Skip to main content
Log in

Econophysics: making sense of a chimera

  • Paper in History and Philosophy of Science
  • Published:
European Journal for Philosophy of Science Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The history of economic thought witnessed several prominent economists who took seriously models and concepts in physics for the elucidation and prediction of economic phenomena. Econophysics is an emerging discipline at the intersection of heterodox economics and the physics of complex systems, with practitioners typically engaged in two overlapping but distinct methodological programs. The first is to export mathematical methods used in physics for the purposes of studying economic phenomena. The second is to export mechanisms in physics into economics. A conclusion is drawn that physics transfer is often justified at the level of mathematical transfer but unjustified at the level of mechanistic transfer.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. I borrow this term from Boumans (1993) who described the attempts of physicist Paul Ehrenfest and the economist Jan Tinbergen to apply the formalism of Hamiltonians and the adiabatic method to business cycles analysis.

  2. See History of Political Economy (1993) Volume 25, Supplementary Issue 1 for further discussion.

  3. See Mirowski (1984) for more on physics transfer in the ‘Marginalist Revolution’ period of the latter half of the 19th-century.

  4. exp(x)’ refers to ex, where e is Euler’s number.

  5. Notice that this is not a Gaussian distribution.

  6. Cited in Sinha & Chakrabarti (2012, 46).

  7. Since at least as early as 2006, the University of Houston has launched the first PhD program in the United States for the study of econophysics. The East China University of Science and Technology also has a Research Center for Econophysics using methods from physics to understand high-frequency trading data (Yu & Li, 2010).

  8. The percentage of articles with the term ‘econophysics’ in Physica A began as low as 0% in 1996 and increased to highs of 18% in 2004 and 20% in 2007, with a modest upward trend between 1996 - 2009 (Jovanovic & Schinckus, 2013, 448).

  9. See Cockshott et al. (2009), section 7.1.1, for further discussion.

  10. Here, the symbol ‘∝’ is to be understood as ‘proportional to’.

  11. It is worth noting that Wilson was the PhD supervisor of Belal Baaquie, who is a notable contemporary econophysicist active in applying the mathematical formalisms, but not mechanisms, of quantum field theory for application in financial modelling (Baaquie, 2004, 2018). Baaquie’s work is nonetheless criticized at length in Arioli and Valente (2021) for misapplying several key formalisms.

  12. Here, the symbol ‘≈’ is to be understood as ‘approximates to’.

  13. This at least is the charitable interpretation of the JLS model. In the original paper, Johansen et al. (2000, 220) write: “The individual trader has only 3 possible actions (or “states”): selling, buying or waiting.” However, this would render their model strongly disanalogous to the physical systems they are inspired by, as the spin of ferromagnets in physical models have only two possible states (up and down).

  14. However, even on this point, Baaquie’s work has recently been criticized by Arioli and Valente (2021) for inappropriately applying quantum field theory’s mathematical formalism, specifically with respect to the usage of imaginary units in the Schrödinger equation, given that ‘interference phenomena’ do not exist in finance in the way this occurs in the quantum realm. And yet, these authors agree with my analysis that “what helps one justify the empirical success of quantum econophysics is just the fact that the applied models lose some of their characteristic quantum-mechanical components” (Arioli & Valente, 2021, 3).

  15. See chapter 5 of Jovanovic and Schinckus (2017) for further examples.

  16. See also Kincaid (2021) for a recent systematic overview of how diverse conceptions of mechanisms remain in economics and the social sciences.

  17. Two mainstream economists Smith & Foley (2008, 27) make a related criticism concerning attempts to relate economic utility to physical concepts: “The most direct way to understand why utility cannot be a counterpart to energy is to recognize that energy, along with volume or other conserved quantities, defines the surface of possible configurations of aggregated systems”.

  18. A family of related objections have been made toward mainstream neoclassical economics as well, specifically from the ‘critical realism’ school of social science (Lawson, 1997).

  19. I thank an anonymous referee for drawing my attention to this work.

  20. For example, see a recent institutional analysis in Volume 3, Issue 1 of the Journal of Financial Crises (2021) for a set of papers outlining in great detail how the Federal Reserve Bank of New York bailed out American International Group, Inc., one of the world’s largest insurance corporations which was brought to the brink of bankruptcy in the 2008 financial crisis.

  21. In this same paper, Cross further criticizes several prominent usages of time-irreversible mechanisms which have been appropriated from physics for usage in economics, such as hysteresis effects in electromagnetic phenomena and a purported analogy to international trade in the presence of exogenous shocks (Cross (1995), 130).

  22. For example, consider Irving Fisher’s well known false prediction in 1929 that the stock market would not crash (Sornette, 2003b, 13-14), when it did, or 1995 Nobel Memorial Prize winner Robert Lucas’s naive remark just prior to the 2007-2008 recession that ``the central problem of depression-prevention has been solved” (Krugman, 2009). This is so despite Joseph Schumpeter once remarking of Fisher: “I venture to predict that his name will stand in history principally as the name of this country’s [the United States] greatest scientific economist” ([1952] 1997, 223). If mainstream economics cannot be relied upon to make predictions of critical economic phenomena such as market crashes, it is unclear that alternative approaches such as econophysics should be optimistic of their ability to do so either. While it is a contention by econophysicists that mainstream economics is fundamentally flawed in its approach, especially in avoiding usage of fat-tailed distributions, strong claims require stronger evidence than is arguably on hand.

  23. It is highly doubtful many scholars of finance would find an alleged physical explanation explanatory for market crashes. In a systematic review of what they describe as pervasive ‘physics envy’ in mainstream economics and finance, Lo & Mueller (2010, 50-57) provide a detailed discussion of several competing narrative explanations of the 2007-2008 financial crisis. See also Kotz (2009) for a detailed ‘institutional economics’ analysis that, according to Google Scholar, has been cited 565 times at the time of writing, and which articulates the mechanisms, and their respective parts, of the effects of neoliberal policies leading to the crisis, that have nothing to do with analogies from physical mechanisms.

  24. See for instance Challet et al. (2001) for a representative minority game study conducted by econophysicists. See also Chakraborti et al. (2011) for a systematic review of agent-based models in econophysics.

  25. See Guala (2005) for a detailed overview of the methodology of behavioral economic study and the extent at which what occurs in the laboratory can be rationally believed to occur outside the laboratory and in the real economic world.

  26. Finance scholars Lo and Mueller (2010) agree, writing in their criticisms of physics transfer in mathematical finance that: “Today’s financial system is considerably more complex than ever before, requiring correspondingly greater concerted effort and expertise to overhaul. By comparison, the Large Hadron Collider — as complex as it is — is a much simpler system...the accelerator, detectors, and computers that constitute the Collider are governed by physical laws that are either perfectly certain or fully reducibly uncertain” (49).

References

  • Aldrich, J. (1987). Jevons as statistician: the role of probability. The Manchester School, 55(3), 233–256.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arioli, G., & Valente, G. (2021). What is really quantum in quantum econophysics? Philosophy of Science, https://doi.org/10.1086/713921. Accessed May 29, 2021.

  • Baaquie, B. (2004). Quantum Finance: path integrals and Hamiltonians for options and interest rates. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baaquie, B. (2018). Quantum field theory for economics and finance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Backhouse, Roger E. (2004). History and equilibrium: A partial defense of equilibrium economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 11(3), 291–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barbé, L. (2010). Francis Ysidro Edgeworth: A Portrait with Family and Friends. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.

  • Bouatta, N., & Butterfield, J. (2014). Renormalization for Philosophers. arXiv:http://arxiv.org/pdf/1406.4532.pdf. 1--48. Accessed May 28, 2021.

  • Boumans, M. (1993). Paul Ehrenfest and Jan Tinbergen: a case of limited physics transfer. History of Political Economy, 25, 131–156.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradley, S., & Thébault, K. (2019). Models on the move: Migration and imperialism. Studies in History and Philosophy of Science: Part A, 77, 81–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, M. (2013). What has econophysics ever done for us? Nature Physics, 9, 317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bursten, J. (2021). The function of boundary conditions in the physical sciences. Philosophy of Science, 88, 234–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carlson, M. (2006). A brief history of the 1987 stock market crash with a discussion of the federal reserve response. Finance and economics discussion series: 2007-13 https://www.federalreserve.gov/pubs/feds/2007/200713/200713pap.pdf. Accessed June 1, 2021.

  • Chakraborti, A., Toke, I., Patriarca, M., & Abergel, F. (2011). Econophysics review: II. Agent-based models. Quantitative Finance, 11(7), 1013–1041.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Challet, D., Marsili, M., & Zhang, Y. (2001). Stylized facts of financial markets and market crashes in Minority Games. Physica A, 294, 514–524.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cockshott, W., Allin, P., Cottrell, F., Michaelson, G. J., Wright, I. P., & Yakovenko, V. M. (2009). Classical econophysics. Routledge.

  • Cross, R. (1995). Metaphors and time reversibility and irreversibility in economic systems. Journal of Economic Methodology, 2(1), 123–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dimand, R. (2013). David Hume and Irving Fisher on the quantity theory of money in the long run and the short run. The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 20(2), 284–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dragulescu, A., & Yakovenko, V. (2000). Statistical mechanics of money. European Physical Journal B, 17, 723–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duarte, F. J., Machado, J. A., & Duarte, G. M. (2010). Dynamics of the Dow Jones and the NASDAQ stock indexes. Nonlinear Dynamics, 61, 691–705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F. (1877). New and old methods of ethics. Oxford: James Parker and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F. (1881). Mathematical psychics. C. Kegan Paul & Co.

  • Edgeworth, F. (1884). The rationale of exchange. Journal of the Statistical Society of London, 47(1), 164–166.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F. (1893). Review of mathematical investigations in the theory of value and prices. The Economic Journal, 112, 108–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F. (1922). The philosophy of chance. Mind, 31(123), 257–283.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F., & Pareto, V. ([1896] 2008). Controversy between Pareto and Edgeworth. Giornale degli Economisti e Annali di Economia, Nuova Serie, 67(121), 425–440.

  • Farjoun, E., & Machover, M. (1983). Laws of chaos: a probabilistic approach to political economy. Verso Editions and NLB.

  • Fisher, I. ([1892] 1925). Mathematical investigations in the theory of value and price. August M. Kelly.

  • Gabaix, X. (2016). Power laws in economics: an introduction. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30(1), 185–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gallegati, M., Keen, S., Lux, T., & Ormerod, P. (2006). Worrying trends in econophysics. Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications, 370(1), 1–6.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gelfert, A. (2016). How to do science with models. Springer.

  • Georgescu-Roegen, N. (1971). The entropy law and the economic process. Harvard University Press.

  • Gingras, Y., & Schinckus, C. (2012). The institutionalization of econophysics in the shadow of physics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 34(1), 109–130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greaves, H. (2007). Probability in the Everett interpretation. Philosophy Compass, 2(1), 109–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guala, F. (2005). The methodology of experimental economics. Cambridge University Press.

  • Harrison, G., & Ross, D. (2010). The methodologies of neuroeconomics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 17(2), 185–196.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, D. (2001). Explanation and Diagnosis in Economics. Revue internationale de philosophie, 217, 311–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hedström, P., & Swedberg, R. (1996). Social Mechanisms. Acta Sociologica, 39(3), 281–308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J. (2015). Experimental econophysics: Complexity, self-organization, and emergent properties. Physics Reports, 564, 1–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutchison, T. (1998). Ultra-deductivism from Nassau Senior to Lionel Robbins and Daniel Hausman. Journal of Economic Methodology, 5(1), 43–91.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ingrao, B., & Israel, G. (1990). The invisible hand: economic equilibrium in the history of science. The MIT Press.

  • Isard, W. (1954). Location theory and trade theory: short-run analysis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 68(2), 305–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jevons, W. ([1871] 1970). The theory of political economy. Penguin classics.

  • Jevons, W. (1873). The philosophy of inductive inference. Fortnightly Review, 14(18), 457–476.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jevons, W. (1883). The principles of science: a treatise on logic and scientific. Method. Macmillan and Co.

  • Jevons, W. (1886). Letters & journals. Macmillan and Co.

  • Jevons, W. ([1888] 2010). Elementary lessons in logic: deductive & inductive. Ludwig von Mises Institute.

  • Jhun, J., Palacios, P., & Weatherall, J. (2018). Market crashes as critical phenomena? Explanation, idealization, and universality in econophysics. Synthese, 195, 4476–4505.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johansen, A., Ledoit, O., & Sornette, D. (2000). Crashes as critical points. International Journal of Theoretical and Applied Finance, 3(2), 219–255.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, F., & Schinckus, C. (2013). The emergence of econophysics: a new approach in modern financial theory. History of Political Economy, 45 (3), 443–474.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, F., & Schinckus, C. (2017). Econophysics and financial economics: an emerging discipline. Oxford University Press.

  • Kincaid, H. (2021). Mechanisms, good and bad. Theoria, 36(2), 173–189.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. ([1921]1964). Risk, uncertainty and profit. August M. Kelly.

  • Kotz, D. M. (2009). The financial and economic crisis of 2008: a systemic crisis of neoliberal capitalism. Review of Radical Political Economics, 41(3), 305–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kovalev, A. (2016). Misuse of thermodynamic entropy in economics. Energy, 100, 129–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. (2009). How did economists get it so wrong? The New York Times. https://www.nytimes.com/2009/09/06/magazine/06Economic-t.html. Accessed June 1st, 2021.

  • Kuhlmann, M (2014). Explaining financial markets in terms of complex systems. Philosophy of Science, 81, 1117–1130.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuhlmann, M. (2019). Crossing boundaries: why physics can help understand economics. In Mechanistic explanations in physics and beyond (pp. 183–205). Switzerland: Springer Nature .

  • Kutner, R., Ausloos, M., Grech, D., Matteo, T., Schinckus, C., & Stanley, H. E. (2019). Econophysics and sociophysics: Their milestones & challenges. Physica A, 516, 240–253.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawson, T. (1997). Economics and reality. Routledge.

  • Leng, N., & Li, J. (2020). Forecasting the crude oil prices based on econophysics and Bayesian approach. Physica A, 554, 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lo, A., & Mueller, M. (2010). Warning: physics envy may be hazardous to your wealth! Journal of Investment Management, 8(2), 13–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machamer, P., Darden, L., & Craver, C. (2000). Thinking about mechanisms. Philosophy of Science, 67, 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandelbrot, B. (1962). Sur certains prix spéculatifs: Faits empiriques et modél basé sur les processus stables additifs non gaussiens de Paul Lévy. Comptes Rendus de l’Academie des Scienceś, [Meeting of June 4]: 3968–70.

  • Mantegna, R., & Stanley, H. (2004). An introduction to econophysics: correlations and complexity in finance. Cambridge University Press.

  • Marchionni, C., & Reijula, S. (2019). What is mechanistic evidence, and why do we need it for evidence-based policy? Studies in History and Philosophy of Science Part A, 73, 54–63.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCauley, J. (2006). Response to “Worrying Trends in Econophysics”. Physica A, 371, 601–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski, P. (1984). Physics and the ‘marginalist revolution.’ Cambridge Journal of Economics, 8, 361–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski, P. (1988). Energy and energetics in economic theory: a review essay. Journal of Economic Issues, 22(3), 811–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski, P. (1989). More heat than light. Cambridge University Press.

  • Pickhardt, M., & Seibold, G. (2014). Income tax evasion dynamics: Evidence from an agent-based econophysics model. Journal of Economic Psychology, 40, 147–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ragan, C. (2012). Financial Stability: The Next Frontier for Canadian Monetary Policy. C.D. Howe Institute, 338, 1–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richmond, P., Mimkes, J., & Hutzler, S. (2013). Econophysics and physical economics. Oxford University Press.

  • Rickles, D. (2007). Econophysics for philosophers. Studies in History and Philosophy of Modern Physics, 38, 948–978.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rickles, D. (2011). Econophysics and the complexity of financial markets. In Philosophy of complex systems (pp. 531–565). Elsevier.

  • Rosser, J. B. (2016). Entropy and econophysics. European Physical Journal Special Topics, 255, 3091–3104.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rother, K. (2007). Diabetes treatment - bridging the divide. New England Journal of Medicine, 356(15), 1499–1501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Russo, F., & Williamson, J. (2007). Interpreting causality in the health sciences. International Studies in the Philosophy of Science, 21, 157–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. ([1947] 1971). Foundations of economic analysis. Oxford University Press.

  • Sãvoiu, G., & Andronache, C. (2013). The potential of econophysics for the study of economic processes. In Econophysics background and applications in economics, finance, and sociophysics (pp. 91–133). Elsevier.

  • Schabas, M. (1984). The “Worldly Philosophy” of William Stanley Jevons. Victorian Studies, 28(1), 129–147.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schabas, M. (1990). A world ruled by number: William Stanley Jevons and the rise of mathematical economics. Princeton University Press.

  • Schabas, M. (2009). Constructing ‘The Economy’. Philosophy of Social Sciences, 39(1), 3–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schinckus, C. (2010). Is econophysics a new discipline? The neopositivist argument. Physica A, 389, 3814–3821.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schinckus, C. (2018). Toward a unifying perspective on economic complexity: the contribution of Chinese econophysics community. Theoretical Economics Letters, 8, 609–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1997). Ten great economists: from Marx to Keynes. Routledge.

  • Slanina, F. (2014). Essentials of econophysics modelling. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sinha, S., & Chakrabarti, B. (2012). Econophysics: an emerging discipline. Economic and Political Weekly, 47(32), 44–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1776/2012). Wealth of nations. Wordsworth editions limited.

  • Smith, E., & Foley, Duncan (2008). Classical thermodynamics and economic general equilibrium theory. Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control, 32, 7–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D. (2003a). Critical market crashes. Physics Reports, 278, 1–98.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D. (2003b). Why stock markets crash. Princeton University Press.

  • Sornette, D. (2014). Physics and financial economics (1776–2014): puzzles, Ising and agent-based models. Reports on Progress in Physics, 77, 1–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, S. (1977). Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, Statistician. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 141(3), 287–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, S. (1986). The history of statistics: the measurement of uncertainty before 1900. The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.

  • Tarasov, V. (2020). Fractional econophysics: Market price dynamics with memory effects. Physica A, 557, 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thébault, K., Bradley, S., & Reutlinger, A. (2018). Modelling inequality. British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 79, 691–718.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thornes, J., & Randalls, S. (2007). Commodifying the Atmosphere: ‘Pennis from Heaven’? Geografiska Annaler Series A., 89(4), 273–285.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weatherall, J. (2013). The physics of wall street. Houghton Mifflin Harcourt.

  • Wilson, K. (1979). Problems in physics with many scales of length. Scientific American, 241(2), 158–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodward, J. (2003). Making things happen: a theory of causal explanation. Oxford University Press.

  • Woolridge, J. (2019). Introductory econometrics: a modern approach. Cengage Learning.

  • Yakovenko, V. (2016). Monetary economics from econo-physics perspective. European Physical Journal Special Topics, 225, 3313–3335.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yegorov, Y. (2007). Econo-physics: A Perspective of Two Matching Sciences. European Physical Journal Special Topics, 4, 143–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yu, T., & Li, H. (2010). Econo-physics: A perspective of matching two sciences. Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review, 4, 143–-170.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

Thanks to the following for constructive feedback: Chris Atkinson, Joseph Berkovitz, Tim Cejka, John B. Davis, Jesse Hall, Julia Lücke, Soroush Marouzi, Michael E. Miller, Mark S. Peacock, Kate Tong, Tracy Wan, two anonymous referees, and audience members attending my talks at the 46th Annual History of Economics Society Meeting at Columbia University (Aug 2019), the 1st Winter Institute for the History of Economic Thought at Arizona State University (Jan 2020), and the 1st Philosophy of Physics Graduate Conference at the University of Oxford (Feb 2020). I thank the IHPST for funding and the University of Cambridge History & Philosophy of Science Department for an academic home where this paper was written.

Funding

University of Toronto (FAST Fellowship).

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Adrian K. Yee.

Ethics declarations

Conflict of Interests

None to declare.

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Yee, A.K. Econophysics: making sense of a chimera. Euro Jnl Phil Sci 11, 100 (2021). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13194-021-00413-1

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s13194-021-00413-1

Navigation