigation