Skip to main content
Log in

Firm financed training and pareto improving firing taxes

  • Published:
Economia Politica Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyses how the under-investment in firm financed training caused by hold up can justify the introduction of firing taxes in a laissez-faire economy with search frictions and risk neutral agents. In particular, we show two main results. First, the introduction of a firing tax for newly hired workers combined with hiring subsidies, always acts as a Pareto improving policy. Second, with no hiring subsidies, the introduction of a firing tax for the newly hired always increase the welfare of employed while its impact on the welfare of unemployed depends on the returns to training. Hence, policy implications are derived.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Using Euro Area data to parameterize their model, Thomas and Zanetti (2009) also simulate the effects of hypothetical reductions in unemployment benefits and firing costs showing that these reforms would have only small effects on inflation volatility, due to the small contribution of hiring and firing costs to inflation volatility.

  2. Additive returns of training simplify analysis without affecting the results; moreover, they highlight that firm-sponsored training does not arise because of complementary between training and match specific productivity (see Acemoglu and Pischke 1999).

  3. In our model the tax paid on separation is not a compensation given to the newly hired worker but a loss borne entirely by the firm. In reality EPL has other components, such as severance payments. Severance payments are pure transfers in wage bargaining, so they do not affect the financing of training by firms.

  4. In the period when the policy is introduced, no workers hired after the introduction of the policy are fired (since they are all in training). The government borrows to pay the first round of subsidies and collects exactly enough revenue to repay its debt when some of the workers whose hiring was subsidized are fired.

  5. The economy is characterized by an initial laissez-faire equilibrium in which \(\sigma = T = 0\). From the first period onward the government may introduced firing tax \(T > 0\) and hiring subsidies \(\sigma > 0\), according to the design of the policy.

  6. Agreement is always reached so firms never pay the firing taxes which affect wage negotiations, while the firing taxes which are actually paid in equilibrium only affect wages indirectly by affecting the value of matches.

  7. Similar conclusions are reached if the firm could write a binding contract about training, but workers could not take enough of wage cut to finance it. This happens, for example, in presence of liquidity constraints and/or a binding legal minimum wage. In this case both firing tax and the cost of training cannot push bargained wage below the minimum level, so that there will be a lower bound which prevents the firms from sharing these costs with workers.

  8. It is straightforward to demonstrating that Eq. (9) can be equivalently derived from: (9′) \(J_{1} (\varepsilon^{d} ,h) = - T\). Since the asset value \(J_{1} (\varepsilon ,h)\) increases with the idiosyncratic component \(\varepsilon\), there is a unique threshold value. Given labour market equilibrium both (9) and (9′) mean that firms and employees decide to separate only if the value of the surplus in the second stage of the match is negative.

  9. Note that the right hand side of Eq. (11) is the firms’ share of total surplus evaluated at the first stage of the match: \(J{}_{0}(\varepsilon^{e} ,h) = \left( {1 - \beta } \right)\left( {J{}_{0}(\varepsilon^{e} ,h) + E{}_{0}(\varepsilon^{e} ,h) - U} \right)\).

  10. This approach to policy evaluation can be justified by arguing that since general search externalities have an ambiguous impact on welfare and \(\beta\) is unobservable, in practice, policy may not succeed in improving this aspect of resource allocation (Pissarides 2001).

  11. Note that we have also performed a computational analysis using ISFOL-PLUS data to provide an example that the introduction of a small firing tax for newly hired workers may be Pareto Improving also with no hiring subsidies (results are available on request).

  12. The Eq. (16) is subject to a dynamic of unemployment in each period of time (27) \(u_{t} = u_{t - 1} - m\left( {u_{t - 1} ,v_{t - 1} } \right) + F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)\). In steady state it will be: \(m(u,v) = F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)\).

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Pischke, S. (1999). Beyond becker: training in imperfect labour market. Economic Journal, 109, 112–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arulampalam, W., & Booth, A. (1998). Training and labour market flexibility: Is there a trade-off? The British Journal of Industrial Relations, 36(4), 521–536.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bassanini, A., Booth, A., Brunello, G., De Paola, M., & Leuven, E., (2005). Workplace Training in Europe, IZA Discussion Papers 1640, Institute for the Study of Labor.

  • Bassanini, A., Nunziata, L., & Venn, D. (2009). Job protection legislation and productivity growth in OECD countries. Economic Policy, 24, 349–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belot, M., Boone, J., & van Ours, J. (2007). Welfare-improving employment protection. Economica, 74(295), 381–396.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentolila, S., & Bertola, G. (1990). Firing costs and labor demand: How bad is eurosclerosis? Review of Economic Studies, 57, 381–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentolila, S., & Dolado, J. (1994). Labor flexibility and wages: Lessons from Spain. Economic Policy, 18, 55–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertola, G., & Rogerson, R. (1997). Institutions and labor reallocation. European Economic Review, 41, 1147–1171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K., Rubinstein, A., & Wolinsky, A. (1986). The nash bargaining solution in economic modelling. Rand Journal of Economics, 17, 176–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., & Landier, A. (2002). The perverse effects of partial labour market reform: Fixed term contracts in France. Economic Journal, 112, 214–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boeri, T. (2011). Institutional Reforms and Dualism in European Labor Markets. Handbook of Labor Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boeri, T., & Garibaldi, P. (2007). Two tier reforms of employment protection: A honeymoon effect? Economic Journal, 117(521), 357–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damiani, M., Pompei, F., & Ricci, A., (2011). Temporary job protection and productivity growth in EU economies, MPRA Paper n. 29698, University Library of Munich.

  • Damiani, M., Pompei, F., & Ricci, A., (2012). Labour share and employment protection in European economies, MPRA Paper 43058, University Library of Munich.

  • Estevez-Abe, M., Iversen, T., & Soskice, D. (2001). Social protection and the formation of skills: A reinterpretation of the welfare state. In P. Hall & D. Soskice (Eds.), Varieties of capitalism: The challenges facing contemporary political economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garibaldi, P. (1998). Job flow dynamics and firing restrictions. European Economic Review, 42, 245–275.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guell, M., & Petrongolo, B. (2007). How binding are legal limits? Transitions from temporary to permanent work in Spain. Labour Economics, 14(2), 153–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hashimoto, M. (1981). Specific human capital as a shared investment. American Economic Review, 3, 476–482.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hashimoto, M., & Yu, B. T. (1980). Specific capital, employment contracts, and wage rigidity. The Bell Journal of Economics, 2, 536–549.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmlund, B., & Storrie, D. (2002). Temporary work in turbulent times: The Swedish experience. Economic Journal, 112, 245–269.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hosios, A. (1990). On the efficiency of matching and related models of search and unemployment. Review of Economic Studies, 57, 279–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ISFOL (2014). Mercato del Lavoro, Capital Umano e Imprese: una prospettiva di politica del Lavoro, FSE-ISFOL.

  • Layard, R., & Nickell, S. (1999). Labor market institutions and economic performance. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Malcomson, J. (1999). Individual employment contracts. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen, D., & Pissarides, C. (1994). Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. Review of Economic Studies, 61, 397–415.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mortensen, D., & Pissarides, C. (1999). New developments in the model of search in the labor market. In O. Ashenfelter & D. Card (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, C. (2000). Equilibrium unemployment theory (2nd ed.). Cambridge: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pissarides, C. (2001). Employment protection. Labour Economics, 8, 131–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, C., & Zanetti, F. (2009). Labor market reform and price stability: An application to the Euro Area. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(6), 885–899.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wasmer, E. (2006). General versus specific skills in labor markets with search frictions and firing costs. American Economic Review, 96(3), 811–831.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zanetti, F. (2011). Labor market institutions and aggregate fluctuations in a search and matching model. European Economic Review, 55(5), 644–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zanetti, F. (2013). On the Friedman rule with labor market frictions. Central Bank Review, 13(2), 59–78.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Andrea Ricci.

Appendices

Appendix 1: The local maximum

Firms maximize their expected profit with respect to training and threshold productivity, i.e. \(MaxJ_{{\varepsilon^{d} ,h}}^{0} \left( {\varepsilon^{e} ,h} \right)\). The equilibrium wage at entry does not vary when firms make their optimal choices, so that the expected profit is

  1. (i)
    $$J_{0} \left( {\varepsilon^{e} ,h} \right) = \frac{{\varepsilon^{e} - h - w_{0} + \sigma }}{1 + r} - \frac{{\left[ {F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right) - \beta \left( {1 - F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)} \right)} \right] \cdot T}}{1 + r} - \frac{{\left( {1 - \beta } \right)\left[ {1 - F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)} \right] \cdot U}}{1 + r} + \frac{(1 - \beta )}{(r + s)(1 + r)}\int\limits_{{\varepsilon^{d} }}^{{\varepsilon_{u} }} {\left( {\varepsilon^{\prime } + ah^{\alpha } } \right)dF\left( {\varepsilon^{\prime } } \right)}$$

    First order conditions are given by Eqs. (11) and (12). To find a local maximum the Hessian matrix must be semi definite negative so that:

    $$\frac{{(1 - \beta )^{2} \alpha (1 - \alpha )h^{\alpha - 2} [1 - F(\varepsilon^{d} )]f(\varepsilon^{d} ) - (1 - \beta )[f(\varepsilon^{d} )]^{2} \alpha^{2} a^{2} h^{2\alpha - 2} }}{{(r + s)^{2} (1 + r)^{2} }} > 0$$

    that is:

  2. (ii)

    \(\frac{{(1 - \alpha ) \cdot \left[ {1 - F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)} \right]}}{{a \cdot \alpha \cdot f\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)}} > h^{\alpha }\).

Appendix 2: Existence and uniqueness of equilibrium

Existence Define the four component vector \(z \equiv \left( {h,\varepsilon^{d} ,\theta ,U} \right)\). An equilibrium is a fixed point of the correspondence \(\varPsi\) from \(z\) to \(z\), with \(\varPsi (z) = \left( {h(z),\varepsilon^{d} (z),\theta (z),U(z)} \right)\), where \(\theta (z)\) is defined implicitly by Eq. (13), \(U(z)\) is defined by Eq. (14) and \(h_{{}} (z)\) and \(\varepsilon^{d} (z)\) are chosen to maximize \(J_{0} \left( {\varepsilon^{e} ,h} \right)\). The correspondence \(\varPsi\) is a best response relation. Thus it is convex valued and has a closed graph. \(\varPsi\) maps a convex compact set into itself, so Kukutani’s fixed point theorem implies that \(\varPsi\) has a fixed point, which is an equilibrium.

Proof To prove the continuity of functions in vector \(z\) is straightforward. The optimal training choice is a continuous function and takes values in the range \(0 \le h \le \left[ {\frac{{\alpha a\left( {1 - \beta } \right)}}{(r + s)}} \right]^{{\frac{1}{1 - \alpha }}} \equiv \bar{h}\); then the set of possible values of training is compact. Market tightness is also continuous and assumes values in the range: \(0 \le m^{ - 1} (\theta ) < \left[ {\frac{{\left( {1 - \beta } \right)\varepsilon^{e} }}{{k\left( {1 + r} \right)}} + \frac{{\left( {1 - \beta } \right)\left( {\varepsilon + a\bar{h}^{\alpha } } \right)}}{{k\left( {1 + r} \right)\left( {r + s} \right)}}} \right]\). The value of being unemployed can be written as \(U = U\left( {h,\varepsilon ,\frac{{r\left( {1 - \beta } \right)}}{\beta k}U} \right)\), with \(\theta = \frac{{r\left( {1 - \beta } \right)}}{\beta k}U\), so that \(0 < U \le U\left( {\overline{h} ,\varepsilon_{U} } \right) \equiv \overline{U}\). Finally \(\underline{\varepsilon } \equiv \varepsilon (0,\overline{h} ) < \varepsilon_{{}}^{d} < \varepsilon (\overline{U} ,0) \equiv \overline{\varepsilon }\), where \(\left[ {\varepsilon_{L} ,\varepsilon_{U} } \right]\) is the finite support of the distribution of the idiosyncratic productivity and \(h_{\hbox{max} }\) is the maximum amount of training.

Uniqueness of the interior solution If condition (ii) is met, the maximized expected profit can be represented as function of the equilibrium value of being unemployed: \(J_{0} (U) = MaxJ_{{_{{\varepsilon^{d} ,h}}^{0} }} \left( {\varepsilon^{e} \left( U \right),h(U),U} \right)\). \(J_{0} (U)\) is continuous and decreasing with respect to the value of being unemployed, \(\frac{{dJ_{0} }}{dU} < 0\), so that \(\frac{{d\theta \left( {J_{0} } \right)}}{dU} < 0\). Considering the positive monotonic relation between the equilibrium market tightness and workers’ outside option, Eq. (14), and the continuous positive relation between \(\theta\) and \(J_{0} (U)\), Eq. (13), it is verified that: \(\frac{{dU\left( {J_{0} ,\theta \left( {J_{0} } \right)} \right)}}{dU} < 0\). Thus there can be only one equilibrium value of \(U\)and, as a consequence, there is only an equilibrium value of \(\theta\). Two different solutions to \(\left( {h,\varepsilon^{d} } \right)\) would have to give the same maximal \(J_{0} (\varepsilon^{e} ,h)\) and the same \(U_{{}}\). However this result is not possible since the sum \(J_{0} + E_{0}\) is increasing in \(h\) at the equilibrium.

A corner solution A corner equilibrium with no layoffs is also possible for some parameters. When \(\varepsilon^{d} = \varepsilon_{L}\), the equilibrium values of training and market tightness are given by Eqs. (12)–(13):

$$h_{\hbox{max} } = \left[ {\frac{\alpha a(1 - \beta )}{r + s}} \right]$$
$$m^{ - 1} (\theta ) = \frac{(1 - \beta )}{k(1 + r)}\left[ {\left( {\left( {\varepsilon^{e} - h_{\hbox{max} } } \right) - rU + \left( {\varepsilon^{e} + ah^{\alpha } } \right)} \right)} \right]$$

while the value of being unemployed is determined by Eq. (14). We note that in Eq. (14), for \(\theta = 0\), \(U = 0\), and for \(\theta \to + \infty\), \(U = U_{\hbox{max} }\). In Eq. (13) for \(U = 0\), \(\theta > 0\), and for \(U > 0\), \(\frac{\partial \theta }{\partial U} < 0\). This implies a decreasing relationship between job creation condition and workers’ outside option when \(\varepsilon^{d} = \varepsilon_{L}\) and \(h_{{}} = h_{\hbox{max} }\). Thus, there exists a candidate equilibrium \(\left\{ {\varepsilon_{L} ,h_{\hbox{max} } ,\theta ,U} \right\}\).

Appendix 3: Comparative statics with hiring subsidies

Totally differentiating Eqs. (11)–(13), and using the equilibrium budget constraint, \(\sigma = F\left( {\overline{\varepsilon }^{d} } \right)T\), one obtains:

$$\frac{d\theta }{dT} = \frac{1}{\varTheta }\left[ {\frac{{\left( {1 - \beta } \right)}}{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}}\beta \frac{dh}{dT} + \frac{{\left( {1 - \beta } \right)}}{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}}\left[ {F\left( {\overline{\varepsilon }^{d} } \right) - F\left( {\overline{\varepsilon }^{d} } \right)} \right] + \frac{{\left( {1 - \beta } \right)f\left( {\overline{\varepsilon }^{d} } \right)T}}{{\left( {1 + r} \right)}}} \right]$$

where, as in “Appendix 3”, \(\varTheta = \frac{\eta \cdot \theta }{m(\theta )} + \frac{{r + \left[ {1 - F\left( {\varepsilon_{f}^{d} } \right)} \right]}}{1 + r} \cdot \frac{\beta k}{r(1 - \beta )}\). Given that \(\overline{\varepsilon }^{d} = \varepsilon^{d}\) and evaluating job creation at T = 0, it reduces to: \(\left. {\frac{d\theta }{dT}} \right|_{T = 0} = \frac{1}{\varTheta }\frac{(1 - \beta )}{(1 + r)}\beta \frac{dh}{dT}\). From Eq. (14) we have \(\frac{dU}{dT} = \frac{{\beta^{2} k}}{\varTheta \cdot r(1 + r)}\frac{dh}{dT}\) so that, on the job destruction condition, will be:

$$\left. {\frac{{d\varepsilon_{{}}^{d} }}{dT}} \right|_{T = 0} = \frac{ - (r + s)}{{\left[ {\underbrace {{1 - \frac{{f\left( {\varepsilon_{f}^{d} } \right)a^{2} \alpha^{2} \left( {1 - \beta } \right)h^{2\alpha - 1} }}{{\left( {1 - \alpha } \right)\left( {r + s} \right)}}}}_{ > 0} + (r + s) \cdot \frac{{\beta^{2} k}}{\varTheta \cdot r(1 + r)} \cdot \frac{{f\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)a\alpha (1 - \beta )h^{\alpha } }}{(1 - \alpha )(r + s)}} \right]}} < 0$$

Training is inversely related to the threshold productivity level, when firing cost varies, i.e. \(\left. \frac{dh}{dT} \right|_{T = 0} = - \frac{{f\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)}}{{(1 - \alpha )\left[ {1 - F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)} \right]h^{\alpha - 2} }} \cdot \frac{{d\varepsilon^{d} }}{dT} > 0\) and, as a consequence, \(\left. {\frac{d\theta }{dT}} \right|_{T = 0} > 0\) and \(\left. \frac{dU}{dT} \right|_{T = 0} > 0\).

Appendix 4: Comparative statics without hiring subsidies

With no hiring subsidies, the introduction of firing costs implies:

$$\frac{d\theta }{dT} = \frac{(1 - \beta )}{\varTheta (1 + r)}\left[ {\beta \frac{dh}{dT} - F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)} \right]$$

Totally differentiating Eqs. (11)–(13), and setting σ = 0, one obtains:

$$\left. {\frac{{d\varepsilon^{d} }}{dT}} \right|_{T = 0} = \frac{{ - (r + s)\left[ {\frac{{\varTheta \cdot r(1 + r) + (r + s)\beta kF\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)}}{\varTheta \cdot r(1 + r)}} \right]}}{{\left[ {\underbrace {{1 - \frac{{f\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)a^{2} \alpha^{2} (1 - \beta )h^{2\alpha - 1} }}{(1 - \alpha )(r + s)}}}_{ > 0} + (r + s) \cdot \frac{{\beta^{2} k}}{\varTheta \cdot r(1 + r)} \cdot \frac{{f\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)a\alpha (1 - \beta )h^{\alpha } }}{(1 - \alpha )(r + s)}} \right]}} < 0$$

where \(\varTheta = \frac{\eta \cdot \theta }{m(\theta )} + \frac{{r + \left[ {1 - F\left( {\varepsilon_{f}^{d} } \right)} \right]}}{1 + r} \cdot \frac{\beta k}{r(1 - \beta )}\) and \(\left. \frac{dh}{dT} \right|_{T = 0} = - \frac{{f\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)}}{{(1 - \alpha )[1 - F\left( {\varepsilon^{d} } \right)]h^{\alpha - 2} }} \cdot \frac{{d\varepsilon^{d} }}{dT} > 0.\)

The sign of the effect on market tightness is not clear a priori.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ricci, A., Waldmann, R. Firm financed training and pareto improving firing taxes. Econ Polit 32, 201–220 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-015-0011-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40888-015-0011-1

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation