Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Wage and employment determination in a dynamic insider–outsider model

  • Article
  • Published:
Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

In this paper, I develop a differential insider–outsider game in which a union of corporative incumbents chooses the wage of its members by taking into account the optimal employment policy of a firm that, in turn, is assumed to decide the number of outsiders to hire in a spot labour market. Under the assumption that incumbents cannot be fired and commit themselves to a given path of wages, I demonstrate that such a game displays an open-loop Stackelberg equilibrium in which the initial stock of insiders pins down the trajectories of incumbents, entrants and insider wages. Moreover, resorting to numerical simulations, I show that adjustments towards the steady-state equilibrium occur through asymmetric oscillations that mimic the decline of union membership and union wage premia observed in the US all over the last 20 years. In addition, I show that the model provides a positive relationship between the labour market power of the insider union and the impatience of the firm.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. In the same years, other prominent authors contributed to that theory. For example, Carruth and Oswald (1987) provided a model of union behaviour grounded on the distinction between insider and outsider workers and discussed some related macroeconomic implications such as the possibility that productivity improvements can feed into pure wage increases for insiders with no, or minor, effects on employment. Furthermore, Blanchard and Summers (1986) as well as Gottfries and Horn (1987) relied on insider–outsider relations to explain the strong persistence of unemployment observed in European countries during the 1980s.

  2. Recognizing the inherent dynamic of the insider–outsider hypothesis, a similar exercise is carried out by Vetter and Andersen (1994).

  3. Different OLG models in which the insider–outsider distinction is concerned are given by McCausland (1998) and Begg (1988).

  4. In Morin (2017), union members are either employed or unemployed. When contracting the wage, however, the union considers only the surplus of employed workers because their fallback utility is assumed to coincide with the welfare of unemployed individuals. Therefore, similarly to Huizinga and Schiantarelli (1992), the bargaining process proceeds by weighting the surplus of insiders and the one of the firm.

  5. An alternative hypothesis could be to assume that workers who do not become unionized remain employed without the benefits of union membership. The exploration of that assumption under which outsiders become a distinct state variable in addition to the stock of insiders is left to future developments.

  6. As argued by Drazen and Gottfries (1990), one may think of a union which organizes an industry and that is large relative to firms in that industry. Delacroix (2006) defines a union with the features assumed in this paper as ‘monolithic’.

  7. The hypothesis that the union imposes an identical wage for all the insider workers can be motivated by the broad literature documenting that unions tend to compress the distribution of wages (cf. Alvarez and Shimer 2014; Krusell and Rudanko 2016).

  8. The only thing to notice about Proposition 2 is that when the union does not care about its membership, i.e. when \(\beta \rightarrow 0\), the stationary solution for the insider wage cannot be determined.

  9. Along these lines, it is worth noting that higher (lower) values of m lead to an increase (reduction) of the equilibrium unionization rate.

  10. The quadratic production function of the firm and the log-linear preferences of the union rule out the possibility of limit cycles.

  11. A similar value for the discount rate is also used in the continuous-time union model set forth by Alvarez and Shimer (2014).

  12. To have a trajectory for \(w_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) \) with positive values only, \(D_{a}\) and \(D_{b}\) are fixed to meet the transversality condition in Eq. (17) in a negative neighbourhood of 0.

References

  • Ackerberg DA, Caves K, Frazer G (2015) Identification properties of recent production function estimators. Econometrica 83(6):2411–2451

    Google Scholar 

  • Alvarez F, Shimer R (2014) Unions and unemployment. mimeo

  • Barron JM, Bishop J, Dunkelberg WC (1985) Employer search: the interviewing and hiring of new employees. Rev Econ Stat 67(1):43–52

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker GS (1983) A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quart J Econ 98(3):371–400

    Google Scholar 

  • Begg DKH, Lindbeck A, Martin C, Snower DJ (1989) Symmetric and asymmetric persistence of labor market shocks. J Jpn Int Econ 3(4):554–577

    Google Scholar 

  • Begg DKH (1988) Hysteresis, market forces, and the role of policy in a dynamic game with insiders and outsiders. Oxford Econ Papers 40(4):587–609

    Google Scholar 

  • Bertola G (1992) Labor turnover costs and average labor demand. J Labor Econ 10(4):389–411

    Google Scholar 

  • Binmore K, Rubinstein A, Wolinsky A (1986) The nash bargaining solution in economic modelling. RAND J Econ 17(2):176–188

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower DG, Bryson A (2004) The Union Wage Premium in the US and the UK. CEP Discussion Paper, No. 612

  • Blanchard O, Summers L (1986) Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. In: NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 1. MIT Press, Cambridge, pp 15–77

  • Booth A (1984) A public choice model of trade union behaviour and membership. Econ J 94(376):883–898

    Google Scholar 

  • Carruth AA, Oswald AJ (1987) On union preference and labour market models: insiders and outsiders. Econ J 97(386):431–445

    Google Scholar 

  • Coe DT, Snower DJ (1997) Policy complementarities: the case for fundamental labor market reform. Staff Paper Int Monet Found 44(1):1–35

    Google Scholar 

  • Cole HL, Rogerson R (1999) Can the Mortensen–Pissarides matching model match the business cycle? Int Econ Rev 40(4):933–959

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooper R, Willis JL (2009) The cost of labor adjustment: inferences from the gap. Rev Econ Dyn 12(4):632–647

    Google Scholar 

  • Delacroix A (2006) A multisectorial matching model of unions. J Monet Econ 53(3):573–596

    Google Scholar 

  • Dertouzos JN, Pencavel JH (1981) Wage and employment determination under trade unionism: the international typographical union. J Polit Econ 89(6):1162–1181

    Google Scholar 

  • Dockner EJ, Jorgensen S, Long NV, Sorger G (2000) Differential games in economics and management sciences. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dockner EJ, Feichtinger G (1991) On the optimality of limit cycles in dynamic economic games. J Econ 53(1):31–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Dockner EJ (1985) Local stability analysis in optimal control problems with two state variables. In: Feichtinger G (ed) Optimal control theory and economic analysis 2. North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp 89–103

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Virgillito ME (2019) Whither the evolution of the contemporary social fabric? New Technologies and Old Socio-Economic Trends. LEM Papers Series, No. 2019/02

    Google Scholar 

  • Drazen A, Gottfries N (1990) The persistence of unemployment in a dynamic insider–outsider model. In: Weiss Y, Fishelson G (eds) Advances in the theory and measurement of unemployment. Palgrave Macmillan, New York, pp 323–335

    Google Scholar 

  • Farber HS (1987) The analysis of union behavior. In: Ashenfelter O, Layard R (eds) Handbook of labor economics, vol 2, no 2, pp 1039–1089

  • Fukuda S, Owen RF (2008) Human capital and economic growth: dynamic implications of insider-outsider problem for macroeconomics. Public Policy Rev 4(1):133–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Gahan PG (2002) (What) do unions maximize? Evid Surv Data Cambridge J Econ 26(3):279–298

    Google Scholar 

  • Gali J (2016) Insider–outsider labor markets, hysteresis and monetary policy. Working paper of the department of economics and business, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, No. 1506

  • Giammarioli N (2003) Indeterminacy and search theory. European Central Bank Working Paper Series, No. 271

  • Gottfries N, Horn H (1987) Wage formation and the persistence of unemployment. Econ J 97(388):877–884

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrazzi M (2011) Wage bargaining as an optimal control problem: a dynamic version of the right-to-manage model. In: Optimal control applications and methods, vol 32, pp 609–622

    Google Scholar 

  • Guerrazzi M, Ksebi I (2019) Measuring unemployment by means of official data and administrative records. Quaderni di Economia del Lavoro—Labour Economics Papers (forthcoming)

  • Hamermesh DS (1995) Labour demand and the source of adjustment costs. Econ J 105(430):620–634

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirsh BT, Macpherson DA (2016) Union membership and coverage database from the current population survey. Available at www.unionstats.com

  • Huizinga F, Schiantarelli F (1992) Dynamics and asymmetric adjustment in insider–outsider models. Econ J 102(415):1451–1466

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones SRG, McKenna CJ (1994) A dynamic model of union membership and employment. Economica 61(242):179–189

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaufman BE (2002) Models of union wage determination: what have we learned since dunlop and ross. Ind Relat 41(1):110–158

    Google Scholar 

  • Kempt MC, Long NV, Shimomura K (1980) Cyclical and noncyclical redistributive taxation. Int Econ Rev 34(2):415–430

    Google Scholar 

  • Krusell P, Rudanko L (2016) Unions in a frictional labor market. J Monet Econ 80(2):35–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Kugler AD, Saint-Paul G (2000) Hiring and firing costs, adverse selection and long-term unemployment. IZA Discussion Paper, No. 134

  • Kydland FE, Prescott EC (1982) Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50(6):1345–1370

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (2002) The insider–outsider theory: a survey. IZA Discussion Paper, No. 534

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (1989) The insider–outsider theory of employment and unemployment. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (1988) Cooperation, harassment, and involuntary unemployment. Am Econ Rev 78(1):167–188

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (1987) Efficiency wages versus insiders and outsiders. Eur Econ Rev 31(1–2):407–416

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindbeck A, Snower DJ (1984) Involuntary unemployment as an insider–outsider dilemma. Seminar paper of the institute for international economic studies, No. 282

  • Long NV (1992) Pollution control: a differential game approach. Ann Oper Res 37(1):283–296

    Google Scholar 

  • Manzini P, Snower DJ (2002) Wage determination and the sources of bargaining power. IZA Discussion Paper, No. 535

  • McCausland WD (1998) Employment hysteresis in an overlapping-generations insider–outsider model. Aust Econ Papers 37(4):394–403

    Google Scholar 

  • Mattesini F, Rossi L (2009) Optimal monetary policy in economies with dual labor market. J Econ Dyn Control 33(7):1469–1489

    Google Scholar 

  • Mattesini F, Rossi L (2008) Productivity shocks and optimal monetary policy in a unionized labor market economy. Manchest School 76(5):578–611

    Google Scholar 

  • Morin A (2017) Cyclicality of wages and union power. Lab Econ 48(7):1–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Nair-Reichert U (2000) R&D investment and import competition in unionized industries. Appl Econ Lett 8(10):669–674

    Google Scholar 

  • Oi WY (1962) Labor as a quasi-fixed factor. J Polit Econ 70(6):538–555

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne MJ, Rubinstein A (1990) Bargaining and markets. Academic Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Pencavel JH (1985) Wages and employment under trade unionism: microeconomic models and macroeconomic applications. Scand J Econ 87(2):197–225

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanfey PJ (1995) Insider and outsiders in union models. J Econ Surveys 9(3):255–284

    Google Scholar 

  • Shimer R (2005) The cyclical behavior of equilibrium unemployment and vacancies. Am Econ Rev 95(1):25–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow RM (1985) Insiders and outsiders in wage determination. Scand J Econ 87(2):411–428

    Google Scholar 

  • Stemp PJ, Herbert RC (2006) Solving non-linear models with saddle path instability. Comput Econ 28(2):211–231

    Google Scholar 

  • Trigari A (2006) The role of search frictions and bargaining for inflation dynamics. IGIER Working Paper, No. 304

  • van Vliet O, Caminada K (2012) Unemployment replacement rates dataset among 34 welfare states: 1971–2009. Neujobs Report, No. 2

  • Vetter H, Andersen TM (1994) Do turnover costs protect insiders? Econ J 104(442):124–130

    Google Scholar 

  • Zanetti F (2007) A non-Walrasian labor market in a monetary model of the business cycle. J Econ Dyn Control 31(7):2413–2437

    Google Scholar 

  • Zanetti F (2006) Labor market frictions, indeterminacy, and interest rate rules. J Money Credit Bank 38(7):1959–1970

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marco Guerrazzi.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of interest

The corresponding author states that there is no conflict of interest.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

The author would like to thank the participants from the 10th NED Conference (Pisa, 2017) for their helpful comments and suggestions on a previous draft of the paper. The author also thank two anonymous referees of this journal for their insightful and encouraging comments. The usual disclaimers apply.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary file1 (XLS 40 kb)

Appendix: Controllability of the firm problem

Appendix: Controllability of the firm problem

Consider the first two differential equations of the dynamic system in (14). They read as

$$\begin{aligned} \overset{\cdot }{L}_{\text {I}}\left( t\right)= & {} m\frac{A\phi -w_{\text {E}}+m\Lambda \left( t\right) }{\alpha +h}-bL_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) \nonumber \\ \overset{\cdot }{\Lambda }\left( t\right)= & {} \Lambda \left( t\right) \left( b+\rho _{{\text {F}}}\right) -A+\alpha L_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) -\frac{1-\beta }{\Psi \left( t\right) }. \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Taking into account Eq. (10), the system of autonomous differential equations in (A.1) can be written as the following linear time-invariant (LTI) system that describes the solution of the firm problem:

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \begin{array}{c} \overset{\cdot }{L}_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) \\ \overset{\cdot }{\Lambda }\left( t\right) \end{array} \right) =\left( \begin{array}{c} \frac{m\left( A\phi -w_{\text {E}}\right) }{\alpha +h}\\ -A \end{array} \right) +\left[ \begin{array}{cc} -b &{} \frac{m^{2}}{\alpha +h}\\ \alpha &{} b+\rho _{{\text {F}}} \end{array} \right] \left( \begin{array}{c} L_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) \\ \Lambda \left( t\right) \end{array} \right) +\left( \begin{array}{c} 0\\ -1 \end{array} \right) w_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) , \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

where \(w_{\text {I}}\left( t\right) \) is the control of the union.

The controllability matrix of the LTI system in (A.2) is given by

$$\begin{aligned} H_{2\times 2}=\left[ \begin{array}{cc} 0 &{} -\frac{m^{2}}{\alpha +h}\\ -1 &{} -\left( b+\rho _{{\text {F}}}\right) \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

Since H has full rank, i.e. \(rank\left( H\right) =2\), the problem of the firm is controllable by the union.

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Guerrazzi, M. Wage and employment determination in a dynamic insider–outsider model. Evolut Inst Econ Rev 17, 1–23 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-019-00158-w

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s40844-019-00158-w

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation