Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Is capital back? The role of land ownership and savings behavior

  • Published:
International Tax and Public Finance Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Wealth inequality is a major political concern in most OECD countries. Under this premise, we analyze different policy instruments in terms of their impact on wealth inequality and output. In a general equilibrium model, we disaggregate wealth in its capital and land components, and savings in their life-cycle and bequest components. Households are heterogeneous in their taste for leaving bequests. We show that governments have considerable freedom in reducing wealth inequality without sacrificing output: Land rent taxes enhance output due to a portfolio effect and reduce wealth inequality slightly. Bequest taxes have the highest potential to reduce inequality, and their effect on output is moderate. By contrast, we confirm the standard result that capital taxes reduce output strongly and show that they only have moderate redistributive effects. Furthermore, we find that using the tax proceeds for transfers to the young generations enhances output the most and further reduces wealth inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Although Piketty and Saez (2013) is titled A Theory of Optimal Inheritance Taxation, the tax on bequests which they analyze is equivalent to a capital tax (p. 1854, Footnote 4). Accordingly, the title of their working paper version Piketty and Saez (2012) is A Theory of Optimal Capital Taxation.

  2. Recently, Straub and Werning (2014) have called the zero-capital-tax result of Judd (1985) and Chamley (1986) into question. However, Straub and Werning rely on the assumption that consumption taxes are not available—their model thus constitutes an “extreme example of an incomplete set of fiscal instruments” as Chari, Nicolini, and Teles, point out in their manuscript More on the taxation of capital.

  3. In contrast to Stiglitz (2016), Homburg (2015) seems to dismiss the distributional implications of the dynamics of land rent ownership in the conclusion of his article.

  4. Feldstein (1977) was the first to identify the portfolio effect, which Mountford (2004) and Petrucci (2006) further formalized. Edenhofer et al. (2015) extended the analysis of the portfolio effect by introducing a social welfare function as a normative benchmark for evaluating fiscal policy, in particular land rent taxes. The present paper, in contrast, takes a positive approach and focuses on the economic impacts of fiscal policy. Hence, we do not consider a social welfare function. Nevertheless, we find that under land rent taxation the winners of the policy could theoretically compensate the losers. Thus, land rent taxation fulfills the Kaldor–Hicks criterion (see Appendix C).

  5. For a discussion of the transmission of tastes from one generation to the next, see for example de la Croix and Michel (2002) and Black et al. (2015). Both publications provide evidence suggesting that our simplifying assumption is justified as a first-order approximation.

  6. We shall make use of the convention that all households choose the same asset composition. More precisely, in every period t there is an \(X_t > 0\) such that \(X_t = k^s_{i,t}/l_{i,t}\) for all \(i \in \{1,\ldots ,N\}\). We use this convention because there is an infinite continuum of possible combinations of individual asset portfolio compositions of each household i that have no bearing on any of our results.

  7. For example, the analytical method applied by Mountford (2004) to a dynamic system with two state variables already leads to inconclusive results if the number of states is increased by one dimension (i.e.  bequests are added to his model) and households are still assumed to be homogeneous.

  8. Similar to Davies (1986), we can thus separate two different effects of taxation: We first analyze only the distorting effect of different taxes on households’ investment behavior, and do not take into account the effect caused by the redistribution of the tax revenues to the households as transfers. Only in the second step we also consider the impact of the government’s transfers. In contrast to Davies (1986), however, we always allow for general equilibrium effects.

  9. In Sect. 3.2, we will discuss conditions under which capital income and bequest taxes may increase inequality.

  10. Recall that the results we obtain are independent of whether labor supply is fixed or endogenous. Thus, we abstract from a labor-leisure choice here, to keep the analysis as tractable as possible.

  11. This can be made plausible by recalling Fig.  1. Compare the set of coordinates in the policy option space that can be reached with the land rent tax alone—the green curve with circles marking the data points—with the coordinates in the policy option space that can be reached with the bequest tax—the blue curve with triangles as data points. When implementing a mix of both taxes it is likely that the coordinates that can be thus reached lie between the green (circles) and the blue (triangles) curve.

  12. The difference of 0.13 is a little bit less than the difference between the wealth distributions of the USA (with 0.93, the highest inequality within the sample given by OECD 2015), and France or Finland (both 0.77). The difference of 0.13 corresponds to the difference between the Slovak Republic (with 0.52, the most equal country in the sample), and Greece (0.65). The Gini coefficients of all countries for which OECD (2015) reports wealth distributions are given in Table 6 in Appendix B.

  13. Here, we use \(\delta = \frac{1}{2}\). In general, of course, any \(0<\delta <1\) implies transfers to both.

  14. See Appendix B, Fig. 6 for a graphical exposition of this fact.

  15. As discussed in Sect. 3.1.1, the main channel through which tax reforms change the wealth distribution in our model is the difference in income composition, i.e. the ratio of bequests to wages in total income.

References

  • Ackerman, B., & Alstott, A. (1999). The stakeholder society. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1989). Giving with impure altruism: Applications to charity and Ricardian equivalence. The Journal of Political Economy, 97, 1447–1458.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, J. (2008). Do tax structures affect aggregate economic growth? Empirical evidence from a panel of OECD countries. Working Paper 643. OECD Economics Department.

  • Atkinson, A. B. (2015). Inequality: What can be done?. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. (1990). Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 103–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baxter, M., & King, R. G. (1993). Fiscal policy in general equilibrium. The American Economic Review, 83, 315–334.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, G. S., & Tomes, N. (1979). An equilibrium theory of the distribution of income and intergenerational mobility. Journal of political Economy, 87, 1153–1189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benhabib, J., Bisin, A., & Zhu, S. (2011). The distribution of wealth and fiscal policy in economies with finitely lived agents. Econometrica, 79, 123–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black, S. E., Devereux, P. J., Lundborg, P., & Majlesi, K. (2015). Poor little rich kids? The determinants of the intergenerational transmission of wealth. Working Paper 21409. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Bom, P., & Ligthart, J. (2014). What have we learned from three decades of research on the productivity of public capital? Journal of Economic Surveys, 28(5), 889–916.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brooke, A., Kendrick, D., Meeraus, A., Raman, R., & Rosenthal, R. (2005). GAMS: A users guide. Washington: GAMS Development Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cagetti, M., & De Nardi, M. (2008). Wealth inequality: Data and models. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12, 285–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chamley, C. (1986). Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica, 54, 607–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, J. B. (1986). Does redistribution reduce inequality? Journal of Labor Economics, 4, 538–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de la Croix, D., & Michel, P. (2002). A theory of economic growth: Dynamics and policy in overlapping generations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Edenhofer, O., Mattauch, L., & Siegmeier, J. (2015). Hypergeorgism: When rent taxation is socially optimal. FinanzArchiv: Public Finance Analysis, 71, 474–505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feldstein, M. (1977). The surprising incidence of a tax on pure rent: A new answer to an old question. The Journal of Political Economy, 85, 349–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fernholz, R. T. (2017). The distributional effects of progressive capital taxes. Journal of Economic Policy Reform, 20, 99–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Homburg, S. (2015). Critical remarks on Piketty’s capital in the twenty-first Century. Applied Economics, 47, 1401–1406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Judd, K. L. (1985). Redistributive taxation in a simple perfect foresight model. Journal of Public Economics, 28, 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalkuhl, M., Fernandez Milan, B., Schwerhoff, G., Jakob, M., Hahnen, M., & Creutzig, F. (2017). Fiscal instruments for sustainable development: The case of land taxes. MCC report .

  • Kopczuk, W. (2013). Taxation of intergenerational transfers and wealth. In A. J. Auerbach, R. Chetty, M. Feldstein, & E. Saez (Eds.), Handbook of public economics (Vol. 5). Oxford: Newnes.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mountford, A. (2004). Global analysis of an overlapping generations economy with land. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 8, 582–595.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2015). In it together: Why less inequality benefits all (Figure 6.14: Wealth composition). Paris: OECD Publishing. https://doi.org/10.1787/888933208607.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2016). OECD.stat: Annual national accounts, detailed tables and simplified accounts. https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DataSetCode=SNA_TABLE9B.

  • OECD. (2017). OECD.stat: Tax database, Table II.1. Statutory corporate income tax rate. https://stats.oecd.org/index.aspx?DataSetCode=Table_II1.

  • Petrucci, A. (2006). The incidence of a tax on pure rent in a small open economy. Journal of Public Economics, 90, 921–933.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pfeffer, F. T., & Killewald, A. (2015). How rigid is the wealth structure and why? Inter-and multigenerational associations in family wealth. Research Report 15-845. Population Studies Center.

  • Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st Century. Cambridge: Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T., & Saez, E. (2012). A theory of optimal capital taxation. Working Paper 17989. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Piketty, T., & Saez, E. (2013). A theory of optimal inheritance taxation. Econometrica, 81, 1851–1886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T., & Zucman, G. (2014). Capital is Back: Wealth-Income Ratios in Rich Countries 1700–2010. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129, 1255–1310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Piketty, T., & Zucman, G. (2015). Wealth and inheritance in the long run. Handbook of income distribution (Vol. 2). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Quadrini, V., & Ríos-Rull, J. V. (1997). Understanding the US distribution of wealth. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 21, 22–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saez, E., & Zucman, G. (2016). Wealth inequality in the United States since 1913: Evidence from capitalized income tax data. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 131(2), 519–578. https://doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjw004.

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). The origin of inequality, and policies to contain it. National Tax Journal, 68, 425–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J. E. (2016). New theoretical perspectives on the distribution of income and wealth among individuals. In K. Basu, & J. E. Stiglitz (Eds.), Inequality and growth: Patterns and policy. International economic association series. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

  • Straub, L., & Werning, I. (2014). Positive long run capital taxation: Chamley-Judd revisited. Working Paper 20441. National Bureau of Economic Research.

  • Turnovsky, S. J. (1997). Fiscal policy in a growing economy with public capital. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 1, 615–639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wan, J., & Zhu, S. (2017). Bequests, estate taxes, and wealth distributions. Economic Theory. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-017-1091-7.

  • Zhu, S. (2018). A becker-tomes model with investment risk. Economic Theory. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00199-018-1103-2.

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Mireille Chiroleu-Assouline, Marc Fleurbaey, Robert C. Franks, Beatriz Gaitan, Etienne Lehmann, Linus Mattauch, Christina Roolfs, Marco Runkel, Gregor Schwerhoff, and two anonymous referees, as well as seminar participants at PIK’s RD3 PhD seminar, the PRSE seminar at Universität Potsdam, the OLG days 2016 in Luxembourg, the Journées Louis-André Gérard-Varet 2017, and PET 2017 in Paris for helpful comments and fruitful discussions. Funding by the German Research Foundation (DFG) under grant proposal LE 782/2-1 ist gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Max Franks.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (pdf 2342 KB)

Appendices

Model parameters and calibration

See Tables 4 and 5.

Table 4 Benchmark parameters that reproduce observed data on the wealth distribution in OECD countries
Table 5 Comparison of average OECD data and model output

Additional figures and data

See Figures 5, 6, 7 and 8 and Table 6.

Fig. 5
figure 5

Aggregate composition of assets (cf. Sect. 3.1) under variation of fiscal policy. Fiscal policy that stimulates (hampers) investment in capital will unambiguously increase (decrease) output. While a bequest tax only indirectly affects asset prices, taxes on capital income and land rents have a relatively strong impact on asset prices. As the relative prices of assets change, households react by changing the composition of their portfolio—a portfolio effect takes place. The tax on land rents shifts investment toward capital. The capital stock increases, but the other two inputs, labor and land, do not change, as we assume that they are in fixed supply. Hence, the land rent tax increases output. Raising a capital income tax has the opposite effect. It discourages investments in capital and, thus, leads to output reductions

Fig. 6
figure 6

The revenue raising potential of fiscal policy depends on the recycling scheme used. For the bequest tax, public revenues are higher the higher the share of transfers to the old. The capital income and the land rent tax are much less sensitive to the transfer scheme used. Note that if all tax revenues are transferred to the old generation (\(\delta =1\)), the capital income tax is only feasible up to a rate of \(70\%\). Figure 4 shows how the choice of the transfer scheme affects output

Fig. 7
figure 7

Impact of different recycling schemes on output and on the wealth distribution (cf. Fig. 4). The filled points mark the option space for the case in which public revenues are not redistributed (the capital income tax is marked by boxes, the bequest tax by triangles). Thus, transferring all tax revenues to the old generation, for example, would result in a lower steady-state level of output and higher wealth inequality, than if the tax revenues were not recycled to the modeled economy at all

Fig. 8
figure 8

Impact of varying the progressivity of the capital and the bequest tax in a model without land (cf. Sect. 3.1.3). If only the top quintile is taxed, both tax instruments have a higher potential to reduce wealth inequality compared to scenarios in which a greater fraction, or all households are taxed. A capital tax on the top quintile has a higher potential to reduce inequality and a less negative impact on output than a bequest tax on the top \(20\%\)

Table 6 Gini coefficients of the wealth distributions of those countries for which OECD (2015) reports data on their respective wealth distribution

Kaldor–Hicks criterion

Even though we find that recycling all public revenues to the young as lump-sum transfers enhances output and reduced inequality, a Pareto improvement is not possible with such a transfer scheme. However, we find that at least there are cases in which the Kaldor–Hicks criterion is fulfilled. Consider, for instance, the case in which all land rents are skimmed off and redistributed to the young (\(\tau _L = 1\), \(\delta = 0\)) shown in Figs. 9 and 10. Absent any additional transfer mechanism between winners and losers, generations belonging to the top wealth quintile \(i=5\) and possibly all households belonging to the first old generation suffer under the tax. Whether the first old generation suffers under the tax depends on the assumption made about its exogenously fixed level of consumption when young.

Now we introduce a mechanism that allows intertemporal transfers between households. Instead of the lump-sum transfers from public revenues \(g_t\), young and old households may now receive a transfer or have to pay a lump-sum tax X. Their budget equations thus are

$$\begin{aligned} c^y_{i,t}+ s_{i,t}&= w_t + b_{i,t}(1-\tau _B) + X^y_{i,t}\\ c^o_{i,t} + b_{i,t}&= (1+R_{t}(1-\tau _K))k_{i,t}^s + l_{i,t}(p_{t}+q_{t}(1-\tau _L)) + X^o_{i,t}. \end{aligned}$$

Further, we assume that funds can be shifted over time via banking and borrowing at the market interest rate R. Then, for the total volume of the transfers, it has to hold that

$$\begin{aligned} \sum _t \frac{g_t}{\Pi _{s=1}^t (1+R_s)}&\ge \frac{1}{N}\sum _{i,t} \frac{X^y_{i,t} + X^o_{i,t}}{\Pi _{s=1}^t (1+R_s)}. \end{aligned}$$

Our numerical experiments confirm that there are feasible combinations of \(\{X^y_{i,t}, X^o_{i,t}\}_{i=1,\ldots ,N,\ t=1,\ldots ,T}\) such that the winners of the 100% land rent tax can compensate the losers, i.e., that

$$\begin{aligned} u_{i,t}|_{\tau _L=1}&\ge u_{i,t}|_{\tau _L=0} \quad \forall i,t. \end{aligned}$$
Fig. 9
figure 9

When land rents are taxed at 100% and recycled as lump-sum transfers to the young, the richest households bear the burden. Their utility under taxation is less than without taxation, i.e., \(u|_{\tau _L=1} - u|_{\tau _L=0} < 0\). All other households benefit from the policy

Fig. 10
figure 10

For certain parameters, not only the rich households, but also the households belonging to the first old generation bear the burden of the tax reform

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Franks, M., Klenert, D., Schultes, A. et al. Is capital back? The role of land ownership and savings behavior. Int Tax Public Finance 25, 1252–1276 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9486-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10797-018-9486-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation