Skip to main content
Log in

Dynamic Pricing of New Products in Competitive Markets: A Mean-Field Game Approach

  • Published:
Dynamic Games and Applications Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Dynamic pricing of new products has been extensively studied in monopolistic and oligopolistic markets. But, the optimal control and differential game tools used to investigate pricing behavior on markets with a number of firms are not well-suited to model competitive markets with a large number of firms. Using a mean-field game approach, this article develops a setting where numerous firms optimize prices for a new product. We analyze a framework à la Bass with product diffusion and experience effects. The analytical contribution of the paper is to prove the existence and uniqueness of a mean-field game equilibrium, further characterized in terms of mean tendencies and market heterogeneity. We also demonstrate the possible emergence of one or more groups of firms with regards to their pricing strategy. Numerical simulations illustrate how differences in firm experience translate into market heterogeneity in sales and profits. We show that, on a market where the absolute price effect is stronger than the relative price effect, we observe the emergence of two groups of firms, characterized by different prices, sales, and profits. Heterogeneity in firms’ prices and profits is thus compatible with competitive markets.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Weintraub et al. [82, p. 1377] affirm that “most industries contain more than 20 firms, but it would require more than 20 million gigabytes of computer memory to store the policy function for an industry with just 20 firms and 40 states.”

  2. Technically, an MFG equilibrium approximates a Nash equilibrium with a finite but large number of players. The approximation process is the following. First is the optimization of the game with a finite number of players; second is the passage to the limit. Note that the steps are not commutative.

  3. Technically, modeling rational anticipation is achieved with the forward/backward structure of the mean-field game.

  4. Stochastic analyses are also frequent in the dynamic pricing literature [15, 16, 36, 71, 72]. A difference between the deterministic and stochastic analyses is that the deterministic setting gives information about the mean tendencies, while the stochastic setting also provides information about the deviations from the mean. While the main results are expected to be similar in the two settings, the stochastic approach complexifies the analysis which is already computationally complex with MFG.

  5. Note that inequality \({\overline{X}}_t \le N_0\) is only true in average and does not imply \(x_t \le N_0\). This means that a particular firm may sell more than \(N_0\) units. However, if some firms sell more than \(N_0\), some other firms sell necessarily less to compensate at market level.

  6. The reciprocal is also true: given the price distribution \(P_t\), if the price distribution \(p_t\) is optimal and any moment of \(p_t\) and \(P_t\) coincide, then we have an equilibrium.

  7. Note that the condition of mean equality (i.e., \({\mathbb E}[p_t]={\mathbb E}[P_t]\)) is necessary for the equilibrium, but not sufficient. If only the means coincide one cannot conclude to a MFG equilibrium because this condition alone does not ensure that the distribution \(P_t\) of prices observed on the market coincides with the distribution \(p_t\) of prices announced by the firms.

  8. A more general formulation of the type \(\mathrm{d}x_t/\mathrm{d}t = h(x_t,p_t;\mu _t ,P_t )\) is also possible. It corresponds to the case where the firms have more information about the mean-field distributions of cumulative demands and prices.

  9. See the official interest rates of the European Central Bank. www.ecb.europa.eu/stats/policy_and_exchange_rates/key_ecb_interest_rates/html/index.en.html.

  10. Indeed, when the price of each firm is a time-dependent curve, the difficulty comes from the fact that the MFG will be a Nash equilibrium between an infinity of curves (whose mean values \({\overline{X}}_t\) and \({\overline{P}}_t\) represent the mean-fields). The following fixed point procedure is used: Starting with the mean-fields \({\overline{X}}_t\) and \({\overline{P}}_t\), we compute the (optimal) price of any firm through the critical point equations. By averaging, we obtain the novel mean-fields which should coincide with the initial datum \({\overline{X}}_t\) and \({\overline{P}}_t\). The result by Kakutani–Glicksberg–Fan guarantees that a fixed point exists if the space of curves is regular enough (the required mathematical concept is the compactness).

  11. A log-normal (or Gibrat) distribution accounts for the multiplicative product of numerous independent and identically distributed variables, which are additive on a log scale.

  12. The definition of the mapping \({\mathscr {E}}\) appears in the proof of point 1 from Theorem 5.6 in “Appendix B”.

  13. Recall that \(\Pi ^\dagger (x_0):=J^*(x_0,Z^\dagger )\), with \(J^*\) defined in Eq. (B.6) in “Appendix B.”

Abbreviations

t :

Time

\(p_{t}\) :

Price of the firm at time t (decision variable)

\(x_t\) :

Cumulative demand of the firm at time t (state variable)

\(x^{\tau ,y}_t\) :

Cumulative demand at time t of the firm with cumulative demand y at time \(\tau \)

\(\mathrm{d}x_t/\mathrm{d}t\) :

Current demand of the firm at time t

\(X_t\) :

The variable capturing the distribution of cumulative demands of all firms at time t

\(P_t\) :

The variable capturing the distribution of prices of all firms at time t

\({\overline{X}}_t\) :

Average (mean-field) market cumulative demand at time t

\({\overline{P}}_t\) :

Average (mean-field) market price at time t

r :

Discount rate

c(.):

Unit production cost

\(\Pi (.)\) :

Profit of the firm

\(^*\) :

Superscript notation for the optimal strategy

\(^\dagger \) :

Superscript notation for the equilibrium

\(N_0\) :

Average market potential per firm

References

  1. Adlakha S, Johari R (2013) Mean field equilibrium in dynamic games with strategic complementarities. Oper Res 61(4):971–989

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  2. Adlakha S, Johari R, Weintraub GY (2015) Equilibria of dynamic games with many players: existence, approximation, and market structure. J Econ Theory 156:269–316

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  3. Alasseur C, Taher IB, Matoussi A (2020) An extended mean field game for storage in smart grids. J Optim Theory Appl 184(2):644–670

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  4. Babonneau F, Foguen R, Haurie A, Malhamé R (2020) Coupling a power dispatch model with a wardrop or mean-field-game equilibrium model. In: Haurie A, Zaccour G (eds) Dynamic games and applications. Springer, Berlin, pp 1–25

    Google Scholar 

  5. Bardi M, Capuzzo-Dolcetta I (1997) Optimal control and viscosity solutions of Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equations. Systems and control: foundations and applications. Birkhäuser, Boston. With appendices by Maurizio Falcone and Pierpaolo Soravia

  6. Bass F (1969) A new product growth for model consumer durables. Manag Sci 15(5):215–227

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  7. Bensoussan A, Frehse J, Yam P et al (2013) Mean field games and mean field type control theory, vol 101. Springer, Berlin

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  8. Bressan A, Piccoli B (2007) Introduction to the mathematical theory of control. Volume 2 of AIMS series on applied mathematics. American Institute of Mathematical Sciences (AIMS), Springfield

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  9. Calvano E, Calzolari G, Denicolò V, Pastorello S (2019) Algorithmic pricing what implications for competition policy? Rev Ind Organ 55(1):155–171

    Article  Google Scholar 

  10. Carmona R, Delarue F (2017, 2018) Probabilistic theory of mean field games with applications I–II. Springer, Berlin

  11. Chan P, Sircar R (2015) Bertrand and Cournot mean field games. Appl Math Optim 71(3):533–569

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  12. Chan P, Sircar R (2017) Fracking, renewables, and mean field games. SIAM Rev 59(3):588–615

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Chatterjee R (2009) Strategic pricing of new product and services. In: Rao V (ed) Handbook of pricing research in marketing. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, pp 169–215

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  14. Chen M, Chen Z-L (2015) Recent developments in dynamic pricing research: multiple products, competition, and limited demand information. Prod Oper Manag 24(5):704–731

    Article  Google Scholar 

  15. Chen X, Hu P, Shum S, Zhang Y (2016) Dynamic stochastic inventory management with reference price effects. Oper Res 64(6):1529–1536

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  16. Chen X, Hu Z-Y, Zhang Y-H (2019) Dynamic pricing with stochastic reference price effect. J Oper Res Soc China 7(1):107–125

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  17. Chen Y-M, Jain DC (1992) Dynamic monopoly pricing under a Poisson-type uncertain demand. J Bus 65(4):593–614

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Chenavaz R (2012) Dynamic pricing, product and process innovation. Eur J Oper Res 222(3):553–557

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  19. Chenavaz R (2017) Better product quality may lead to lower product price. BE J Theor Econ 17(1):1–22

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  20. Chenavaz R, Drouard J, Escobar OR, Karoubi B (2018) Convenience pricing in online retailing: evidence from Amazon.com. Econ Model 70:127–139

    Article  Google Scholar 

  21. Chenavaz R, Paraschiv C (2018) Dynamic pricing for inventories with reference price effects. Econ Open Access Open Assess E J 12(2018–64):1–16

    Google Scholar 

  22. Chenavaz RY, Feichtinger G, Hartl RF, Kort PM (2020) Modeling the impact of product quality on dynamic pricing and advertising policies. Eur J Op Res 284(3):990–1001

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  23. Chutani A, Sethi SP (2012) Optimal advertising and pricing in a dynamic durable goods supply chain. J Optim Theory Appl 154(2):615–643

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  24. Clarke FH, Darrough MN, Heineke JM (1982) Optimal pricing policy in the presence of experience effects. J Bus 55(4):517–530

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Couillet R, Perlaza SM, Tembine H, Debbah M (2012) Electrical vehicles in the smart grid: a mean field game analysis. IEEE J Sel Areas Commun 30(6):1086–1096

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Crandall MG, Lions P-L (1983) Viscosity solutions of Hamilton–Jacobi equations. Trans Amer Math Soc 277(1):1–42

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  27. Danaher PJ, Hardie BG, Putsis WP Jr (2001) Marketing-mix variables and the diffusion of successive generations of a technological innovation. J Mark Res 38(4):501–514

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Delarue F, Lacker D, Ramanan K (2019) From the master equation to mean field game limit theory: a central limit theorem. Electron J Probab 24(51):1–54

    MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  29. Den Boer AV (2015a) Dynamic pricing and learning: historical origins, current research, and new directions. Surv Oper Res Manag Sci 20(1):1–18

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  30. Den Boer AV (2015b) Tracking the market: dynamic pricing and learning in a changing environment. Eur J Oper Res 247(3):914–927

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  31. Dockner E, Jørgensen S (1988) Optimal pricing strategies for new products in dynamic oligopolies. Mark Sci 7(4):315–334

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Dockner E, Jorgenssen S, Long VN, Gerhard S (2000) Differential games in economics and management science. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  33. Fruchter G (2009) Signaling quality: dynamic price-advertising model. J Optim Theory Appl 143(3):479–496

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  34. Fruchter GE, Van den Bulte C (2011) Why the generalized Bass model leads to odd optimal advertising policies. Int J Res Mark 28(3):218–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  35. Fudenberg D, Tirole J (1991) Game theory. MIT Press, Cambridge

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  36. Gallego G, Van Ryzin G (1994) Optimal dynamic pricing of inventories with stochastic demand over finite horizons. Manag Sci 40(8):999–1020

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  37. Gini C (1921) Measurement of inequality of income. Econ J 31:22–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  38. Gomes D, J. a. Saúde, (2014) Mean field games models a brief survey. Dyn Games Appl 4(2):110–154

  39. Gomes DA, Saúde J (2020) A mean-field game approach to price formation. Dyn Games Appl. https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-020-00348-x

  40. Guéant O, Lasry J-M, Lions P-L (2011) Mean field games and applications. In: Carmona R, Çınlar E, Ekeland I, Jouini E, Scheinkman JA, Touzi N (eds) Paris-Princeton lectures on mathematical finance 2010. Springer, Berlin, pp 205–266

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  41. Gutierrez GJ, He X (2011) Life-cycle channel coordination issues in launching an innovative durable product. Prod Oper Manag 20(2):268–279

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Helmes K, Schlosser R (2015) Oligopoly pricing and advertising in isoelastic adoption models. Dyn Games Appl 5(3):334–360

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  43. Helmes K, Schlosser R, Weber M (2013) Optimal advertising and pricing in a class of general new-product adoption models. Eur J Oper Res 229(2):433–443

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  44. Huang M, Caines PE, Malhamé RP (2007) Large-population cost-coupled LQG problems with nonuniform agents: individual-mass behavior and decentralized \(\varepsilon \)-Nash equilibria. IEEE Trans Autom Control 52(9):1560–1571

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  45. Huang M, Malhamé RP, Caines PE (2005) Nash equilibria for large-population linear stochastic systems of weakly coupled agents. In: Boukas El-Kébir, Malhamé Roland P (eds) Analysis, control and optimization of complex dynamic systems. Springer, Berlin, pp 215–252

    Chapter  MATH  Google Scholar 

  46. Huang M, Malhamé RP, Caines PE et al (2006) Large population stochastic dynamic games: closed-loop McKean–Vlasov systems and the Nash certainty equivalence principle. Commun Inform Syst 6(3):221–252

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  47. Iyer K, Johari R, Sundararajan M (2014) Mean field equilibria of dynamic auctions with learning. Manag Sci 60(12):2949–2970

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Jeong M, Kim B-I, Gang K (2017) Competition, product line length, and firm survival: evidence from the US printer industry. Technol Anal Strateg Manag 29(7):762–774

    Article  Google Scholar 

  49. Jiang Z, Jain DC (2012) A generalized Norton–Bass model for multigeneration diffusion. Manag Sci 58(10):1887–1897

    Article  Google Scholar 

  50. Jing B (2011) Social learning and dynamic pricing of durable goods. Mark Sci 30(5):851–865

    Article  Google Scholar 

  51. Jorgensen S, Kort PM (2002) Autonomous and induced learning: an optimal control approach. Int J Technol Manag 23(7–8):655–674

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Jørgensen S, Kort PM, Zaccour G (1999) Production, inventory, and pricing under cost and demand learning effects. Eur J Oper Res 117(2):382–395

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  53. Jørgensen S, Zaccour G (2004) Differential games in marketing. Springer, Berlin

    Book  Google Scholar 

  54. Kalish S (1983) Monopolist pricing with dynamic demand and production cost. Mark Sci 2(2):135–159

    Article  Google Scholar 

  55. Karray S, Martín-Herrán G (2009) A dynamic model for advertising and pricing competition between national and store brands. Eur J Oper Res 193(2):451–467

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  56. Kiesling E, Günther M, Stummer C, Wakolbinger LM (2012) Agent-based simulation of innovation diffusion: a review. CEJOR 20(2):183–230

    Article  Google Scholar 

  57. Kizilkale AC, Salhab R, Malhamé RP (2019) An integral control formulation of mean field game based large scale coordination of loads in smart grids. Automatica 100:312–322

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  58. Kogan K, El Ouardighi F (2019) Autonomous and induced production learning under price and quality competition. Appl Math Model 67:74–84

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  59. Krishnan TV, Bass FM, Jain DC (1999) Optimal pricing strategy for new products. Manag Sci 45(12):1650–1663

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  60. Larsen J (2017) The making of a pro-cycling city: social practices and bicycle mobilities. Environ Plan A 49(4):876–892

    Article  Google Scholar 

  61. Lasry J-M, Lions P-L (2006a) Jeux à champ moyen. I: Le cas stationnaire. C R Math Acad Sci Paris 343(9):619–625

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  62. Lasry J-M, Lions P-L (2006b) Jeux à champ moyen. II: horizon fini et contrôle optimal. C R Math Acad Sci Paris 343(10):679–684

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  63. Lasry J-M, Lions P-L (2007) Mean field games. Jpn J Math 2(1):229–260

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  64. Leduc MV, Jackson MO, Johari R (2017) Pricing and referrals in diffusion on networks. Games Econ Behav 104:568–594

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  65. Li G, Rajagopalan S (1998) Process improvement, quality, and learning effects. Manag Sci 44(11–part–1):1517–1532

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  66. Lorenz MO (1905) Methods of measuring the concentration of wealth. Publ Am Stat Assoc 9(70):209–219

    Google Scholar 

  67. Moon J, Başar T (2019) Risk-sensitive mean field games via the stochastic maximum principle. Dyn Games Appl 9(4):1100–1125

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  68. Raman K, Chatterjee R (1995) Optimal monopolist pricing under demand uncertainty in dynamic markets. Manag Sci 41(1):144–162

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  69. Robinson B, Lakhani C (1975) Dynamic price models for new-product planning. Manag Sci 21(10):1113–1122

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  70. Rubel O (2013) Stochastic competitive entries and dynamic pricing. Eur J Oper Res 231(2):381–392

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  71. Schlosser R (2017) Stochastic dynamic pricing and advertising in isoelastic oligopoly models. Eur J Oper Res 259(3):1144–1155

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  72. Schlosser R (2020) Stochastic dynamic pricing with waiting and forward-looking consumers. Springer, Berlin, pp 1–23

    Google Scholar 

  73. Schmeidler D (1973) Equilibrium points of nonatomic games. J Stat Phys 7(4):295–300

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  74. Selcuk C, Gokpinar B (2018) Fixed versus flexible pricing in a competitive market. Manag Sci 64(12):5584–5598

    Article  Google Scholar 

  75. Shokri M, Kebriaei H (2018) Mean field optimal energy management of plug-in hybrid electric vehicles. IEEE Trans Veh Technol 68(1):113–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  76. Sultan F, Farley JU, Lehmann DR (1990) A meta-analysis of applications of diffusion models. J Mark Res 27(1):70–77

    Article  Google Scholar 

  77. Tchuendom RF, Malhamé R, Caines P (2019) A quantilized mean field game approach to energy pricing with application to fleets of plug-in electric vehicles. In: 2019 IEEE 58th conference on decision and control (CDC). IEEE, pp 299–304

  78. Vörös J (2006) The dynamics of price, quality and productivity improvement decisions. Eur J Oper Res 170(3):809–823

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  79. Vörös J (2019) An analysis of the dynamic price-quality relationship. Eur J Oper Res 277(3):1037–1045

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  80. Wang B, Huang M (2015) Dynamic production output adjustment with sticky prices: a mean field game approach. In: 2015 IEEE 54th annual conference on decision and control (CDC). IEEE, pp 4438–4443

  81. Wang B, Huang M (2019) Mean field production output control with sticky prices: nash and social solutions. Automatica 100:90–98

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  82. Weintraub GY, Benkard CL, Van Roy B (2008) Markov perfect industry dynamics with many firms. Econometrica 76(6):1375–1411

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  83. Wiszniewska-Matyszkiel A (2002) Static and dynamic equilibria in games with continuum of players. Positivity 6(4):433–453

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  84. Wiszniewska-Matyszkiel A (2014) Open and closed loop Nash equilibria in games with a continuum of players. J Optim Theory Appl 160(1):280–301

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  85. Xie J, Sirbu M (1995) Price competition and compatibility in the presence of positive demand externalities. Manag Sci 41(5):909–926

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  86. Yang J, Xia Y (2013) A nonatomic-game approach to dynamic pricing under competition. Prod Oper Manag 22(1):88–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Régis Chenavaz.

Additional information

Publisher's Note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Appendices

Appendix A: Proof of Lemma 5.4

Proof

General considerations When the overall dynamics \({\overline{X}}_t\) and \({\overline{P}}_t\) is given, the situation enters, formally, the setting of Kalish [54, bottom of page 141] and Clarke et al. [24, Proposition 2 page 523]. Consider the function

$$\begin{aligned} p \in {\mathbb R}_+ \mapsto {\mathscr {L}}(p) = p + \frac{g(p)}{g'(p)}. \end{aligned}$$
(A.1)

Since \({\mathscr {L}}'(p)= 2- \frac{g(p) g''(p)}{(g'(p))^2}\) and hypothesis (H1) holds, we obtain \({\mathscr {L}}'(p)>0\). \({\mathscr {L}}\) is thus a strictly increasing function. Its image is \([\frac{g(0)}{g'(0)},\infty [\). Since \(g\ge 0\) and \(g'(p)\le 0\), we get \(\frac{g(0)}{g'(0)} \le 0\). Thus, the image of \({\mathscr {L}}\) contains \({\mathbb R}_+\).

P

Proof of points 2 and 3

For \(r>0\), the optimum price \(p^*\) satisfies as in Kalish [54] and Clarke et al. [24]:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{d p^*_t}{\mathrm{d}t} \cdot {\mathscr {L}}'(p^*_t) < 0, \end{aligned}$$
(A.2)

which together with hypothesis (H1) provide the point 2 of the conclusion.

For \(r=0\), one obtains \(\frac{d p^*_t}{\mathrm{d}t} {\mathscr {L}}'(p^*_t) =0\) thus \(p^*_t\) is constant (point 3 of the conclusion).

Proof of point 1

We introduce the Hamiltonian

$$\begin{aligned} H(t,p,\lambda ) = (p-c(x) + \lambda ) f({\overline{X}}_t,{\overline{P}}_t) g(p). \end{aligned}$$
(A.3)

The optimal price \(p^*\) will maximize H with respect to p when \(\lambda \) is the adjoint state \(\lambda ^*\); recalling that at the optimal solution, \(\lambda ^*(t) = \partial _x \Pi ^*(t,x_t)\).

With the market conditions given, the maximization of (A.3) is related to the maximization of \(p \mapsto (p-\beta )g(p)\) (with the particular case of interest \(\beta =c(x) -\lambda \)). Its derivative is \(g(p) + (p-\beta )g'(p)\) which is positive when \(\beta \ge {\mathscr {L}}(p) \) or, equivalently, \( {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}(\beta ) \ge p\) (for \(\beta \) in the domain of \({\mathscr {L}}\)). Thus \((p-\beta )g(p)\) increases and then decreases; it has a unique maximum attained at \({\mathscr {L}}^{-1}(\beta )\). Going back to the maximization of Eq. (A.3) it results that the optimal price satisfies \(p^*_t = {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}(c(x_t) - \lambda _t ) = {\mathscr {L}}^{-1} \left( c(x_t) - \partial _x \Pi ^*(t,x_t) \right) \), which shows that the optimal price is unique when \(\Pi ^*(t,x)\) is differentiable with respect to x everywhere (and not necessarily so otherwise).

Proof of point 4

Intuitively the profit \(\Pi ^*\) is increasing with respect to x because a firm with higher initial sales can use the same strategy as a firm with lower initial sales, but its cost will be lower, which allows for higher profit. The rigorous transcription of this idea is as follows: consider two firms with initial sales \(x_0^1\) and \(x_0^2\), with \(x_0^1 \le x_0^2\), p some pricing strategy as in (3.3) and \(x^{\tau ,x_0^1}_t\) and \(x^{\tau ,x_0^2}_t\) the sales of the firms using the strategy p. Then \(\frac{d}{\mathrm{d}t}x^{\tau ,x_0^2}_t = \frac{d}{\mathrm{d}t} x^{\tau ,x_0^1}_t\) and thus \(x^{\tau ,x_0^2}_t \ge x^{\tau ,x_0^1}_t\) for any \(t\ge \tau \) which shows that \(c(x^{\tau ,x_0^2}_t) \le c(x^{\tau ,x_0^1}_t)\) for any \(t\ge \tau \). But then, recalling definition (4.3), \(\Pi (\tau ,x_0^2,p) \ge \Pi (\tau ,x_0^1,p) \). Taking now the supremum with respect to p and using (3.3) it follows that

$$\begin{aligned} \Pi ^*(\tau ,x_0^2) = \sup _{p} \Pi (\tau ,x_0^2,p) \ge \sup _{p} \Pi (\tau ,x_0^1,p) = \Pi ^*(\tau ,x_0^1), \end{aligned}$$
(A.4)

proving the first part of point 4.

Denote \({\mathscr {H}}(\beta )= \max _{p\ge 0} (p-\beta ) g(p)\). The optimal profit \(\Pi ^*\) is the unique viscosity solution (see Crandall and Lions [26], Bressan and Piccoli [8] and Bardi and Capuzzo-Dolcetta [5] for more details) of the following Hamilton–Jacobi–Bellman equation:

$$\begin{aligned}&\partial _{t} \Pi ^*(t,x) + \mathscr {H} \left( c(x) - \partial _x \Pi ^*(t,x) \right) f({\overline{X}}_t,{\overline{P}}_t) - r \Pi ^*(t,x) = 0 \ \end{aligned}$$
(A.5)
$$\begin{aligned}&\Pi ^*(\infty ,x)=0. \end{aligned}$$
(A.6)

In addition, at any point \(x_t\) where \(\partial _x \Pi ^*(t,x_t)\) exists the optimal price \(p^*_t\) of a firm with cumulative sales \(x_t\) at time t only depends on t and \(x_t\) and satisfies:

$$\begin{aligned} p^*_t= {\mathscr {L}}^{-1} \left( c(x_t) - \partial _x \Pi ^*(t,x_t) \right) \le {\mathscr {L}}^{-1} \left( c(x_t) \right) \le {\mathscr {L}}^{-1} \left( c(x_0) \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(A.7)

Thus, hypothesis (H2) and (H3) allow bounding the profit for \(x_0\rightarrow \infty \). For \(x_0 \rightarrow 0\) the optimal price can be unbound (since \(c(x_0)\) may tend to \(\infty \) for \(x_0\rightarrow 0\)) but the profit will certainly be finite (being inferior to any profit for fixed \(x_0 > 0\)), which proves the second part of point 4 of the conclusion. \(\square \)

Appendix B: Proof of Theorem 5.6

Proof

General considerations

Point 3 of Lemma 5.4 gives that for \(r=0\), the optimal price \(p^*\) of a representative firm is constant. Given \({\overline{X}}_t\), \({\overline{P}}_t\) (not necessarily at equilibrium) the (constant) optimal price \(p^*\) of a firm maximizes the profit [obtained from Eq. (4.3) with p constant using (4.1)] :

$$\begin{aligned} \int _0^\infty (p -c(x_t))\frac{d x_t}{\mathrm{d}t} \mathrm{d}t = p \cdot (x_\infty - x_0) - [ I_c(x_\infty )-I_c(x_0)], \end{aligned}$$
(B.1)

where \(I_c(\cdot )\) refers to a primitive of the cost function c; that is, \(I_c'(y)= c(y)\), for any \(y> 0\).

Using the definition of \(Z=Z_{{\overline{X}}_t,{\overline{P}}_t}\), which is fixed and integrating (4.1) with respect to time, yields \(x_\infty = x_0 + Z g(p)\). To determine the optimal price \(p^*=p^{Z,*}(x_0) \) that maximizes Eq. (B.1), we define the profit function J:

$$\begin{aligned} J(p;x_0,Z):= p Z g(p) - [ I_c(x_0 + Z g(p))-I_c(x_0)]. \end{aligned}$$
(B.2)

Note that J is increasing with respect to \(x_0\). By differentiating J with respect to p, we obtain \( Z(p^*g'(p^*)+ g(p^*)) = c(x_0 + Z g(p^*)) Z g'(p^*)\). Divide now both terms by \(Z g'(p^*)\), to obtain \(p^*+ g(p^*)/g'(p^*) = c(x_0 + Z g(p^*))\), which can also be written as \({\mathscr {L}}(p^*)= c(x_0 + Z g(p^*))\). Hence, after inverting the function \({\mathscr {L}}\) and indicating the explicit dependence on \(x_0\), we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned} p^{Z,*}(x_0) = {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}\left[ c(x_0 + Z g(p^{Z,*}(x_0))) \right] \le {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}\left( c(x_0 )\right) . \end{aligned}$$
(B.3)

Note that at this time \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is not necessarily unique. However, we can show that \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is decreasing with respect to \(x_0\); indeed consider \(x_0^1 < x_0^2\). The optimum price being constant means that we must have for any \(t \ge 0\)

$$\begin{aligned} x_t^{x_0^1,*} < x_t^{x_0^2,*}. \end{aligned}$$
(B.4)

Otherwise, some point \(\bar{t}\) exists with \(x_{\bar{t}}^{x_0^1,*} = x_{\bar{t}}^{x_0^2,*}\), and thus, a non-constant price can be constructed that is optimal for the firm starting in \(x_0^2\). However, (B.4) implies \(x_\infty ^{x_0^1,*} \le x_\infty ^{x_0^2,*}\), which also implies

$$\begin{aligned} p^{Z,*}(x_0^1) = {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}\left[ c(x_\infty ^{x_0^1,*}) \right] \ge {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}\left[ c(x_\infty ^{x_0^2,*}) \right] = p^{Z,*}(x_0^2). \end{aligned}$$
(B.5)

A closer analysis reveals that \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is in fact strictly monotonic. Thus \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is strictly decreasing with respect to \(x_0\), has left and right limits (which are optimums) and any other (optimal) value is between these limits.

On the other hand, the function

$$\begin{aligned} (x_0,Z) \mapsto J^*(x_0,Z)=\sup _{p \ge 0} J(p,x_0,Z), \end{aligned}$$
(B.6)

is Lipschitz thus differentiable almost everywhere with respect to \(x_0\); in any point of differentiability of \(J^*(x_0,Z)\) we have that \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is uniquely given by [compare with formula (A.7)]

$$\begin{aligned} p^{Z,*}(x_0)= {\mathscr {L}}^{-1}\left[ c(x_0) - \partial _{x_0} J^*(x_0,Z) \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(B.7)

Let us now inquire about the variation of \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) with respect to Z: consider \(Z_2 > Z_1\) and the optimal dynamics \(x_t^{x_0,*}\) of a firm starting in \(x_0\); at time \(t=0\) the price \(p^{Z_2,*}(x_0)\) represents a maximum of the profit \(J(x_0,Z_2=\int _0^\infty f({\overline{X}}_t,{\overline{P}}_t) \mathrm{d}t,p)\) with respect to p, while at a later time \(t\ge 0\) it will also be an optimum of \(J(x_0,\int _t^\infty f({\overline{X}}_t,{\overline{P}}_t) \mathrm{d}t,p)\). Choosing the time t for which \(Z_1= \int _t^\infty f({\overline{X}}_t,{\overline{P}}_t) \mathrm{d}t\) we obtain \(p^{Z_2,*}(x_0) = p^{Z_1,*}(x_t^{x_0}) < p^{Z_1,*}(x_0)\), where we used the monotonicity of \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) with respect to \(x_0\); thus, we obtain that \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is strictly decreasing with respect to Z.

In summary, \(x_0 \mapsto p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) is strictly decreasing; thus, although it is not continuous, the set of discountinuity points is at most countable. The same holds for \(Z \mapsto p^{Z,*}(x_0)\).

To avoid lengthy technical developments, we will only present the reminder of the proof for the situation when \(\mu _0\) admits a density \(\rho _0(x_0)\), i.e., \(\mu _0 = \rho _0(x_0) d x_0\).

When \(\mu _0\) does not admit a density, then it may occur that for a set A (with \(\mu _0(A)> 0\)) of firms \(\omega \in A\), the price p is not necessarily unique, which means that two firms starting from the same \(x_0\) can choose different prices. In mathematical terms, p depends not only on the cumulative sales \(X_0(\omega )\) of the firm \(\omega \) but also on the firm \(\omega \) itself: \(p=p(\omega ,X_0(\omega ))\); in this case \({\mathscr {E}}(\cdot )\) is a set-valued map and the proof has to use more general fixed point theorems (see Remark 5.10).

Moreover, to avoid degenerate settings, we also assume that the cost function \(c(\cdot )\) is always strictly positive.

Proof of point 2a

Since each firm has constant optimal price, the equilibrium mean price \({\overline{P}}^\dagger _t\) will also be constant:

$$\begin{aligned} {\overline{P}}^\dagger _t = {\mathbb E}\left[ P^\dagger _t \right] = {\mathbb E}\left[ P^\dagger _0 \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(B.8)

In addition, hypothesis (H4) ensures that \({\overline{X}}^\dagger _t \in [0,N_0]\) and \({\overline{X}}^\dagger _t\rightarrow N_0\) for \(t\rightarrow \infty \).P

Proof of point 1

The proof of existence relies on the remark that to each possible \({\overline{X}}_t\) and \({\overline{P}}_t\) a number Z corresponds. We will find the Z that gives an equilibrium. Note first that any equilibrium Z can be bounded by some universal constant \(Z_{max}^{\mu _0} := \frac{N_0- {\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g({\mathscr {L}}^{-1}\left( c(X_0 )\right) ) \right] }\); thus, it is enough to look for an equilibrium in the interval \([0, Z_{max}^{\mu _0}]\). Let \(Z \in [0, Z_{max}^{\mu _0}]\); then one can associate to it the optimal price \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) maximizing \(J(p,x_0,Z)\) (with respect to p). This price is unique for almost all \(x_0\); for \(Z_n \rightarrow Z\) any accumulation point of \(\{ p^{Z_n,*}(x_0), n\ge 1 \}\) is necessarily an optimum for \(J(p,x_0,Z)\), thus by uniqueness \(p^{Z,*}(x_0) = \lim \limits _{n\rightarrow \infty } p^{Z_n,*}(x_0)\) a.e. in \(x_0\). The mapping \(Z \in [0, Z_{max}^{\mu _0}] \mapsto {\mathscr {E}}(Z) = \frac{N_0-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(p^{Z,*}(X_0)) \right] } \in [0, Z_{max}^{\mu _0}]\) is thus well defined and continuous; it must have a fixed point (according to Brower’s theorem) that corresponds to an equilibrium.

Also note that \({\mathscr {E}}(Z) \ge \frac{N_0-{\overline{X}}_0}{g(0)} > 0\). The strict monotony of \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) with respect to Z implies that \({\mathscr {E}}(Z) \) is decreasing with respect to Z and thus the fixed point is unique.

Proof of point 2b

Now take \(Z^{\dagger }\) as the equilibrium value and \(p^\dagger (\cdot )= p^{Z^\dagger ,*}(\cdot )\); note that

$$\begin{aligned} x^{\dagger ,x_0}_t = x_0 + g(p^\dagger (x_0)) \frac{{\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(p^\dagger (X_0)) \right] }, \ X_t^\dagger = X_0 + g(P^\dagger _0) \frac{{\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(P^\dagger _0) \right] }. \end{aligned}$$
(B.9)

To prove that \({\mathbb V}(X_t)\) is increasing with respect to t, we will use an alternative formula for the variance of a random variable Y:

$$\begin{aligned} {\mathbb V}(Y) = \frac{1}{2} \left\{ \int _{\Omega } \int _{\Omega } \Big [(Y(\omega _1)-Y(\omega _2) \Big ]^2 {\mathbb P}(d \omega _1) {\mathbb P}(d \omega _2) \right\} . \end{aligned}$$
(B.10)

Or, formula (B.9) and the monotonicity of \(p^{Z,*}(x_0)\) with respect to \(x_0\) show that for any \(y_1 = X_0(\omega _1),y_2=X_0(\omega _1) \ge 0\):

$$\begin{aligned} | X_t(\omega _1)-X_t(\omega _2) | = |x^{\dagger ,y_1}_t-x^{\dagger ,y_2}_t| \ge |y_1-y_2| = |X_0(\omega _1)-X_0(\omega _2) |, \end{aligned}$$
(B.11)

which implies, using (B.10), that \({\mathbb V}(X_t) \ge {\mathbb V}(X_0)\).

Proof of point 2c

We now analyze the past cumulative revenue \({\mathbb V}\left[ \int _{0}^{t} P^\dagger _s \dot{X}^\dagger _s ds \right] \). Recalling that with firm’s price being constant in time, the past cumulative revenue is simply \(P^\dagger _0(X_t^\dagger -X_0)\); equation (B.9) shows that \({\mathbb V}(P^\dagger _0(X_t^\dagger -X_0)) = {\mathbb V}\left[ P^\dagger _0 g(P^\dagger _0) \right] \frac{ ({\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0)^2}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(p^\dagger (X_0)) \right] ^2 }\) which is increasing because \({\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0\) is positive increasing. The conclusion on the Lorenz curve follows from the remark that cumulative revenue \(P^\dagger _0 (X^\dagger _t-X_0)\) is the product of a time-dependent real constant \({\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0\) and a time-independent random variable \( \frac{ P^\dagger _0 g(P^\dagger _0) }{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(P^\dagger _0) \right] }\).

Proof of point 2d

Recall that the Gini coefficient of a real variable B is

$$\begin{aligned} G_B = \frac{ \int _{\Omega } \int _{\Omega } |B(\omega _1)-B(\omega _2)| {\mathbb P}(d\omega _1) {\mathbb P}(d\omega _2) }{2{\mathbb E}\left[ B \right] }. \end{aligned}$$
(B.12)

Thus

$$\begin{aligned} G_{X_t^\dagger }= & {} \frac{ \int _{\Omega } \int _{\Omega } |X_t^\dagger (\omega _1)-X_t^\dagger (\omega _2)| {\mathbb P}(d\omega _1) {\mathbb P}(d\omega _2)}{2{\mathbb E}\left[ X_t \right] } \nonumber \\= & {} \frac{ \int _{\Omega } \int _{\Omega } \left| X_0^\dagger (\omega _1)-X_0^\dagger (\omega _2) + \left[ g(P^\dagger _0(\omega _1)) - g(P^\dagger (\omega _2)) \right] \frac{{\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(P^\dagger _0) \right] } \right| {\mathbb P}(d\omega _1) {\mathbb P}(d\omega _2)}{2{\mathbb E}\left[ X_t \right] }.\nonumber \\ \end{aligned}$$
(B.13)

But since \(y_1-y_2\) and \( g(p^\dagger (y_1)) -g(p^\dagger (y_2))\) have the same sign and \( \frac{{\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(P^\dagger _0) \right] } >0\) we obtain:

$$\begin{aligned}&\left| X_0^\dagger (\omega _1)-X_0^\dagger (\omega _2) + \left[ g(P^\dagger _0(\omega _1)) - g(P^\dagger (\omega _2)) \right] \frac{{\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(P^\dagger _0) \right] } \right| = \left| X_0^\dagger (\omega _1)-X_0^\dagger (\omega _2) \right| \nonumber \\&+ \left| g(P^\dagger _0(\omega _1)) - g(P^\dagger (\omega _2)) \right| \frac{{\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0}{ {\mathbb E}\left[ g(P^\dagger _0) \right] } \end{aligned}$$
(B.14)

and after some computations,

$$\begin{aligned} G_{X^\dagger _t} = \frac{{\mathbb E}\left[ X_0 \right] }{{\mathbb E}\left[ X^\dagger _t \right] } G_{X_0} + \left( 1- \frac{{\mathbb E}\left[ X_0 \right] }{{\mathbb E}\left[ X^\dagger _t \right] }\right) G_{g(P^\dagger _0)}, \end{aligned}$$
(B.15)

hence the conclusion follows. \(\square \)

Appendix C: Proof of Corollaries

Proof of Corollary 5.7

Proof

The proof of Corollary 5.7 uses the same arguments as those developed in “Appendix B” to prove that the variance of cumulative demand \({\mathbb V}(X_t^\dagger )\) increases over time (point 2b of Theorem 5.6). Formula (B.9) and the monotony of \({\overline{X}}^\dagger _t-{\overline{X}}_0\) and \({\overline{X}}^\dagger _\infty -{\overline{X}}_t^\dagger \), respectively guarantee that the variance of past cumulative demand \({\mathbb V}(X_t^\dagger -X_0)\) increases over time, while the variance of future cumulative demand \({\mathbb V}(X_\infty ^\dagger -X_t^\dagger )\) decreases over time. \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 5.8

Proof

The proof of Corollary 5.8 is similar to that of Point 3 of Theorem 5.6 in “Appendix B.” \(\square \)

Proof of Corollary 5.9

Proof

In the General considerations of the proof of Theorem 5.6, we shown that the optimal equilibrium price \(p^\dagger (x_0)\) is strictly decreasing with respect to \(x_0\), has left and right limits (which are optimums). The monotonicity of \(p^\dagger (\cdot )\) implies (by the Darboux–Froda theorem) that it can only have at most a countable number of discontinuities. Each such discontinuity corresponds to a non-differentiability point of \(\Pi ^\dagger (\cdot )\), which proves the claims of the Corollary. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Chenavaz, R., Paraschiv, C. & Turinici, G. Dynamic Pricing of New Products in Competitive Markets: A Mean-Field Game Approach. Dyn Games Appl 11, 463–490 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-020-00369-6

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13235-020-00369-6

Keywords

Navigation