Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

The agro-food industry, public health, and environmental protection: investigating the Porter hypothesis in food regulation

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Review of Agricultural, Food and Environmental Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Sustainable food concerns have pushed public authorities to act by means of regulations, standards and other devices, and businesses to innovate in their products and production processes. We argue that the Porter hypothesis—which asserts that properly designed and implemented environmental regulation might be good for society as well as the targeted firms—might well be verified in this context. After reviewing and illustrating the working principles and main criticisms of this hypothesis, we provide a more in-depth discussion of nutritional issues. While the literature generally points to organizational imperfections and market failures to validate the Porter hypothesis, we submit and model another rationale for the agro-food industry, a rationale that is based on consumer behavior.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. According to Porter and van der Linde (1995, p. 98 and 105): “Pollution is a manifestation of economic waste and involves unnecessary or incomplete utilization of resources. (…) Reducing pollution is often coincident with improving productivity with which resources are used. (…) Properly designed environmental regulation can trigger innovation that may partially or more than fully offset the costs of complying with them.”

  2. In this connection, see the debate surrounding agent behavior vis-à-vis risk initiated by Maurice Allais’ (1953) seminal article.

  3. This was put forward early on by the philosopher Alfred North Whitehead, in the following provocative statement: “It is a profoundly erroneous truism, repeated by all copy-books and by eminent people making speeches, that we should cultivate the habit of thinking of what we are doing. The precise opposite is the case. Civilization advances by extending the number of operations which we can perform without thinking about them.”

  4. http://affichage-environnemental.afnor.org/

  5. To our knowledge, very few studies in experimental economics have examined this assertion. A notable exception is Bougherara and Combris (2009).

  6. The first difficulty relates to the nature of the criteria used for attesting environmental performance. How does one assess the carbon footprint or the impact on the water table and biodiversity (which are particularly difficult to measure) throughout the value chain? Next, improving product performance along these criteria often means amending the firm’s activities significantly.

  7. This was the case in the 2011 Spanish cucumber crisis. This highly-publicized condemnation by German authorities of cucumber imports from Spain—a gesture that soon proved to be mistaken, as the problem stemmed from spouted seeds contaminated by verotoxin-producing E. coli strains—led to the collapse of vegetable consumption throughout Europe (Jourdan and Hobbis 2013).

  8. D’Aspremont and Jacquemin (1988) show that, in this case, firms would face a prisoner’s dilemma, which explain the paucity of investment in R&D; regulations that protect innovations or that require the adoption of a new technology can then benefit all businesses (see also Ambec and Barla 2007).

  9. For more details, see www.oqali.fr

  10. Some articles examine the possibility that regulations could put certain companies in a market leadership position by inducing R&D. Simpson and Bradford (1996) make this case in the context of international competition.

  11. In these conditions, the higher the quality of the product offered by firm i is, the more consumers will tend to be “loyal” to the preferred firm. It should be noted that, in contrast to André et al. (op. cit.), we retain an additive indirect utility between brand effects and taste quality effects.

  12. Although not explicitly taken into account in the model, a complete illustration of the Porter hypothesis assumes, to be sure, that the social cost implicit in the conventional strategy (cost for the health of the population) is sufficiently high to justify the search for the results of innovations.

  13. The stage 2 resolution corresponds to resolution of the price competition in the production differentiation model considered above. However, our decision to remain with a linear transportation cost for consumers makes it impossible to completely resolve this game by pure strategy equilibria (absence of an equilibrium of this kind for certain parameter values). This hypothesis has, however, the advantage of a simple treatment of the covered-uncovered market alternatives that are of interest to us here.

References

  • Académie des technologies (2012) Alimentation, innovation et consommateurs, Commission des biotechnologies, Editions Le Manuscrit, Paris, France, 92 p

  • Aghion P, Dewatripont M, Rey P (1997) Corporate governance, competition policy and industrial policy. Eur Econ Rev 41(3–5):797–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allais M (1953) Le comportement de l’homme rationnel devant le risque; critiques des postulats et axiomes de l’école Américaine. Econometrica 21(4):503–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ambec S, Barla P (2007) Survol des fondements théoriques de l’hypothèse de Porter. L’Actualité Economique 83(3):399–413

    Google Scholar 

  • Ambec S, Cohen M, Elgie S, Lanoie P (2013) The Porter hypothesis at 20: can environmental regulation enhance innovation and competitiveness? Rev Environ Econ Policy 7(1):2–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • André F, González P, Porteiro N (2009) Strategic quality competition and the Porter hypothesis. J Environ Econ Manag 57(2):182–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariely D (2008) Predictably irrational: the hidden forces that shape our decisions. Harper Collins, New York, 384 p

    Google Scholar 

  • Asfaw S, Mithöfer D, Waibel H (2010) Agrifood supply chain, private-sector standards, and farmers’ health: evidence from Kenya. Agric Econ 41(3–4):251–263

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard P, Huiban J-P, Musolesi A, Sevestre P (2013) Where there is a will, there is a way? Assessing the impact of obstacles to innovation. Ind Corp Chang 22(3):679–710

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton P, Dewatripont M (1994) The firm as a communication network. Q J Econ 109(4):809–839

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bougherara D, Combris P (2009) Eco-labelled food products: what are consumers paying for? Eur Rev Agric Econ 36(3):321–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brambila-Macias J, Shankar B, Capacci S, Mazzocchi M, Perez-Cueto F, Verbeke W, Traill B (2011) Policy interventions to promote healthy eating: a review of what works, what does not, and what is promising. Food Nutr Bull 32(4):365–375

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ceci-Renaud N. and Thao Khamsing W (2012) Les consommateurs face à l’affichage environnemental, Collection «Études et documents» du Service de l’Économie, de l’Évaluation et de l’Intégration du Développement Durable (SEEIDD) du Commissariat Général au Développement Durable (CGDD), Paris, France, n°74, 38 p

  • Constantatos C, Herrmann M (2011) Market inertia and the introduction of green products: can strategic effects justify the Porter hypothesis? Environ Resour Econ 50(2):267–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cyert R, March J (1992) A behavioral theory of the firm, 2nd edn. Wiley-Blackwell, Maiden, U.S.A., 268 p

    Google Scholar 

  • d’Aspremont L-A, Jacquemin A (1988) Cooperative and noncooperative R&D in duopoly with spillovers. Am Econ Rev 78(5):1133–1137

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabel HL and Sinclair-Desgagné B (1998) The firm, its routines, and the environment, in: The International Yearbook of Environmental and Resource Economics 1998/1999: A Survey of Current Issues, H. Folmer and T. Tietenberg (eds), Edward Elgar, 89–118.

  • Giraud-Héraud E, Hammoudi A, Hoffmann R, Soler L-G (2012) Joint private safety standards and vertical relationships in food retailing. J Econ Manag Strat 21(1):179–212

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greaker M (2006) Spillovers in the development of new pollution abatement technology: a new look at the Porter-hypothesis. J Environ Econ Manag 52(1):411–420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanemann M (2009) The role of emissions trading in domestic climate change policy. Energy J 30(2):79–114

    Google Scholar 

  • He FJ, MacGregor G (2009) A comprehensive review on salt and health and current experience of worldwide salt reduction programmes. J Hum Hypertens 23(6):363–384

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henson S, Masakure O, Cranfield J (2011) Do fresh produce exporters in Sub-Saharan Africa benefit from GlobalGap certification? World Dev 39(3):375–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hercberg S, Chat-Yung S, Chaulia M (2008) The French national and health program: 2001-2006-2010. Int J Public Health 53(2):68–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hotelling H (1929) Stability in competition. Econ J 39:41–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huiban J.P. and Musolesi A. (2012) Augmenting the production function with knowledge capital to test the Porter hypothesis: the case of French food industries, Working Paper ALISS 2012–08, http://www.paris.inra.fr/aliss, 25 p.

  • Jaffe AB, Palmer K (1997) Environmental regulation and innovation: a panel data study. Rev Econ Stat 79(4):610–619

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jourdan C, Hobbis S (2013) Tensions internationales autour d’un concombre tueur : confiance et glocalisation alimentaire. Anthropol Soc 37(2):173–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lanoie P, Laurent-Lucchetti J, Johnstone N, Ambec S (2011) Environmental policy, innovation and performance: new insights on the Porter hypothesis. J Econ Manag Strateg 20(3):803–842

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maertens M, Swinnen JFM (2009) Trade, standards and poverty: evidence from Senegal. World Dev 37(1):161–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MEDDE (2013) Ministère de l’Ecologie et du Développement Durable et de l’Energie, Le bilan au Parlement de l’expérimentation nationale de l’affichage environnemental, septembre 2013, www.developpement-durable.gouv.fr/Bilan-au-Parlement-de-l.html.

  • Minten B, Randrianarison L, Swinnen JFM (2009) Global retail chains and poor farmers: evidence from Madagascar. World Dev 37(11):1728–1741

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mohr RD (2002) Technical change, external economies, and the Porter hypothesis. J Environ Econ Manag 43(1):158–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moorman C, Ferraro R, Huber J (2012) Unintended nutrition consequences: firm responses to the nutrition labeling and education act. Mark Sci 31(5):717–737

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • OQALI (2012) (Observatoire de la qualité de l’alimentation) Évaluation de l’impact potentiel des chartes d’engagements volontaires de progrès nutritionnel sur les apports en nutriments de la population française, Rapport « études transversales”, https://www.oqali.fr/Publications-Oqali/Etudes-transversales, 147 p

  • OQALI (2013) (Observatoire de la qualité de l’alimentation) Etude des relations entre composition nutritionnelle, étiquetage et prix, Rapport « études transversales”, https://www.oqali.fr/Publications-Oqali/Etudes-transversales, 52 p

  • Ouma S (2010) Global standards, local realities: private agrifood governance and the restructuring of the Kenyan horticulture industry. Econ Geogr 86(2):197–222

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palmer K, Oates W, Portney P (1995) Tightening environmental standards: the benefit-cost or the no-cost paradigm. J Econ Perspect 9(4):119–131

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Popp D (2006) International innovation and diffusion of air pollution control technologies: the effects of NOx and SO2 regulation in the US, Japan, and Germany. J Environ Econ Manag 51(1):46–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Porter M (1991) America’s green strategy, Scientific American 264(4)

  • Porter M, van der Linde C (1995) Towards a new conception of environment-competitiveness relationship. J Econ Perspect 9(4):97–118

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Radner R (1992) Hierarchy: the economics of managing. J Econ Lit 30(3):1382–1415

    Google Scholar 

  • Réquillart V, Soler LG (2014) Is the reduction of chronic diseases related to food consumption in the hands of the food industry? Eur Rev Agric Econ 41(3):375–403. doi:10.1093/erae/jbu010

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sah R, Stiglitz J (1986) The architecture of economic systems: hierarchies and polyarchies. Am Econ Rev 76(4):716–727

    Google Scholar 

  • Salop S (1979) Monopolistic competition with outside goods. Bell J Econ 10(1):141–156

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saulais L, Ruffieux B (2012) A field experiment to design healthier foods: consumer valuation of butter production processes. Food Qual Prefer 26(2):178–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sebillotte C (2013) Efficiency of public-private co-regulation in the food sector: the French voluntary agreements for nutritional improvements, Aliss Working Paper 2013–03, http://www.paris.inra.fr/aliss, 34 p

  • Simpson RD, Bradford RL (1996) Taxing variable cost: environmental regulation as industrial policy. J Environ Econ Manag 30(3):282–300

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Subervie J, Vagneron I (2013) A drop of water in the Indian Ocean? The impact of GlobalGap certification on lychee farmers in Madagascar. World Dev 50:57–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Traill B (2012) Economic perspectives on nutrition policy evaluation. J Agric Economics 63(3):505–527

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Traill B, Bech-Larsen T, Gennaro L, Koziol-Kozakowska A, Kuhn S, Wills J (2012) Reformulation for healthier food: a qualitative assessment of alternative approaches, 2012 AAEA/EAAE Food Environment Symposium, May 30–31. Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, Boston, U.S.A., 33 p

    Google Scholar 

  • Traill WB, Mazzocchi M, Niedźwiedzka B, Shankar B, Wills J (2013) The EATWELL project: recommendations for healthy eating policy interventions across Europe. Nutr Bull 38(3):352–357

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vadiveloo M, Morwitz V, Chandon P (2013) The interplay of health claims and taste importance on food consumption and self-reported satiety. Appetite 71:349–356

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vergez A. (2012) Vers un affichage environnemental sur les produits alimentaires, n°64, janvier 2012, Commissariat Général au développement durable, URL : http://www.developpement-durable.gouv.fr/IMG/pdf/ED64.pdf, 26 p

  • Wansink B, van Ittersum K, Painter J (2004) How diet and health labels influence taste and satiation. Journal of food science 69(9):340–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

The initial idea of this paper was widely discussed with Jean-Pierre HUIBAN. This research is part of research program conducted in the following projects: OCAD, funded by the French ANR (ANR 11 ALID 002 03); and ERA-Net SUSFOOD SUSDIET (grant agreement no. 291766), with the Daniel and Nina Carasso Foundation).

An earlier version of this paper was presented at the INRA conference in the honor of Jean-Pierre Huiban that took place on January 27th 2015 in Paris. We wish to thank the participants at this conference, as well as three anonymous referees and the editor, Xavier Irz, for valuable comments and suggestions.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric Giraud-Héraud.

Appendices

Appendix

Covered market condition

U 1 > 0 if and only if \( \mathsf{y}<{\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{1}}}{\alpha } \) and U 2 > 0 if and only if \( \mathsf{y}>{\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{2}}}{\alpha } \)

Moreover, U 1 > U 2 if and only if \( \mathsf{y}<\widehat{\mathsf{y}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{1}},{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{2}}\right)=\frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{2}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha } \)

The market is covered if and only if \( {\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{2}}\le \widehat{\mathsf{y}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{1}},{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{2}}\right)\le {\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{1}} \), that is to say:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\le \alpha +{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{1}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{2}} $$
(C)

The market is covered whenever the offered qualities are sufficiently high relative to product selling price.

Case in which both firms adopt the Conv strategy

In this case, consumers unanimously feel that the quality offered by each firm is at level K H .

Equilibrium with a covered market

The demand for firm 1’s products is such that \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\widehat{\mathit{\mathsf{y}}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}},{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right) \) and the profit \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)\ \widehat{\mathsf{y}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}},{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right) \).

The condition for first-order maximization of firm 1’s profits gives \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \right) \).

By symmetry, we obtain the equivalent condition for firm 2, which gives the equilibrium price \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \) and the market shares \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}} \). The covered market condition is thus equivalent to:

$$ {\mathrm{k}}_{\mathit{\mathsf{H}}}\ge \overline{\mathsf{c}}+\frac{\alpha }{\mathsf{2}} $$
(C1)

E1 equilibrium: firms choose a conventional strategy, and under condition (C1), there is a single equilibrium with a covered market such that \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \), \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}} \) and \( {\varPi}_1^{*}={\varPi}_2^{*}=\frac{\alpha }{2} \). In this equilibrium, profits do not depend on variable production costs.

Equilibrium with an uncovered market

The demand for firm 1’s products can now be written as \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}} = {\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathit{\mathsf{H}}}}{\alpha } \)The condition for first-order maximization of profit gives \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathit{\mathsf{H}}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \right) \).

By symmetry, we obtain the equivalent condition for firm 2. The uncovered market condition is thus equivalent to:

$$ {\mathrm{k}}_{\mathit{\mathsf{H}}}<\overline{\mathsf{c}}-\alpha $$
(C2)

Both firms obtain a strictly positive profit in equilibrium if and only if:

$$ {\mathrm{k}}_{\mathit{\mathsf{H}}}>\overline{\mathsf{c}}-\alpha $$
(C2’)

We can note that the conditions (C1) and (C2) are never compatible with one another.

E2 equilibrium: firms choose a conventional strategy, and under conditions (C1) and (C2)’, there is a single equilibrium with an uncovered market in which both firms make a strictly positive profit. This equilibrium is such that \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathit{\mathsf{H}}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \right) \), \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\alpha +{k}_H-\overline{\mathsf{c}}}{2\alpha } \) and \( {\varPi}_1^{*}={\varPi}_2^{*}=\frac{1}{4\alpha }{\left(\alpha +{k}_H-\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)}^2 \).

Case in which both firms adopt an Innov strategy

In this case, only informed consumers feel that the quality offered by both firms is at level K H . A proportion (1-l) of consumers feels that the quality is at level K L .

Equilibrium with a covered market

The demand for firm 1’s products is written as:

$$ {\mathsf{D}}_1=\mathsf{I}\;\widehat{\mathsf{y}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}},{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right) + \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\Big)\kern1em \widehat{\mathsf{y}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}},{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right) = \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha } $$

The equilibrium can thus be deduced form the first situation in the E1 equilibrium, but this time with a marginal production cost at level \( \underline {\mathrm{c}} \). The equilibrium prices are such that \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\underline {\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \) and the market shares \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}} \). The covered market conditions for both consumer types are written as:

$$ \left\{\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\le \alpha +\mathsf{2}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\le \alpha +\mathsf{2}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\hfill \end{array}\right.\iff \kern0.48em {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\ge \underline {\mathrm{c}}+\frac{\alpha }{\mathsf{2}} $$
(C3)

E3 equilibrium: firms choose a conventional strategy, and under condition (C3), there is a single equilibrium with a covered market, such that: \( {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\alpha \), \( {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}} \) and \( {\varPi}_1^{*}={\varPi}_2^{*}=\frac{\alpha }{2}-F \). In this equilibrium, profits do not depend on variable production costs.

Equilibrium with an uncovered market for uninformed consumers

We now assume that for the proportion I of consumers, the market is covered whereas it is uncovered for the proportion (1-I) of consumers. In this hypothesis, the demand for firm 1’s products is written as:

$$ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{I}\left(\frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\right)+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}}{\alpha}\right) $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \mathsf{F} \) gives:

$$ \mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left[\underline {\mathsf{c}}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\left(\alpha +{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right] $$

We thus obtain the symmetrical equilibrium:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}}\left[\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\underline {\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \right)+\mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right] $$

The covered market condition for informed consumers gives:

$$ \mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} \mathsf{4}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\ge \mathsf{2}\underline {\mathrm{c}}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)+\alpha \mathsf{I} $$
(C4)

The uncovered market condition for uninformed consumers gives:

$$ {\mathsf{k}}_L<\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\frac{\alpha \mathsf{I}}{\mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)} $$
(C4)’)

E4 equilibrium: firms choose an innovation strategy, and under conditions (C4) and (c4)’, there is a single equilibrium with an uncovered market, such that:

$$ \begin{array}{l}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}}\left[\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\underline {\mathsf{c}}+\alpha \right)+\mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right]\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}{\mathsf{2}\alpha \left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right)}\left[\alpha \left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)+\mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}\right)\right]\hfill \\ {}{\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}={\varPi}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}{\mathsf{2}\alpha }{\left[\frac{\alpha \left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\hbox{-} \mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}\right)}{\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right)}\right]}^{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} \mathsf{F}\hfill \end{array} $$

In this equilibrium, the market is covered for informed consumers and uncovered for uninformed consumers.

Case in which only firm 2 adopts an Innov strategy

In this case, all consumers feel that the quality offered by firm 1 is at level k H whereas only informed consumers feel that the quality offered by firm 2 is at level k H . A proportion (1-I) of consumers feel that the quality offered by firm 2 is at level k L .

Equilibrium with a covered market

In a covered market hypothesis, both informed and uninformed consumers decide to buy from one or the other of these two firms. We obtain a demand addressed to each firm:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha +\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)}{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}} \) gives:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}+\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left[\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right] $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{2}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}} \) gives:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left[\alpha +\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right] $$

We thus obtain the equilibrium:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{3}}\left[\mathsf{2}\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha +\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{3}}\left[\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\mathsf{2}\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha \hbox{-} \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

The covered market condition for informed and uniformed consumers gives:

$$ {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\ge \alpha +\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}} $$
(C5)

E5 equilibrium: firm 1 chooses a conventional strategy and firm 2 an innovation strategy. Under condition (C5), there is a single equilibrium with a covered market, such that:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{l}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{3}}\left[\mathsf{2}\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha +\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{3}}\left[\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\mathsf{2}\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha \hbox{-} \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{6}\alpha}\left[\underline {\mathrm{c}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha +\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{6}\alpha}\left[\overline{\mathsf{c}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha \hbox{-} \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]\hfill \\ {}{\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{1}\mathsf{8}\alpha }{\left[\underline {\mathrm{c}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha +\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]}^2\hfill \\ {}{\varPi}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{1}\mathsf{8}\alpha }{\left[\overline{\mathsf{c}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{3}\alpha \hbox{-} \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\right]}^2\hbox{-} \mathsf{F}\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

Equilibrium with an uncovered market for informed and uninformed consumers

In the uncovered market hypothesis for both kinds of consumer, we obtain a demand for both forms’ products:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}}{\alpha}\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}}{\alpha}\right)+\left(1-\mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}}{\alpha}\right)\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}} \) gives:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left(\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right) $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{2}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}} \) gives:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}}\left[\alpha +\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{I}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right] $$

The uncovered market conditions are written as:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{1}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right)<{\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{2}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right)\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{1}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right)<{\overline{\mathsf{y}}}_{\mathsf{2}}\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right)\hfill \end{array}\right.\iff {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}>\alpha +\mathsf{2}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}} $$

We obtain:

$$ \left(\mathsf{3}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}<\underline {\mathsf{c}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}} $$
(C6)

E6 equilibrium: firm 1 chooses a conventional strategy and firm 2 an innovation strategy. Under condition (C6), there is a single uncovered market equilibrium, such that:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{2}\left(\overline{\mathsf{c}}+\alpha +{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right)\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{2}\left[\underline {\mathrm{c}}+\alpha +\mathsf{I}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right]\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\left(\alpha \hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right)\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\left[\alpha \hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{I}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right]\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{4}\alpha }{\left[\alpha \hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\right]}^2\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\varPi}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{1}}{\mathsf{4}\alpha }{\left[\alpha \hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}+\mathsf{I}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\right]}^2\hbox{-} \mathsf{F}\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

Incompatibility of constraints (C5) and (C6)

We can easily show that (C5) and (C6) are incompatible with one another if and only if:

$$ {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}<\frac{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\underline {\mathsf{c}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)+\alpha \left(\mathsf{3}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}{\mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)} $$
(C7)

Equilibrium with an uncovered market only for uninformed consumers

In the uncovered market hypothesis for uninformed consumers, we obtain the demand for both firms’ products:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{I}\left(\frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\right)+\left(1-\mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}}{\alpha}\right)\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\right)+\left(1-\mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}}{\alpha}\right)\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{1}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}} \) gives:

$$ \mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{I}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}+\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}\ \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}} $$

The first-order profit maximization condition \( {\varPi}_{\mathsf{2}}=\left({\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)\ {\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}} \) gives:

$$ \mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\mathsf{I}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\alpha +\underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}\ \left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}} $$

We thus obtain the equilibrium:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{c}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\alpha +\underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}^{\mathsf{2}}\left(\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}+\mathsf{4}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}}{\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right)}\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}^{\mathsf{2}}\left(\alpha +\underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+\mathsf{4}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}}{\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right)}\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

The market coverage condition for uninformed consumers is written as:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}+{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}\le \alpha +\mathsf{2}{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}} $$
(C7)

which is equivalent to:

$$ \left(\mathsf{6}\hbox{-} \mathsf{5}\mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}\hbox{-} \mathsf{2}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}>\alpha \mathsf{I}+\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\underline {\mathsf{c}}+\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right) $$
(C7)

The uncovered market condition for uninformed consumers is written as:

$$ {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}+{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}>\alpha +{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}} $$
(C7’)

which is equivalent to:

$$ \alpha \mathsf{I}>\left({\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+{\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}\hbox{-} \underline {\mathrm{c}}\hbox{-} \overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right) $$
(C7’)

E7 equilibrium: firm 1 chooses the convention strategy and firm to the innovation strategy. Under conditions (C7) and (C7)’, there is a single uncovered market equilibrium for uninformed consumers, such that:

$$ \left|\begin{array}{l}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\alpha +\underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}^{\mathsf{2}}\left(\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}+\mathsf{4}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}}{\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right)}\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}^{*}=\frac{\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\alpha +\overline{\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}{\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)}^{\mathsf{2}}\left(\alpha +\underline {\mathsf{c}}\right)+\mathsf{2}\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}+\mathsf{4}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{2}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right){\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}}{\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{4}\hbox{-} \mathsf{3}\mathsf{I}\right)}\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{1}}=\mathsf{I}\left(\frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\right)+\left(1-\mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{H}}}{\alpha}\right)\hfill \\ {}{\mathsf{D}}_{\mathsf{2}}=\mathsf{I}\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{1}}+\alpha }{\mathsf{2}\alpha}\right)+\left(1-\mathsf{I}\right)\left(\mathsf{1}\hbox{-} \frac{{\mathsf{p}}_{\mathsf{2}}\hbox{-} {\mathsf{k}}_{\mathsf{L}}}{\alpha}\right)\hfill \end{array}\right. $$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Giraud-Héraud, E., Ponssard, JP., Desgagné, B.S. et al. The agro-food industry, public health, and environmental protection: investigating the Porter hypothesis in food regulation. Rev Agric Food Environ Stud 97, 127–140 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s41130-016-0011-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s41130-016-0011-8

Keywords

JEL classification

Navigation