Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Equilibrium unemployment as a worker insurance device: wage setting in worker owned enterprises

  • Original Paper
  • Published:
Economia Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Worker co-operatives have been shown as characterised by higher wage volatility while providing higher employment stability compared with investor-owned firms (IOFs). These stylised facts show co-operatives’ stronger tendency to preserve employment more than maximising members’ incomes or profits. Most empirical tests in different national contexts also provide evidence of lower wages in worker co-operatives than in IOFs. Such evidence is unexplained to date. To fill this explanatory gap, we resort to the Shapiro and Stiglitz (Am Econ Rev 74(3):433–444, 1984) model of unemployment as a worker discipline device. Given lower agency costs, more efficient monitoring and the absence of wage premiums compensating for the expected costs of contractual failures, we show that equilibrium wages in co-operatives can be lower than in IOFs, while employment, ceteris paribus, is always higher. We draw the following conclusions: (1) Equilibrium unemployment can be at least partly interpreted as a negative external effect of labour contract failures and bilateral opportunism. (2) Shapiro and Stiglitz’s (1984) result is a special case of a broader class of equilibria characterised by contractual imperfections in the agency relation. (3) Various ownership forms can have different impacts on equilibrium unemployment and wages.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The neo-classical economic theory of the self-managed firm was formulated for the first time by Ward (1958) and the literature that followed his article has delineated different ideal types of self-managed firms: the Worker managed firm (WMF) where the social (state) ownership of capital is exclusively internally financed (Furubotn and Pejovitch 1970); the labour managed firm (LMF) in which capital is exclusively financed by borrowing (Vanek 1970).

  2. For the sake of simplicity, we equate worker co-operatives with worker-owned firms and capitalist enterprises with investor-owned firms.

  3. This equilibrium condition implies that co-operatives reduce employment in the presence of higher prices (Ellerman 1986). This second effect corresponds to the well-known “perverse” reactions of LMFs to market stimuli, implying a downward sloping supply curve. The existence of a perverse supply effect has been refuted by several empirical tests (e.g., Bonin 1981; Montias 1986; Nantz and Sparks 1990; Bartlett et al. 1992), which has led to increasing criticism against the assumptions and the implications of the Ward model (Ellerman 1986; Horvat 1986; Bonin et al. 1993; Tortia 2003). In most tests, WOFs appear to have a more rigid but not downward sloping supply curve, showing their stronger tendency to protect employment levels also in the short run. On the contrary, the former implication remains largely unquestioned, even though it does not generally pass the test of empirical verification (e.g., Bartlett et al. 1992; Bonin et al. 1993).

  4. Evidence of higher wages in co-operatives is found in a few studies and favoured by production technologies characterised by decreasing returns to scale (cf. Burdín and Dean 2009; Burdín 2016; Dean 2018 on Uruguay).

  5. The ratio of managerial pay to unskilled manual pay is almost 75% higher in private firms than in co-operatives (ibid. 110).

  6. Similar results concerning worker productivity and wage equity have been obtained in experimental settings (Frohlich et al. 1998).

  7. Laid-off members were still paid 80% of their wages.

  8. Italian law (n. 381/1991) defines social co-operatives as multi-stakeholder co-operatives, and they are not required to include workers in their membership base. However, the majority of social co-operatives can de facto be considered worker co-operatives since workers represent either the only or the dominant stakeholder group in the membership.

  9. This refers to Holmstrom’s (1982) definition of a “budget breaker” as a third party that appropriates the residual of production and monitors the team.

  10. The heterogeneity of members’ preferences is reported to substantially increase governance costs (Hansmann 1996; Belloc 2017). Although this problem is not central to our study, and our theoretical model is ill-suited to deal with it, we provide evidence that decision-making costs can be inflated by complex, time-consuming and contrasting participation processes. Consistent with Ostrom’s (1990) view, we claim that co-operatives can reduce these emerging cost categories by developing effective governance (cf. Borzaga and Tortia 2017). Supporting other authors’ positions, we also hypothesise that co-operatives tend to self-select in sectors of activities where it is possible to keep pay scales compressed and have a homogeneous workforce (Belloc 2017).

  11. These contractual failures require the introduction of both legal regulation and self-regulation, aimed at developing multi-stakeholder governance, for example, different forms of co-determination (Blair and Stout 1999). Direct worker control is understood as a radical solution to the same problem, which would imply disregarding the employment relation itself (Jossa 2014).

  12. The one-period expected utility is expressed as the sum of the utility of the current period plus the probability of state change multiplied by the change in the expected utility.

  13. The reason is that increases in \({\bar{w}}\) tighten the NSC, so all payments are made in the form of \(w\) rather than \({\bar{w}}\).

  14. In the case of constant returns to scale, \(F'(L)L = F(L)\), the market equilibrium is optimal and in A in any case.

  15. In general, it is not possible to ascertain whether the equilibrium entails too much or too little employment, and in the case of constant returns to scale, the competitive equilibrium involves too much monitoring and employment. The reason for the result is that each firm believes that the only instrument under its control to reduce shirking is to increase monitoring, but reducing employment enables society to save resources and to offset the loss from the reduced employment (Shapiro and Stiglitz 1984: 441).

  16. As stated, Bowles and Gintis (1987) demonstrate that in worker co-operatives, the risk of worker opportunism, with workers reducing their effort when not properly controlled, is lower than in capitalistic firms, and mutual monitoring is a stronger instrument that increases the probability of successful monitoring.

  17. We could extend the analysis to the effects of the reduced shirking on the levels of effort in co-operatives, measured by the second part of Eq. (7) as an incentive to increase monitoring.

  18. The demand for higher employment protection in exchange for lower wages, as in WOFs, would instead be ineffective since the employers would retain their decision-making power, hence the possibility to start too risky investment projects in order to increase the expected net income. Hidden actions would again increase the probability of workers’ layoffs.

  19. We assume that parameter d, which represents the impact of contractual failures on the NSC, is separable from the other parameters of the model; in other words, it is independent of effort and unemployment.

  20. There is only the case where the equilibrium in WOFs is associated with higher levels of wages due to different diminishing returns to the variable factor and different levels of capital that involve an APL curve positioned in a manner that the equilibrium corresponds to wages higher than wI.

References

  • Albanese, M., Navarra, C., & Tortia, E. (2015). Employer moral hazard and wage rigidity. The case of worker owned and investor owned firms. International Review of Law and Economics, 43(C), 227–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. A., & Demsetz, H. (1972). Production, information costs, and economic organization. The American Economic Review, 62(5), 777–795.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alves, G., Burdín, G., & Dean, A. (2016). Workplace democracy and job flows. Journal of Comparative Economics, 44(2), 258–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arando, S., Freundlich, F., Gago, M., Jones, D. C., & Kato, T. (2010). Assessing Mondragon: Stability and managed change in the face of globalization. Working Paper No. 1003. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan, William Davidson Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bailly, F., Chapelle, K., & Prouteau, L. (2017). Wage differentials between conventional firms and non-worker cooperatives: Analysis of evidence from France. Competition and Change, 21(4), 321–341.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartlett, W., Cable, J., Estrin, S., Jones, D., & Smith, S. (1992). Labor managed cooperatives and private firms in North Central Italy: An empirical comparison. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 46(1), 03–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bartling, B., Fehr, E., & Schmidt, K. M. (2012). Use and abuse of authority: A behavioral foundation of the employment relation. Bonn: IZA DP no. 7029 (online). http://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/viewdoc/download?doi=10.1.1.419.8257&rep=rep1&type=pdf. Accessed 03 Aug 2018.

  • Belloc, F. (2017). What deters labor-owned firm creation? Evidence from Italian manufacturing sectors. Journal of Comparative Economics, 45(1), 139–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Ner, A. (1988). The life cycle of worker-owned firms in market economies. Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 10(3), 287–313.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bisio, L., Cardinaleschi, S., & Leoni, L. (2017). Contrattazioni integrative aziendali e produttività: nuove evidenze empiriche sulle imprese italiane. Paper presented at the 58th SIE annual meeting (Italian Economic Association). University of Calabria, Oct. 2017 (online). http://www.siecon.org/online/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/Bisio.pdf. Accessed 18 Oct.

  • Blair, M. M., & Stout, L. A. (1999). A team production theory of corporate law. Virginia Law Review, 85(2), 247–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonin, J. P. (1981). The theory of the labor-managed firm from the membership’s perspective with implications for Marshallian industry supply. Journal of Comparative Economics, 5(4), 337–351.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bonin, J. P., Jones, D., & Putterman, L. (1993). Theoretical and empirical studies of producer cooperatives: Will the twain ever meet?. Journal of Economic Literature, 31(3), 1290–1320.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borzaga, C., & Depedri, S. (2005). Interpersonal relations and job satisfaction: Some empirical results in social and community care services. In B. Gui & R. Sugden (Eds.), Economics and social interaction: Accounting for interpersonal relations (pp. 132–153). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borzaga, C., & Tortia, E. C. (2006). Worker motivations, job satisfaction, and loyalty in public and non-profit social services. Non-profit and Voluntary Sector Quarterly, 35(2), 225–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borzaga, C., & Tortia, E. C. (2017). Cooperation as coordination mechanism: A new approach to the economics of cooperative enterprises. In J. Michie, J. R. Blasi, & C. Borzaga (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of mutual, cooperative, and co-owned business (pp. 55–75). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1987). Democracy and capitalism: Property, community, and the contradictions of modern social thought. New York, NY: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1993a). The revenge of homo economicus: Contested exchange and the revival of political economy. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 7(1), 83–102.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1993b). A political and economic case for the democratic enterprise. Economics and Philosophy, 9(1), 75–100.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (1998). Mutual monitoring in teams: The effects of residual claimancy and reciprocity. Working Paper No. 98-08-074e. Santa Fe: Santa Fe Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., & Gintis, H. (2008). The democratic firm: An agency-theoretic evaluation. In S. Bowles, H. A. Gintis, & B. Gustafsson (Eds.), Markets and democracy: Participation, accountability and efficiency (pp. 11–39). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burdín, G. (2016). Equality under threat by the talented: Evidence from worker-managed firms. The Economic Journal, 126(594), 1372–1403.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burdín, G., & Dean, A. (2009). New evidence on wages and employment in worker cooperatives compared with capitalist firms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(4), 517–533.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, J. J., Lai, C. C., & Lin, C. C. (2003). Profit sharing, worker effort, and double-sided moral hazard in an efficiency wage model. Journal of Comparative Economics, 31(1), 75–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clemente, J., Diaz-Foncea, M., Marcuello, C., & Sanso-Navarro, M. (2012). The wage gap between cooperative and capitalist firms: Evidence from Spain. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 83(3), 337–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Craig, B., & Pencavel, J. (1992). The behavior of workers cooperatives: The plywood companies of the Pacific Northwest. American Economic Review, 82(5), 1083–1105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig, B., Pencavel, J., Farber, H., & Krueger, A. (1995). Participation and productivity: A comparison of worker cooperatives and conventional firms in the plywood industry. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. Microeconomics, 1995, 121–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dean, A., 2018. Employee buyouts in Uruguay. Paper presented at the IAFEP (International Association for the Economics of Participation) in Ljubljana, 13-15 July 2018 (online). http://www.iafep.org/papers-and-presentations. Accessed 29 July 2018.

  • Deci, E. L. (1971). Effects of externally mediated rewards on intrinsic motivation. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 18(1), 105–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deci, E. L. (1975). Intrinsic motivation. New York: Plenum Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Deci, E. L., & Ryan, R. M. (1985). Intrinsic motivation and self-determination in human behavior. New York: Plenum Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Delbono, F., & Reggiani, C. (2013). Cooperative firms and the crisis: Evidence from some Italian mixed oligopolies. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 84(4), 383–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Domar, E. D. (1966). The Soviet collective farm as a producer cooperative. American Economic Review, 56(4), 734–757.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dow, G. K. (2003). Governing the firm. Workers’ control in theory and practice. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dow, G. K. (2018). The labor-managed firm: Theoretical foundations. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Drèze, J. H. (1976). Some theory of labor management and participation. Econometrica, 44(6), 1125–1139.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellerman, D. (1986). Horizon problems and property rights in labor-managed firms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 10(1), 62–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Estrin, S. (1991). Some reflections on self-management: Social choice and reform in Eastern Europe. Journal of Comparative Economics, 15(2), 349–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eswaran, M., & Kotwal, A. (1984). The moral hazard of budget-breaking. The Rand Journal of Economics, 15(4), 578–581.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Euricse. (2015). Terzo rapporto Euricse sull’economia cooperativa. Trento: European Research Institute on Cooperatives and Social Enterprises (online). http://www.euricse.eu/wp-content/uploads/2015/09/00-ECONOMIA-COOPERATIVA.pdf. Accessed 6 Aug 2018.

  • Faria, J. R. (2000). Supervision and effort in an intertemporal efficiency wage model: The role of the Solow condition. Economics Letters, 67(1), 93–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1997). Not just for the money: An economic theory of personal motivation. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N., Godarda, J., Oppenheimer, J. A., & Starke, F. A. (1998). Employee versus conventionally-owned and controlled firms: An experimental analysis. Managerial and Decions Economics, 19(4–5), 311–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Furubotn, E. G., & Pejovitch, S. (1970). Tax policy and investment decisions of the Yugoslav firm. National Tax Journal, 23(3), 431–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenberg, E. S. (1986). Workplace democracy: The political effects of participation. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrazzi, M. (2008). Dynamic efficiency-wage model with continuous effort and externalities. Economic Issues, 13(2), 37–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrazzi, M. (2012). On involuntary unemployment: Notes on efficiency-wage competition. MPRA Paper No. 38140 (online). https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/38140/. Accessed 27 July 2018.

  • Guest, D. (2002). Human resource management, corporate performance and employee wellbeing: Building the worker into HRM. The Journal of Industrial Relations, 44(3), 335–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H. (1996). The ownership of enterprise. Cambridge, MA: The Bellknap Press of Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmann, H. (1999). Cooperative firms in theory and practice. The Finnish Journal of Business Economics, 4, 387–403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162(3859), 1243–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmstrom, B. (1982). Moral hazard in teams. The Bell Journal of Economics, 13(2), 324–340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Horvat, B. (1986). The theory of the worker-managed firm revisited. Journal of Comparative Economics, 10(1), 9–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jensen, M., & Meckling, W. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305–360.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jossa, B. (2014). Producer cooperatives as a new mode of production. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jossa, B. (2017). Labour managed firms and post-capitalism. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kruse, D. (2016). Does employee ownership improve performance? IZA World of Labor: 311 (online). https://doi.org/10.15185/izawol.311. Accessed 27 Oct 2018.

  • MacLeod, W. B. (1984). A theory of cooperative teams. CORE Discussion Papers 1984041 (online). https://ideas.repec.org/p/cor/louvco/1984041.html. Accessed 6 Aug 2018.

  • Meade, J. E. (1972). Agathotopia: The economics of partnership. Aberdeen: Aberdeen University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mikami, K. (2011). Enterprise forms and economic efficiency: Capitalist, cooperative and government firms. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Miyazaki, H., & Neary, H. M. (1983). The Illyrian firm revisited. Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1), 259–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Montias, J. M. (1986). On the labor-managed firm in a competitive environment. Journal of Comparative Economics, 10(1), 2–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nantz, K., & Sparks, R. (1990). The labor-managed firm under imperfect monitoring: Employment and work effort responses. Journal of Comparative Economics, 14(1), 33–50.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. Public goods and the theory of the groups. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons. The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Pencavel, J. (2002). Worker participation: Lessons from the workers co-ops of the Pacific Northwest. New York, NY: Russell Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pencavel, J., & Craig, B. (1994). The empirical performance of orthodox models of the firm: Conventional firms and worker cooperatives. Journal of Political Economy, 102(4), 718–744.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pencavel, J., Pistaferri, L., & Schivardi, F. (2006). Wages, employment, and capital in capitalist and worker-owned firms. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 60(1), 23–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Prendergast, C. (1999). The provision of incentives in firms. The Journal of Economic Literature, 37(1), 7–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putterman, L. (1984). On some recent explanations of why capital hires labor. Economic Inquiry, 22(2), 171–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roelants, B., Dovgan, D, Eum, H., & Terrasi, E. (2012). The resilience of the cooperative model: How worker cooperatives, social cooperatives and other worker-owned enterprises respond to the crisis and its consequences. CECOP, Bruxelles (online). http://www.cecop.coop/IMG/pdf/report_cecop_2012_en_web.pdf. Accessed 31 July 2018.

  • Sacconi, L. (2012). Corporate social responsibility and corporate governance. Working paper 38, Econometica (online). http://www.econometica.it/wp/wp38.pdf . Accessed 30 July 2018.

  • Screpanti, E. (2001). The fundamental institutions of capitalism. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1984). Equilibrium unemployment as a worker discipline device. American Economic Review, 74(3), 433–444.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tortia, E. C. (2003). Distribution of value added, and accumulation of capital in labour-managed firms. Economia Politica, 19(2), 251–286.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tortia, E. C. (2018). The firm as a common. Non-divided ownership, patrimonial stability and longevity of cooperative enterprises. Sustainability, 10, 1023.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vanek, J. (1970). The general theory of labor-managed market economies. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ward, B. (1958). The firm in Illyria: Market syndicalism. American Economic Review, 48(4), 566–589.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author writes in her personal capacity. The content of the paper is the sole responsibility of the author and any opinions expressed herein should not be taken to represent an official position of the Parliament. We are grateful to Avner Ben-Ner, Carlo Borzaga, Alessandro Fedele for useful comments and suggestions. Usual disclaimer applies.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marina Albanese.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Albanese, M., Navarra, C. & Tortia, E. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker insurance device: wage setting in worker owned enterprises. Econ Polit 36, 653–671 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-018-00139-z

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-018-00139-z

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation