Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Employer Incentives for Providing Informal On-the-job Training in the Presence of On-the-job Search

  • Published:
Journal of Labor Research Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We analyze the provision of informal general training in a frictional labor market in which employers cannot commit to training levels and workers cannot commit to stay. We demonstrate that employers’ training decisions are driven by both an investment motive, to improve productivity, and a compensation motive, to increase employee retention. The investment motive decreases with higher wages, while the compensation motive increases. In our calibration exercises, the former dominates, which creates a negative relationship between wages and training. Furthermore, in contrast to recent studies missing the compensation motive, lessening the search frictions raises overall training levels due to enhanced compensation motives, approaching Becker’s result for a frictionless labor market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. With regard to formal training, which is easier to measure, Lynch and Black (1998) find that over 50 percent (but not all) of U.S. firms provide and pay for general training such as computer skills training and teamwork training.

  2. Yet, Barron et al. (1997) report that there is a great deal of measurement error in on-the-job training variables survey by survey and respondent by respondent. They show that the correlations between worker and establishment measures of on-the-job training are less than 0.5, which are much lower than correlations for other variables that have been used in wage equations. Establishments report 25 percent more hours of training on average than do workers in the same questions.

  3. For instance, in the 1994 wave of the NLSY79, just 1% of workers in the first year of a job attended formal classes or seminars, but 57% received instruction from supervisors for an average of 52 total hours and 46% received instruction from co-workers for an average of 69 hours. Granted, some portion of this informal instruction is likely specific to the job rather than general training increasing the worker’s productivity in any job. But even if three quarters of those workers received only specific training, the number of those that received informal general training would be an order of magnitude larger than that which receive formal training.

  4. Fallick and Fleischman (2004) find that 60 percent of vacancies in the US labor market are taken by employed searchers and only 40 percent of vacancies are given to unemployed searchers. Topel and Ward (1992) also find that a typical worker holds seven jobs during the first 10 years. In addition, Sim (2012) reports that the average job duration of white male high school graduates in the U.S. is around 2 years.

  5. Acemoglu (1997) assumes an exogenous reallocation shock rather than on-the-job search behavior.

  6. Note that the no-borrowing assumption prevents a ‘selling the firm scheme,’ in which workers could buy the firm and thus the efficient level of training would be achieved.

  7. Following the convention of the search literature, we introduce ‘retirement’ and normalize its value to be zero. It can also be interpreted as ‘death.’

  8. By incorporating the piece rate sharing rule into the wage-posting framework proposed by Burdett and Mortensen (1998), Fu (2011) analyzes the interaction between training and wages. In her model, the recruiting firm commits to a fixed piece rate and training intensity in advance. We borrow and extend her model (borrowing, in particular, the fixed piece rate wage structure) to show that firm-sponsored general training based on an implicit relational contract may increase as the competitive pressure increases.

  9. This is innocuous when dt → 0 because the high order terms converge to zero at much faster rates.

  10. The usual arguments apply to ensure that any equilibrium offer distribution will be continuous and have no gaps.

  11. Note that the vertical axis in Panel (a) covers from 30 to 55, which makes the workers’ value appear flat compared to the value of operating firms shown in Panel (b). But once we adjust the scale, we can see that the workers’ value is steeper.

  12. Sim (2016) derives a (partially) consistent result by introducing an explicit wage-training contract. In this companion paper, he shows both that the market equilibrium may over-provide general training relative to the planner’s problem and that the training intensity is reinforced as search frictions are mitigated.

References

  • Acemoglu D (1997) Training and innovation in an imperfect labour market. Rev Econ Stud 64:445–464

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu D, Pischke J (1999) Beyond Becker: training in imperfect labour markets. Econ J 109:112–142

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barron J, Berger M, Black D (1997) How well do we measure training? J Labor Econ 15:507–528

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Becker G (1964) Human capital: a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. University of Chicago Press

  • Burdett K, Mortensen DT (1998) Wage differentials, equilibrium size, and unemployment. Int Econ Rev 39:257–273

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coles MG (2001) Equilibrium wage dispersion, firm size, and growth. Rev Econ Dyn 4:159–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fallick B, Fleischman C (2004) Employer-to-employer flow in the U.S. labor market: the complete picture of gross worker flows, manuscript

  • Fu C (2011) Training, search and wage dispersion. Rev Econ Dyn 14:650–666

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall RE, Milgrom PR (2008) The limited influence of unemployment on the wage bargain. Amer Econ Rev 98:1653–74

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lentz R, Roys N (2015) Training and search on the job. University of Wisconsin-Madison, Manuscript

  • Loewenstein M, Spletzer J (1998) Informal training: a review of existing data and some new evidence. Bureau of Labor Statistics Working Paper 254

  • Lynch LM, Black SE (1998) Beyond the incidence of employer-provided training. Indus Labor Rev 52:64–81

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sanders C, Taber C (2012) Life-cycle wage growth and heterogeneous human capital. Ann Rev Econ 4:399–425

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shimer R (2005) The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies. Amer Econ Rev 95(1):25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sim S-G (2012) Wage dynamics with private learning-by-doing and on-the-job search. University of Tokyo, Manuscript

  • Sim S-G (2016) On-the-job training and on-the-job search: wage-training contracts in a frictional labor market. University of Tokyo, Manuscript

  • Topel R, Ward M (1992) Job mobility and the careers of young men. Q J Econ 107:439–479

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are indebted to Hidehiko Ichimura, John Kennan, Rasmus Lentz, Hideo Owan, Ozkan Eren, and Chris Taber for their helpful comments and warm encouragement. Seung-Gyu Sim acknowledges financial support by the Grants-in-Aid for Scientific Research (Kakenhi No. 26780170) from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science. All remaining errors are ours.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tim Huegerich.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interests

The authors declare that they have no conflict of interest.

Appendix: Details of the Numerical Algorithm

Appendix: Details of the Numerical Algorithm

In this subsection, I describe an alternative way of solving the model by converting the fixed point problem in the functional space into a fixed point problem in a finite dimensional vector space.

Taking the derivative of Eqs. 14 and 17 with respect to ϕ yields

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lefteqn{[r+\delta+\rho+\lambda[1-F(\phi)]+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}]\frac{dE_{i}(\phi, x^{*}(\phi))}{d\phi}}\\ &&=y_{i}+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}\frac{dE_{i + 1}(\phi, x^{*}_{i + 1}(\phi))}{d\phi}+\mu_{i}(E_{i + 1}(\phi, x^{*}_{i + 1})-E_{i}(\phi, x^{*}_{i}))\frac{dx^{*}_{i}(\phi)}{d\phi},~~\text{and} \end{array} $$
(31)
$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lefteqn{[r+\rho+\delta+\lambda[1-F(\phi)]+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}]\frac{dJ_{i}(\phi)}{d\phi}}\\ && =-y_{i} -c^{\prime}(x^{*}_{i})\frac{dx^{*}_{i}}{d\phi}+ \mu_{i}\frac{dx^{*}_{i}(\phi)}{d\phi} (J_{i + 1}(\phi)-J_{i}(\phi))+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}\frac{dJ_{i + 1}(\phi)}{d\phi}+\lambda\frac{dF(\phi)}{d\phi}J_{i}(\phi). \end{array} $$
(32)

Plugging (31) into (11) yields

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} \lefteqn{c^{\prime}(x^{*}_{i}(\phi)) = \mu_{i}(J_{i + 1}(\phi)-J_{i}(\phi))}\\ && + \lambda \frac{dF(\phi)}{d\phi}\left[\frac{y_{i}-c(x^{*}_{i})+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}(\phi)\frac{dE_{i + 1}}{d\phi}}{\mu_{i}(E_{i + 1}(\phi,x^{*}_{i + 1}(\phi))-E_{i}(\phi,x^{*}_{i}(\phi)))}+\frac{dx^{*}_{i}(\phi)}{d\phi}\right]^{-1}J_{i}(\phi).~~~~~ \end{array} $$
(33)

Equation 33 shows how \(x^{*}_{i}(\cdot )\) proceeds to achieve the first order condition. By taking the derivative of Eq. 18 with respect to ϕ, I obtain

$$ \sum\limits_{i = 1}^{n}\left[(\lambda_{u}u_{i}+\lambda G_{i}(\phi))\frac{dJ_{i}(\phi)}{d\phi}+\lambda\frac{dG_{i}(\phi)}{d\phi}J_{i}(\phi)\right]= 0.~~~ $$
(34)

Plugging (24), (26), and (32) into (34) yields

$$\begin{array}{@{}rcl@{}} {\sum\limits_{i}^{n}}\left[(\lambda_{u}u_{i}+\lambda G_{i}(\phi))\frac{-y_{i}-c^{\prime}(x_{i}^{*})\frac{dx^{*}_{i}}{d\phi}+\mu_{i}\frac{dx^{*}_{i}}{d\phi}(J_{i + 1}(\phi)-J_{i}(\phi))+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}(\phi)\frac{dJ_{i + 1}(\phi)}{d\phi}} {r+\delta+\rho+\lambda(1-F(\phi))+\mu_{i}x_{i}(\phi)}\right.\\ +\left.\lambda\frac{\mu_{i-1}x^{*}_{i-1}(\phi)g_{i-1}(\phi)}{\rho+\delta+\lambda(1-F(\phi))+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}}J_{i}(\phi)\right]~~\\ +{\sum\limits_{i}^{n}}\left[\frac{(\lambda_{u}u_{i}+\lambda G_{i}(\phi))\lambda J_{i}(\phi)}{r+\rho+\delta+\lambda(1-F(\phi))+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}}+\frac{(\lambda_{u}u_{i}+\lambda G_{i}(\phi))\lambda J_{i}(\phi)}{\rho+\delta+\lambda(1-F(\phi))+\mu_{i}x^{*}_{i}}\right]\frac{dF(\phi)}{d\phi}= 0. \end{array} $$
(35)

Equation 35 shows how F evolves with ϕ to maintain the equal profit. Consequently, the steady state equilibrium is described as follows.

  • (i) Given U n , our equilibrium selection rule, \(U_{n}=E_{n}(\underline {\phi }, 0)\), yields \(\underline {\phi }\).

  • (ii) Given \(\{U_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n-1}\) and \(\underline {\phi }\), the initial condition \(U_{i}=E_{i}(\underline {\phi }, x^{*}_{i}(\underline {\phi }))\) together with (14) yields \(x^{*}_{i}(\underline {\phi })\), which in turn determines \(J_{i}(\underline {\phi })\) for each i using (17).

  • (iii) Given \(\{U_{i}=E_{i}(\underline {\phi }, x^{*}_{i}(\underline {\phi })), u_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\), the system of the differential Eqs. 22313233 and 35 with \(F(\underline {\phi })= 0\), \(\{G_{i}(\underline {\phi })= 0\}_{i = 1}^{n}\), and the initial conditions in (i) and (ii) yields \(\{E_{i}, J_{i}, x^{*}_{i}, G_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\) and F.

  • (iv) The terminal condition \(F(\overline {\phi })= 1\) determines \(\overline {\phi }\).

  • (v) Given \(\{x^{*}_{i}, G_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\) and \([\underline {\phi }, \overline {\phi }]\), (25) and (27) jointly restore \(\{u_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\).

  • (vi) Given \(\{E_{i}, J_{i}, x^{*}_{i}, G_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\) and \([\underline {\phi }, \overline {\phi }]\), (13) restores \(\{U_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\).

One advantage of this alternative prescription is that it pins down the fixed point problem in a functional space into the fixed point problem in a finite dimensional vector space. In particular, if I assume n number of different types, I need to solve for the system of 4 × n differential equations in (iii). Note that \(x^{*}_{n}= 0\) reduces one equation, but F requires one more equation. From (i), (ii) and (iii), I also have 4 × n initial conditions. Thus, I just need to solve for the fixed point of \(\{U_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\) in n dimensional vector space. The monotonicity condition and (12) should be checked to ensure the existence of the optimal decision. The existence of the equilibrium fixed point of \(\{U_{i}\}_{i = 1}^{n}\) is not proved analytically. Thus, the proof is replaced with the numerical examples.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Sim, SG., Huegerich, T. Employer Incentives for Providing Informal On-the-job Training in the Presence of On-the-job Search. J Labor Res 39, 22–40 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-018-9261-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s12122-018-9261-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation