Background

HIV counseling and testing (HCT) is a cost-effective means of primary and secondary HIV prevention and a point of entry into HIV care and treatment [13]. Despite substantial public health efforts to increase HIV testing, particularly in populations with generalized HIV epidemics, HIV testing rates have plateaued. In addition, rates of repeat testing among persons with ongoing risk are low. For example, in Tanzania, where there is widespread availability of varied HIV testing options, more than half of men and women ages 15–49 have never tested, and fewer than one-third reported testing in the previous 12 months [4]. Testing rates remain low even among populations at extreme risk: a recent report by the Joint United Nations Programme on HIV/AIDS described that across 35 sub-Saharan African (SSA) countries, only 60 % of female sex workers had received an HIV test result in the past 12 months [5].

Basic economic theory states that rational, forward-looking individuals will test for HIV if the expected (cumulative) benefits are greater than the expected (cumulative) costs, including disutility and unpleasantness of the test itself, the discomfort associated with receiving potentially negative information, and the opportunity costs of testing (e.g., transportation costs, lost household or labor market productivity, etc.) [6]. This basic framework applies in resource-rich as well as resource-poor settings such as SSA, where decades of health promotion, education, and medical advances have significantly altered the landscape of HIV prevention, diagnosis and treatment [7].

HIV testing provides several potential benefits: a positive test result establishes the diagnosis of HIV infection, which is the first step for accessing effective, life-prolonging treatment for an otherwise fatal disease, whereas an HIV-negative test result removes uncertainty about the individual’s serostatus. However, there may be offsets to these benefits, such as the expected cost of having to live with the information from a positive test result (e.g., stress, social isolation, guilt) [8, 9]. Like several other diagnostic tests with similar benefits, the behavior of a person who actually tests for HIV reveals an implicit value of the test (implicit willingness to pay, WTP), which in some cases corresponds to a substantial amount of money [10, 11].

However, among populations with limited resources, particularly among most parts of SSA, the value of HIV testing to an individual may not exceed the opportunity costs (e.g., food, housing), and behavioral economics suggests that individuals may not always act rationally according to classic economic theory [12, 13]. In the only WTP study in SSA (conducted among persons who were not actually testing), half were unwilling to pay any amount of money for an HIV test [14]. Further, despite the widespread availability of free HIV testing in SSA, and significant increases in the number of clients presenting for free vs. fee-based HCT [2], substantial numbers of people do not test. These results suggest that, consistent with economic theory on other non-financial costs from testing, financial costs are not the only barrier, and that individuals’ valuations of other costs, including the time and monetary cost of accessing testing venues, fears of knowing the result, and HIV-related stigma, outweigh their valuations of the expected benefits of a test [6].

In theory, subsidies in the form of incentives can change an individual’s cost structure, in that incentives offset financial and non-financial costs and “tip the scale” toward making HIV testing and repeat testing a utility maximizing choice in a simple benefit-cost (or more sophisticated forward-looking) model [1517]. Incentives may thus be used to align individual and social preferences for specific behaviors [18]. Financial and non-financial incentives have been used to encourage the use of diverse preventive and health behaviors [1923], including to promote HIV risk reduction [2429]. However, research on the potential effectiveness of incentives to encourage HIV testing has been limited. A recent review [30] identified only 3 studies that evaluated the effect of incentives for HIV testing – one in the United States [31] and two in sub-Saharan Africa [32, 33]; incentives were associated with increased rates of clients completing HCT [31, 33] and with increased testing uptake among higher-risk populations [32].

Importantly, none of the studies assessed the potential incentive range required to increase testing, nor did these studies characterize variation in the balance between benefits and costs (both direct financial costs and non-financial barriers to testing) across individuals. In theory, an incentive only needs to be as large as the barrier [34], thus, the optimal incentive amount varies with individuals’ perceived benefits and barriers to testing. To inform policies aimed at increasing uptake of HIV testing, we analyzed variation in the net value that individuals place on barriers to testing. Specifically, we identify characteristics associated with individuals’ willingness-to-accept (WTA) an HIV test in a general population sample and in two high-risk populations using a double-bounded contingent valuation format.

Methods

Setting

The study was conducted between September 2012 and February 2013 in Moshi, Tanzania. In 2012, the town had a population of 184,292 [35], with an estimated HIV prevalence of 3.8 % [4]. Public health officials in the study area identified two populations at particularly high risk of HIV infection: female barworkers and male mountain porters. HIV prevalence among barworkers in this area has been estimated at 19 to 26 % [36, 37]. Kilimanjaro mountain porters [38] are predominantly young males, face volatile income cycles, and spend extended time away from home, thus sharing many characteristics with other high-risk groups, such as long-distance truck drivers [39, 40], fishermen [4143], miners [44, 45], and migrant farm workers [46]. HCT services in the study area are available, free of charge, at hospitals, health centers, and free-standing voluntary counseling and testing facilities. Intermittently, mobile and outreach testing options have also been available at venues such as schools, markets, or workplaces. For clients who test HIV positive, 8 HIV care and treatment centers provide access to antiretroviral therapy [47].

Sample

The characteristics and HIV testing preferences of 486 randomly selected community residents and two high-risk populations participating in the HIV Testing Preferences in Tanzania study (2012–2014) were previously described [48, 49]. In short, cluster-randomization and Expanded Programme on Immunization sampling methodology [50] were used to enroll a random sample of male and female community members from an urban setting in Northern Tanzania. Forty mitaa (singular: mtaa, an administrative area translated as ‘neighborhood’) within Moshi Municipality were randomly selected. Within each mtaa, a randomly selected GPS coordinate was used to identify a house that served as the starting point for participant enrollment. In each household, one adult age 18–49 was randomly selected for an in-person interview in the respondent’s home. Snowball sampling was subsequently used to recruit 162 female barworkers and 194 male mountain porters of the same age range in the same area. Seed participants were recruited from barworkers presenting for a health check-up at a municipal health center and from climbing companies and a porters union. Eligible persons were invited to a research office and verbally consented into the study. Participants who reported to have never been sexually active (N = 87) and those who reported to have previously tested positive for HIV (N = 34) were excluded from analyses for this manuscript.

Survey

Surveys were administered by trained interviewers in participants’ native language, Kiswahili, to assess HIV testing history and plans, preferences for various actual or hypothetical HIV testing options, as well as sociodemographic and HIV risk characteristics. Protocols for key aspects of the research implementation and low refusal rates (below 5 %) have been previously described [48].

The survey included dichotomous choice questions that assessed participants’ willingness to test for HIV in exchange for a monetary payment. Prior qualitative work [6] and pre-tests of the WTA questions suggested a mistrust of payments for HIV testing; therefore, WTA questions were prefaced with an introductory script: “You said it takes time to test, and testing may interfere with your normal activities. If someone asked you to change your plans for tomorrow in order to test for HIV, it may be appropriate if they compensate you for your time.”

Following the introductory script, participants were asked: “If you were offered 5000 Shilling to test for HIV tomorrow, would you test?” Those who responded positively were asked “If you were offered 2,000 Shilling to test for HIV tomorrow, would you test?”; those who responded negatively to the first question were asked “If you were offered 10,000 Shilling to test for HIV tomorrow, would you test?”. As a result, the dichotomous choice questions resulted in 4 possible outcomes:

  • “Yes” to the offer of 5000 and again “yes” to the offer of 2000

  • “Yes” to the offer of 5000 and “no” to the offer of 2000

  • “No” to the offer of 5000 and “yes” to the offer of 10,000

  • “No” to the offer of 5000 and again “no” to the offer of 10,000

Participants who were not willing to test for the highest bid amount were asked a follow-up question: “How much would they have to offer so that you would test for HIV tomorrow?” The incentive range was selected based on focus groups and pretests, in which the salient range from low to high acceptability among the sample was identified. At the time of the study 1 US Dollar was worth approximately 1,550 TSH. The cutoff values of 2,000 TSH, 5,000 TSH and 10,000 TSH corresponded to approximately $1.30, $3.20, and $6.40, respectively. The average gross domestic product (GDP) per capita at the time of the study was approximately $835 per year, or $2.30 per day.

Model

We assume that individuals maximize utility and face a tradeoff between testing and the level of consumption of all other goods, subject to resource constraints in terms of income (unobserved on this survey) and time (an identical endowment for all individuals). The societal perspective, promoted by public health officials and clinicians, is that the value of information is unambiguously positive because it may change health-related behaviors, including linkage to care for those found to be HIV positive, and improve others’ welfare through reduced HIV transmission risk. From the individual’s perspective, however, the private value of information is ambiguous, depending on preferences, risks, and individual characteristics. Clearly, revealed preferences in the form of low observed testing rates indicate that for many persons testing is not utility-maximizing in equilibrium. The time and travel costs of seeking testing are negative even if there is generally no financial cost to testing in our study area. An individual demands HIV testing—or not testing—by considering the benefits and costs of the test. Potential compensation for HIV testing (WTA) may alter the demand for testing, and private benefits and costs are captured through several covariates in the survey.

The value of information is a function of an individual’s probability of being infected with HIV: a higher probability of infection corresponds to a greater likelihood that the test results in access to effective, life-prolonging medications. The risk of HIV infection is captured in our data by the participant’s age in years (a), the number of lifetime sexual partners (s: 12, 3–4, or 5+), the presence of HIV-related symptoms (h: any fever, cough, coughing up blood, sweating at night, diarrhea, genital ulcers, or rash) in the past 3 months, and reports of commercial sex (c), defined as having ever given or received gifts or money for sex.

The value of information also depends on the perceived accuracy of the HIV test (pa), which was assessed by the question: “In your opinion, how accurate are HIV tests?”, with answer options: “inaccurate”, “mostly accurate”, and “completely accurate”. An indicator variable for “completely accurate” was included in the final model. Preferences for testing and the value of information may depend on experience with HIV testing, therefore an indicator variable for those who previously tested for HIV (pt) was also included as a covariate.

HIV testing is freely available in diverse settings in the study area; therefore the cost of testing primarily consists of the opportunity cost of time. To approximate opportunity cost and time preferences, we included participants’ education (e: any secondary education vs. primary education or less) as a covariate. Education may also be considered a marker of health literacy [51]. The occupation-based selection of the two high-risk groups precluded the use of an occupation- or employment-based measure of opportunity cost.

Marital status (m) and a sexual partner’s testing history (st) may affect both the benefits and costs of testing and were included as indicators of both risk and barriers. Married individuals may be less likely to have multiple concurrent sexual partners (i.e., lower risk); they may be more concerned about the implications of a positive test result (i.e., greater barriers); and they may feel greater responsibility to others (i.e., greater benefit). A partner having tested for HIV may reduce barriers to testing, particularly for females, but may also change an individual’s perception of risk, as some consider their spouse’s HIV test a proxy test [52].

Combining these factors, the demand for testing is a function of the “price” of testing (q), the price of all other goods (p), a resource endowment (y), and random factors (ε) representing unmeasured preferences or measurement error. The individual utility function is expressed as V(p, q, y, ε). The price of testing is a function of the characteristics discussed above, q = f(a, e, h, s, c, pt, m, st, pa). A priori, the demand for testing, q 0, represents a utility-maximizing choice weighing the consumption of testing (a function of perceived benefits and costs of testing) against the consumption of other goods. On our survey, the WTA questions alter the hypothetical utility function, and demand for testing may change from q 0 to q 1. Testing will decrease private utility for all who did not previously seek it, or V(p, q 1 , y, ε) < V(p, q 0 , y, ε), unless offset through compensation, WTA, which enables the purchase of other goods:

$$ V\left(p,\kern0.5em {q}^0,\kern0.5em y,\kern0.5em \varepsilon \right)=V\left(p,\kern0.5em {q}^1,\kern0.5em y+WTA,\kern0.5em \varepsilon \right) $$

The prices of other goods (p) are constant in both scenarios and cancel out of the econometric model, so they are not included in the model or available on our survey. Income (y) is also not available, although it is captured indirectly through education.

For cultural [53, 54] and epidemiological [55, 56] reasons, HIV risk and willingness to accept an HIV test were expected to differ by gender; therefore gender-specific models were estimated. Among females and among men, generalized Hausman tests [57] indicated that parameter estimates did not differ significantly between randomly selected community members and the respective high-risk population (female barworkers: chi-square (10df) =9.41; p = 0.4935; male mountain porters: chi-square (10df) =5.02; p = 0.8895), thus the community sample and high-risk groups were pooled within each gender.

Estimation

Because amounts were fixed across respondents, the probabilities of observing the four possible response patterns to the two questions are described as follows:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{\pi}^{y,y}= \Pr \left( \min \kern0.5em WTA\kern0.5em \le \kern0.5em \mathrm{T}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{H}\kern0.5em 2000\right)\hfill \\ {}{\pi}^{y,n}= \Pr \left(\mathrm{T}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{H}\kern0.5em 2000< \min \kern0.5em WTA\kern0.5em \le \kern0.5em \mathrm{T}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{H}\kern0.5em 5000\right)\hfill \\ {}{\pi}^{n,y}= \Pr \left(\mathrm{T}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{H}\kern0.5em 5000< \min \kern0.5em WTA\kern0.5em \le \kern0.5em \mathrm{T}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{H}\kern0.5em 10000\right)\hfill \\ {}{\pi}^{n,n}= \Pr \left( \min \kern0.5em WTA>\mathrm{T}\mathrm{S}\mathrm{H}\kern0.5em 10000\right)\hfill \end{array} $$

Or more generally, let these probabilities be indicated by πc1, c2, where c t is the choice (y = yes, n = no) to bid t (1 = first, 2 = second). To estimate WTA, we assume a normally distributed error term that is uncorrelated across individuals. The distribution of observed responses is given by the following function:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{\displaystyle \sum_{i=l}^N\left[{d}_i^{y,y} \ln \left(\Phi \left({z}_i^{\hbox{'}}\frac{\beta }{\sigma }-\frac{-2000}{\sigma}\right)\right)+{d}_i^{y,n} \ln \left(\Phi \left({z}_i^{\hbox{'}}\frac{\beta }{\sigma }-\frac{-5000}{\sigma}\right)-\Phi \left({z}_i^{\hbox{'}}\frac{\beta }{\sigma }-\frac{-2000}{\sigma}\right)\right)\right.}\hfill \\ {}+{d}_i^{n,y} \ln \left(\Phi \left({z}_i^{\hbox{'}}\frac{\beta }{\sigma }-\frac{-10000}{\sigma}\right)-\Phi \left({z}_i^{\hbox{'}}\frac{\beta }{\sigma }-\frac{5000}{\sigma}\right)\right)+{d}_i^{n,n} \ln \left(1\right.\hfill \\ {}\left.\left.-\Phi \left({z}_i^{\hbox{'}}\frac{\beta }{\sigma }-\frac{-10000}{\sigma}\right)\right)\right]\hfill \end{array} $$

where the individuals’ binary choices are represented by the mutually exclusive indicator variables d y,y, d y,n, d n,y, d n,n as in [58]. Parameters were estimated using maximum likelihood with the Stata doubleb routine [58] for double-bounded dichotomous choice contingent valuation models [59]. Because study questions here elicited willingness-to-accept rather than willingness-to-pay, the estimated coefficients were multiplied with −1. Models were estimated in Stata v.13.1.

Ethics statement

Study activities were approved by the Institutional Review Boards of Duke University and Kilimanjaro Christian Medical University College, and Tanzania’s National Institute for Medical Research. Participants provided written informed consent and received an incentive of 3,000 Tanzania Shilling (TSH) for participation in the study.

Results

Sample characteristics

Sample characteristics, by gender and risk group, are shown in Table 1. On average, participants were just under 30 years old, with one-third of women and half of men reporting any secondary education. Half of women and 40 % of men reported symptoms of HIV in the past 3 months. High risk of HIV infection is indicated by one-quarter of women and one-half of men reporting 5 or more lifetime sexual partners; commercial sex was reported by 61 % of female participants and 73 % of male participants. Ninety percent of women and two-thirds of men had previously tested for HIV, with half of respondents reporting that their partner had tested. Approximately one-third of participants perceived HIV tests to be less than “completely accurate.”

Table 1 Basic demographic and risk characteristics of participants (N=721)

There were significant differences in participant characteristics by gender, and between randomly selected community members and high-risk groups (Table 1). Compared with females, males reported higher education (p<0.001), fewer potential HIV-related symptoms (p<0.01), and more lifetime sexual partners (p<0.001); they were less likely to have previously tested for HIV (p<0.001) and less likely to be married (p<0.001).

Compared with randomly selected female community members, female barworkers were younger (p=0.005), reported more HIV-related symptoms (p<0.001), more lifetime sexual partners (p<0.001), higher rates of commercial sex (p<0.001), and were less likely to be married (p<0.001) or have a partner who tested for HIV (p=0.003). Porters were older (p<0.001) and less educated (p<0.001), reported more lifetime sexual partners (p<0.001) and higher rates of commercial sex (p=0.001), and were less likely to be married (p<0.001), compared with randomly selected male community members.

Willingness to accept an HIV test

The distribution of responses to the WTA questions is shown in Fig. 1. Of 721 participants, 196 (27 %) stated that they would be willing to test for TSH 2,000 (or less), whereas 98 (13.6 %) said that they would require more than TSH 10,000. The latter group, in an open-ended follow-up question, was asked about the amount at which they would test; the highest amount was TSH 150,000 (~$100). More than half of participants (419 of 721 participants; 58.1 %) indicated that they would test for HIV if offered TSH 5,000; the number increased to 623 (86.4 %) in response to an offer of TSH 10,000.

Fig. 1
figure 1

Distribution of WTA responses (2012/13 Tanzania Shillings; N=721). 6 of 98 respondents (0.8 % of the total sample) did not provide a numeric answer to the follow-up question of how much they would have to be offered to test for HIV tomorrow. Their binary choices (No; No) are included in the WTA analyses. At the time of the study 1 US Dollar was worth approximately 1,550 TSH. The cutoff values of 2,000 TSH, 5,000 TSH and 10,000 TSH correspond to approximately $1.30, $3.20, and $6.40, respectively

The average WTA estimate was TSH 4,564 (US$ 2.94; 95 % Confidence Interval; CI: TSH 4201 to 4927; Fig. 2). Randomly selected male community members had the highest WTA values (US$ 3.54; TSH 5,484; 95 % CI: TSH 4,351 to 6,618), whereas female community members had the lowest values (US$ 2.34; TSH 3,622; 95 % CI: TSH 2,956 to 4,287).

Fig. 2
figure 2

Mean WTA estimates from univariate double-bounded choice models, by gender and HIV risk group (2012/13; Tanzania Shillings)

The estimated WTA for an HIV test varied significantly by the expected benefit and cost measures included in our model, namely respondents’ risk characteristics and opportunity cost (Table 2). Among females, secondary education (p<0.01) and a previous HIV test (p<0.05) were associated with higher WTA values, whereas females who reported to have engaged in commercial sex and those whose partner had tested for HIV indicated lower WTA values (both p<0.05). Among males, HIV-related symptoms in the past 3 months were associated with a lower WTA (p<0.01). For both genders, the most significant association was observed with respondents’ perception of the accuracy of the HIV test, with those who believed that HIV tests are completely accurate indicating that they would test for approximately one third less (p<0.01).

Table 2 Marginal WTA estimates from gender-specific multivariate double-bounded choice models (2012/13 Tanzania Shillings)

Discussion

To our knowledge, this is the first study to use stated preference surveys to probe the range of economic incentives required for a pay-for-testing strategy in low-resource settings. Our study included both representative community samples and high-risk populations from each gender. We demonstrate that (1) relatively modest economic incentives are potentially useful in increasing HIV testing rates in this population, and (2) willingness to accept differs significantly by gender, with indicators of HIV risk, and with participants’ perceptions of the accuracy of the HIV test.

The results have important policy implications. First, financial incentives for HIV testing may be highly cost effective. HIV prevalence estimates of 3.8 % [60] and Census data [35] suggest that, of the 94,530 Moshi residents aged 18–49, approximately 3,600 live with HIV. Assuming, optimistically, that half of infected adults are already aware of their HIV infection [61], universal testing could plausibly identify 1,800 undiagnosed HIV cases in Moshi alone. Further, if national incidence estimates (0.32 % [62]) were rescaled to account for lower-than-average HIV prevalence in the study area (national HIV prevalence is estimated at 5.1 % [60]), universal annual repeat testing would be expected to identify about 200 new HIV infections each year. The mean WTA estimates identified in this study suggest that in this population universal testing could potentially be achieved with incentive costs of about $280,000, amounting to $150 per diagnosis of prevalent HIV infection, and $1400 per diagnosis of annual incident infections. With an estimated 2.25 discounted quality-adjusted life years (QALY) gained for each newly infected person identified [63], the incentive costs per QALY range from under $70 for prevalent HIV infections to $620 for incident infections. Additional QALYs would be gained from reduced numbers of secondary infections [63]. These estimates compare favorably to Tanzania’s 2012 per capita GDP of $835 [64] and to prior estimates of the cost effectiveness of regular HIV re-testing among high prevalence populations in low-resource settings [63].

Second, while many diverse characteristics influence an individual’s cost structure and thus their individual WTA, systematic variation in WTA by gender, risk and other characteristics plausibly reflects systematic variation in individuals’ valuations of benefits and barriers, and can thus inform the design of HIV testing interventions that target specific risk groups or specific barriers to testing. Larger WTA estimates, analogous to higher incentive amounts required to entice individuals to test, were observed for females who had completed secondary education. This observation is consistent with different time preferences as well as greater income potential and thus higher opportunity cost for secondary school graduates. An offer of HIV testing that provides expanded testing hours, reduced waiting time, or allows for appointments for testing, may appeal to those with the greatest opportunity cost.

Among females, a prior HIV test was also associated with higher incentive amounts. This observation is consistent with lower expected benefits from a second HIV test, as the likelihood of incident HIV infection since the last test is generally lower than the cumulative, lifetime risk of infection at the first test. A similar effect among males was not statistically significant at conventional levels, plausibly due to the smaller sample size. Policy messages aimed at increasing rates of repeat testing may be more effective if recommended repeat testing intervals take into consideration variation in individuals’ ongoing risk of HIV infection [63].

Indicators of HIV risk were associated with lower WTA estimates, an observation consistent with greater expected benefits from an HIV test. Females who had ever engaged in commercial sex required a smaller incentive amount than those who had not. The most plausible reason for this is that commercial sex workers are aware of their increased risk of HIV infection and perceive greater utility of testing. Alternatively, it is possible that commercial sex workers are more open to accepting incentives in exchange for certain behaviors (i.e. sex and HIV testing). Similarly, among males, lower required incentive amounts were observed among those with recent symptoms potentially related to HIV. Others have described high rates of late, (i.e. symptomatic) presentation of HIV disease among males seeking HIV testing [65]. Efforts should be expanded to incentivize males to test for HIV prior to the onset of symptoms.

Finally, the strong association of WTA with participants’ perception of test accuracy points to the potential value of information campaigns to correct misperceptions about the accuracy of HIV testing [66]. Perceived unreliability of test results and distrust of HIV testing technologies has been previously shown to discourage uptake of HIV testing [6769]; our finding is consistent with an increased incentive amount required to encourage those to test who are less confident in the accuracy of the test results.

As the parameters for incentivized HIV testing are explored, we acknowledge several important ethical considerations that derive from conditional cash transfers for health interventions. These have been explored in more detail by others [17, 7074]. From a policy perspective, some argue that in highly resource-constrained settings limited health care funds should be allocated to overcome supply-side obstacles, such as expanding health system capacity, before investing in cash incentives [75]. Others point to the potential for unintended consequences of cash transfer programs. Stecklov et al., for example, described an increase in fertility rates in a Honduran program that provided cash transfers targeting health, nutritional, and educational outcomes for children [76]; and evidence from Malawi suggests that financial incentives may have the perverse effect of increasing HIV risk behaviors as a result of additional disposable income [77]. The equitability of cash-incentivized health-interventions across economic strata and by gender is another potential concern. Moreover, establishing financial incentives for certain health behaviors, such as HIV testing, could set expectations that other health behaviors (e.g. attending antenatal clinic visits) should also be incentivized, which might indirectly result in decreased participation. Finally, concerns about the real-world implementation and long-term sustainability of incentives must be considered: There is evidence that extrinsic motivators, such as financial incentives, may crowd out intrinsic motivators [78], potentially reducing testing rates after incentives are no longer provided. These ethical considerations at the population level merit careful deliberation. On the individual level, the greatest ethical concern is the potential for coercion – namely undermining the recipient’s autonomy and the integrity of her/his own decision making process, with undue inducement [74]. If an individual is already predisposed to test for HIV and the incentive represents a gentle ‘nudge’ from inaction to action along a pathway in keeping with his/her considered values, we see no concerns. On the other hand, if the financial reward is so great relative to potential risks (e.g. potential spousal abuse for testing), then the incentive may constitute wrongful interference and undue coercion. Extensive formative research, careful piloting and ongoing modifications of cash incentives are necessary to guard against perverse incentives, unintended consequences, and the potential for coercion.

Limitations

This study is subject to several limitations. First, starting bids were not randomized due to the survey’s administration as a paper survey. Different WTA estimates may have been obtained if starting values had been randomized [79, 80] or if the incentive structure had involved either losses or lotteries [81]. Second, the contingent valuation questions were part of a broader study, and we did not power the data collection specifically for the analyses described in this paper. Small sample sizes, particularly for males in the community sample, may have contributed to the lack of statistical significance of parameters describing opportunity cost (any secondary education) among males, and risk (number of sexual partners) in both genders. Third, the hypothetical nature of stated preference contingent valuation data may not reflect ‘real-world’ behaviors: WTA estimates based on stated preferences may differ from estimates that would be obtained on the basis of revealed preferences data [82, 83], and barriers specific to HIV, such as fear and stigma, may limit the acceptability of financial incentives in the context of HIV testing [6]. Fourth, further research is needed to evaluate the extent to which specific WTA estimates are transferable to other risk groups within and beyond the study area.

Conclusion

This study used stated preference survey methods to probe the value of economic incentives required for a pay-for-testing strategy in a low-resource setting. The results support the value of information campaigns to correct misperceptions about the accuracy of HIV testing, and that relatively modest amounts of money may be sufficient to incentivize at-risk populations to test for HIV. For translation of the results to policy, additional implementation research will be required.